"Can Immigrants Assimilate?” with Garett Jones

"Can Immigrants Assimilate?” with Garett Jones

Released Tuesday, 29th August 2023
Good episode? Give it some love!
"Can Immigrants Assimilate?” with Garett Jones

"Can Immigrants Assimilate?” with Garett Jones

"Can Immigrants Assimilate?” with Garett Jones

"Can Immigrants Assimilate?” with Garett Jones

Tuesday, 29th August 2023
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:00

Good

0:05

day

0:30

Welcome to another episode of Conversations with

0:32

Coleman. If you're hearing this, then you're on

0:34

the public feed, which means you'll get episodes

0:36

a week after they come out, and you'll hear

0:38

advertisements.

0:39

You can get access to the subscriber feed by going

0:42

to colemanhughes.org and becoming a supporter.

0:44

This means you'll have access to episodes a week early,

0:46

you'll

0:47

never hear ads,

0:48

and you'll get access to bonus Q&A episodes.

0:51

You can also support me by liking and subscribing

0:54

on YouTube and sharing the show with friends and family.

0:56

As always, thank you so much

0:58

for your support.

1:03

Welcome to another episode of Conversations with Coleman.

1:06

My guest today is Garrett Jones. Garrett

1:08

is an associate professor of economics at George

1:11

Mason University. His interests include

1:13

macroeconomics, the micro foundations

1:15

of economic growth, IQ,

1:17

the power of culture,

1:19

and public choice economics. The

1:21

books we focus on in this episode are 10% Less

1:23

Democracy, Why

1:25

You Should Trust Elites a Little Bit More and

1:28

The Public a Little Less, and The Culture

1:30

Transplant, How Migrants Make the Economies

1:33

They Move to a Lot Like the Ones They Left.

1:35

We talk about the intellectual environment of George

1:38

Mason University, and we briefly

1:40

digress into a conversation about UAPs.

1:43

Then we get back to the meat of the discussion. We

1:45

talk about the benefits and drawbacks of

1:47

democracy. We discuss the possibility

1:49

of so-called benign dictatorships. We

1:52

talk about the crisis of expertise, the

1:54

electoral college, and then we move on

1:56

to the topic of immigration. We talk about

1:58

whether and in what way... ways immigrants

2:01

assimilate. We talk about the idea of

2:03

the melting pot.

2:04

We discuss high trust versus low

2:06

trust cultures and much more.

2:08

I find Garrett to be a provocative

2:10

thinker in the good sense of that word, though

2:12

I don't totally share his point of view on

2:15

cultural assimilation.

2:16

In any event, I hope that you enjoy this conversation

2:19

as much as I did. So without further ado, Garrett

2:21

Jones.

2:26

Okay, Garrett Jones, thank you so much for

2:28

coming on my show. Glad to be here. Thanks

2:30

for having me. So I've been following your work for a long

2:33

time. You are in the circle of GMU,

2:35

George Mason University, economists

2:37

like Tyler Cowen, Brian Kaplan,

2:40

I think Robin Hanson as well, right? Who have

2:43

really created this subculture

2:45

of extremely interesting

2:48

high IQ people that disagree

2:50

with each other on various really

2:53

interesting matters of import

2:55

and always play by the rules of

2:58

intellectual engagement. And you

3:00

just, you know, I think created a

3:02

really beautiful subculture that is really

3:05

fascinating to peer into as an outsider

3:08

and to enjoy the

3:10

fruits of as a reader. So congratulations

3:13

on being a part of that. And how does it feel

3:15

to be part of that kind of a rare

3:17

subculture? Yeah, it's obviously one of the

3:19

best things that's ever happened in my life, right? I've met other professors

3:22

who are at officially more prestigious universities who

3:24

tell me, you're really lucky to have with you

3:26

have at George Mason, right? This idea of an environment

3:28

of intellectual ferment where people who are smart,

3:30

who are trained in the best ideas and social sciences,

3:33

but don't waste their best decades

3:36

playing math games and journals and instead

3:38

engage with real ideas instead of engage in interdisciplinary

3:41

thinking. That's a great environment to be in.

3:44

And I'm glad that Tyler Cowen

3:46

and my other my department chairs have done so much to make

3:48

that possible. Seems you also have

3:51

created a subculture that really prizes

3:53

strong disagreement with friends. Such

3:55

that you,

3:56

Brian Kaplan, Tyler Cowen, Robin Hanson,

3:58

you can all write a

3:59

really barbed blog post or

4:02

tweet saying, strongly disagree with

4:04

my colleague here, and you'll lay out the reasons.

4:07

Whereas many other subcultures

4:09

prize conformity, right? And you don't

4:12

want to disagree too much with a friend or else

4:14

it's awkward. Yes, lately

4:16

the question of unmanned aerial phenomenon,

4:18

UFOs has been an opportunity for some back

4:20

and forth between a lot of us, especially

4:23

on Twitter and in blog posts. But

4:26

you don't have to other somebody, right? You can just

4:28

keep the discussion going. Because ultimately,

4:31

I think part of what all of us realize is that our audience

4:33

is not the three or four of us. It's the

4:35

greater intellectual community, right? And we should be

4:37

engaging with those folks in a useful

4:39

way. What's the disagreement about UFOs

4:41

or UAPs as they've been rebranded? Yes,

4:44

so it seems as though Tyler and

4:46

Robin seem to be more sympathetic

4:49

to the evidence. They seem to be more persuaded

4:51

by some of the evidence that these are something

4:54

interesting. Maybe they're putting it in the one

4:56

to two to 3% chance that it's actually something

4:58

alien. And I think it's fair to say

5:00

that Alex and I don't tend to look at

5:02

it that way. I was raised LDS. I've

5:05

seen a lot of evidence for that's a member of the Church of

5:07

Jesus Christ of Latter-day Saints. There are a lot

5:09

of religions that have pretty interesting, miraculous

5:11

claims as part of their background. And

5:14

I evaluate these things. I evaluate these miraculous

5:16

stories. And I'm like, some things are just hard to

5:18

explain. I don't have to have an explanation

5:20

for a really unusual phenomenon. I don't

5:22

have to immediately say if I don't have an explanation for this

5:24

weird phenomenon, I'm going to assume that it's a miracle. I'm

5:27

going to conclude that it's a miracle. Some weird things are just

5:29

hard to explain. There are puzzles

5:29

that are beyond the reach of simple

5:32

explanations, at least in the course of a couple of minutes.

5:34

Yeah, I mean, I can see both sides of this. So

5:37

for example, I had Neil deGrasse Tyson on this podcast.

5:39

And he was very, very dismissive

5:41

of the possibility that any strange

5:44

phenomenon we've seen are explained

5:47

by extraterrestrial life.

5:50

And on the one hand,

5:52

someone like him will say that it's

5:55

very unlikely we're alone in the universe, given

5:57

that we believe life is a natural.

5:59

naturally occurring process and not, it's

6:02

not that God touched one corner of

6:04

the universe and breathed life into it, but

6:06

it's probable that we came from some kind

6:09

of primordial soup which is in principle

6:11

replicable somewhere else and given

6:14

how many worlds there are, it's unlikely we're

6:16

the only instance of intelligent

6:18

life. On the other hand, I haven't

6:21

seen any compelling

6:23

evidence that the UAPs we've seen

6:25

are best explained by extraterrestrial

6:28

life. So for example, recently,

6:30

this podcast probably may not come out for

6:32

a couple of weeks after we're talking about it, but there's been

6:35

renewed attention on the phenomenon

6:37

of UAPs because I believe his name is David

6:39

Grutch. So David

6:42

Grutch has made

6:44

claims before Congress

6:46

now that there's been a kind

6:48

of decentralized program

6:51

within the US government of collecting

6:53

essentially

6:53

alien remains, remains

6:56

of space,

6:57

that's end of

6:59

alien beings. And there

7:01

was an article that first, a long article that

7:03

came out about it a few months ago

7:06

at this point.

7:07

Whenever the article I felt, well,

7:09

this is something definitely worth paying attention

7:11

to. But then when I saw the guy speak himself,

7:14

I had the,

7:15

just like the intuition that

7:17

one has, which you can't quite

7:20

put a finger on, but that you're witnessing

7:22

someone who's a crazy person. Now

7:24

that gut feeling, I'm

7:26

not claiming that my gut is somehow

7:29

super reliable, but I definitely downgraded

7:32

the odds that I think

7:35

he's going to show anything for his claims

7:38

once I saw him speak. Yeah, I mean, I,

7:40

partly I come at this as a Bayesian. I try to

7:43

ask myself statistically, if there were aliens

7:45

in the universe, they would either

7:48

likely be nowhere or they'd be everywhere.

7:50

The chances of them just showing up in

7:52

very hazy photographs on military

7:55

monitors, like that's a very narrow

7:57

range of evidence that should exist if they're really, if

7:59

there's other life in the universe, right? We should

8:01

be seeing either civilizations have

8:04

a tough time getting beyond their galaxy or beyond their

8:06

solar system or wherever, or on the other hand,

8:08

ultimately, everybody gets everywhere. Neither

8:10

of those are obviously what's going on.

8:13

It's possible that the former category

8:15

is what's happening right now. It's possible that there have been

8:17

alien lives that have gone and risen

8:20

and fallen away over the course of the billions of years

8:22

of the

8:24

universe's existence, right? That's totally possible.

8:26

We obviously know that it's not the case that aliens are everywhere

8:29

and obvious, that they're reorganizing galaxies,

8:32

spinning them in unique colors, turning

8:34

galaxies into looking like the number pi, something

8:36

like that, right? So the idea that they're just in this

8:38

tiny little area is very weird. Also, there's

8:41

the more my jokey answer to this is

8:43

that if our government

8:45

is a, if our government were able to actually

8:47

keep secrets and be competent at things, then

8:50

there wouldn't have been a press conference held at Four Seasons

8:52

Total landscaping, right?

8:55

So like the level, like our government makes a

8:57

lot of mistakes and its foul

8:59

ups easily get found out quickly. I mean, the

9:01

Watergate burglary would be one, Iran Contra would

9:03

be another. So the idea that my government

9:06

is competent enough to keep something like

9:08

that under wraps for decades. Well, I wonder if there isn't

9:10

like a seen and unseen fallacy

9:12

there because like by definition, we don't know

9:15

about the things governments have successfully

9:17

hit. That's true. Right. We only know about the

9:19

ones we found out.

9:20

But we do, we should ask ourselves, like, if

9:22

you've worked in government, if you do you think that these are the kind

9:25

of people who can keep a secret for that long, right?

9:27

And would it have leaked out by now? Would Jimmy Carter

9:29

have let us know? Would Donald Trump

9:32

have let us know? I just don't see the incentive

9:34

to hide, right? I think obviously

9:38

Bill Clinton had a large incentive to try to

9:40

hide his blowjob and failed about failed.

9:43

And, you know, Nixon had a huge

9:45

incentive to hide Watergate and failed.

9:47

And those are all instructive examples.

9:50

But like,

9:50

where's the incentive to hide this

9:53

from the public? I suppose

9:55

you could argue the first person to get their hands

9:57

on novel technology. some

10:00

kind of arms race, but I mean,

10:02

still, this seems in

10:04

the category of things that any

10:08

typical patriotic government

10:10

official would very much want to inform

10:13

the top brass of

10:15

very quickly. And then by definition,

10:18

it would become difficult to hide. And of course,

10:20

there are almost 200 countries in the world. And so

10:22

aliens, the idea that governments all around

10:24

the world have been successfully keeping this hidden is

10:27

strange credulity too, right? As

10:29

does the theory that for some reason, the aliens only crash

10:31

land their planes in North America,

10:34

right? These are all sort of basically what one needs a lot

10:36

of crazy to line up in a row in order to get

10:38

just the set of facts that the conspiracy theorists

10:40

are pushing. The UAP diehards would say like

10:43

there's cattle prodding in Brazil and stuff. Yeah,

10:45

but

10:45

I mean, that gets that gets really strange.

10:48

I mean, aliens that just they're able to get all the way across

10:50

the galaxy, but then they just crash land once

10:52

they get to Earth. That's really I mean, that's that's

10:54

real. That's like something out of a 1940s radio serial. On

10:58

the other hand, I thought of this analogy

11:00

in the past. If you were a Native American looking

11:02

at Europeans hundreds of years ago,

11:05

you'd say these guys got all the way across

11:07

the Atlantic Ocean and then they just like like

11:10

they landed here. And now they have no idea what

11:12

to do with themselves. And yeah, and they're dying

11:14

for a while, right? And their

11:15

shipwrecked. Yeah, I mean, I don't know. So it's

11:18

all it's all possible. So I mean,

11:20

I would categorize myself as in principle,

11:23

open minded to UAPs

11:26

stemming from extraterrestrial life. But

11:29

every past example and

11:31

current example of the evidence

11:33

being right around the corner has turned

11:35

up, in my view, wanting. And

11:38

I expect that to be the case for

11:40

for the most recent one as well. Though, you

11:43

know, again, I don't have the best explanations

11:45

for,

11:45

you know, I've seen the tic tac UFO. I've

11:48

seen all of the all

11:50

of the evidence. And

11:52

I this is just something I'm not going to explain

11:55

it by extraterrestrial life until there

11:57

really is the smoking gun. And

11:59

in this case. In this case, David Grush has said, you

12:01

know, we actually have

12:04

biological material that is provably

12:07

non-human. Now, if that is true, that

12:09

is an extremely easy claim to prove.

12:12

All you'd have to do is ship a few

12:14

examples of this to a few different

12:16

teams of chemists or physicists that could

12:19

confirm, yes, this is a source that

12:21

could not possibly have been created given

12:23

the current state of human knowledge. The

12:26

thing that hasn't been done in this case is extremely

12:28

suspicious to me, given the claims that he's

12:29

made. Yeah, I think that we should be good Bayesians

12:32

about this and say extraordinary claims require

12:34

extraordinary evidence. My base level

12:37

of belief is that this is a wildly

12:39

extraordinary claim. So it should require

12:41

wildly extraordinary evidence. And

12:44

they're not even at sort of like basic mid-levels of evidence. So

12:47

I mean, if this is the level of evidence it takes to believe in aliens, I

12:49

should be believing in a lot of religions right

12:51

now. A lot of miraculous claims were

12:53

like weird things happen. Somebody saw something

12:56

and it's hard to explain and I can't come

12:58

up with a legitimate easy explanation. I

13:00

think to me one lesson of this is that the

13:02

human demand to come up with explanations

13:05

is overrated. We

13:07

shouldn't be insisting on coming up with answers for things. We

13:09

should be like people who are trying to explain the origins

13:11

of life and where life came from and how all

13:13

the species came to be. If we were living in the

13:16

1400s, if I was living in the 1400s, I would

13:18

really want an explanation for why there are all these species

13:20

around and why, you know, like seem to produce

13:22

sort of like, you know, lions seem to have lions

13:25

and tigers seem to have tigers. Like why is all this happening? And, you

13:27

know, what's where did life come from? And

13:29

why is there why there's so many species? You

13:31

can see why religions came along to give people easy answers

13:33

for that. The right answer, if

13:36

you lived in the 1400s would be I shouldn't

13:38

come up with an answer. I should just wait for a few centuries and maybe

13:40

somebody else would come up with one. So just embracing

13:42

ignorance is, I think, an intellectual virtue

13:45

that is underrated in our age. Underrated in

13:47

every age, I think. OK, so I didn't expect

13:49

to start there, but really, I got you

13:51

on the podcast to discuss your most

13:53

recent two books surrounding

13:56

the topics of democracy and culture.

13:59

and taking positions on

14:02

those that are probably counterintuitive

14:05

to some people, maybe upsetting to some

14:07

people, but really based on

14:10

lots of research and careful thinking.

14:12

In America, we have this idea

14:14

that democracy is basically a sacred

14:16

value. Democracy

14:19

is at the core of what, for many people,

14:21

it means to be an American. And as a

14:24

sacred value, the idea is

14:26

that more democracy is always better.

14:28

Every example of an American failure,

14:30

of an American problem, is solved, or

14:33

at least not hurt, by having more

14:35

democratic control, by having public

14:37

opinion closer to the lever

14:39

of policy outcomes. You

14:42

come along and you are saying, actually,

14:45

sure, democracy is good to

14:47

an extent, but there are actually very

14:49

important ways in which more

14:51

democracy is bad and less democracy

14:54

would be good. So

14:55

how do you substantiate that? Well,

14:57

part of the way I look at it is that I was trained in monetary

15:00

economics, right? And so my dissertation was

15:02

on the Fed. And if there's one thing that economists have

15:04

learned just by looking at the data over

15:06

the last few decades, it's that countries

15:08

that have central banks that are kept far

15:11

away from the politicians, far from the voters,

15:13

tend to get better outcomes, and not better

15:15

outcomes at the expense of the masses, but it seems

15:18

to be a totally free lunch. So countries

15:20

that have what we euphemistically call more

15:22

independent central banks, banks where the

15:24

elected politicians can't just fire the head of the bank, they seem

15:26

to have lower inflation, and they probably

15:29

have fewer financial crises too. So

15:31

anytime you can get a free lunch, you should take it. So

15:33

we take it for granted. But you might think that's just us

15:35

economists saying, well, we're smart, you should put us

15:38

in charge. But I have to say the evidence backs

15:40

us up on this, right? Having elected

15:42

politicians making decisions on interest

15:44

rates right before an election would probably not be good

15:46

policy. That's why we delegated to the nerds. Independent

15:50

judges, right, independent Supreme

15:52

Courts that have long terms that are kept

15:54

away from the heat of government. That

15:56

seems to be a free lunch or something close to

15:58

a free lunch where we get better governance, we

16:01

hand over a bunch of big decisions to elites

16:03

who can't be recalled by the voters very easily at all.

16:05

And this is part of what we call, we

16:08

call it an independent judiciary. But when we

16:10

talk, when we celebrate the independent judiciary,

16:13

what's it independent of? It's independent of voters.

16:15

So, you know, I look at the Senate,

16:17

for instance, and I was actually

16:20

a Senate staff for a long time ago for Orrin Hatch.

16:22

And senators in the US have six year terms,

16:24

members of the House have two year terms.

16:27

And one thing that everybody knows when you work on

16:29

the Hill is that senators seem to have a longer time

16:31

horizon than members of the House. Senators

16:34

are, they're willing to act like, you

16:36

know, to be a little glib, they act like statesmen the first

16:38

four years, and then they act like pandering politicians the

16:40

last two. And that seems to be pretty good

16:42

for governance overall. It turns out that

16:44

there's a study that shows that senators are 10

16:46

percentage points more likely to vote for a free

16:49

trade agreement when they're further from an election.

16:51

So Hillary Clinton, for example, voted for every

16:53

free trade, every free trade deal in her first

16:55

four years as a senator, and she voted against every

16:58

free trade deal in her last two years as a senator

17:00

when she was just coming up for reelection. Right. So politicians

17:03

pay attention to voters and often what voters want

17:05

is bad. So I'd say those are some

17:07

key forms of evidence, like looking at the Senate

17:09

shows us the value of a little bit of distance from the

17:12

voters, judges and independent judiciary

17:14

is strangely something we celebrate as democratic,

17:17

but it's quite undemocratic, right? Nobody

17:19

wants key judicial decisions made by fiat

17:21

or by excuse me, by plebiscite, by mass

17:24

vote. If you picture a system

17:26

where we could remove a Supreme

17:28

Court justice by referendum,

17:30

by national referendum, probably every

17:33

single current Supreme Court justice

17:35

would have been removed at some point in time

17:37

or another. Yeah. Certainly, if you zoom

17:39

out to the past like 20 years, there's almost no doubt.

17:42

But even more democratic would be to just have the citizens

17:45

make the Supreme Court decisions. So

17:48

it would be more democratic debt. Now, I would have to say

17:50

that jury decision making, you know, which

17:52

is, you know, jury trials are a right that we have

17:54

in the United States for almost everything. A

17:56

jury trial is pretty democratic, right? But

17:59

there we have a small number of people

18:01

who know that they're the decisive voters, you know, usually 12

18:03

people, right? So that's a form of democracy

18:06

that seems to get the best parts of

18:08

democracy, getting the people's voice

18:10

in there, but getting rid of the one of the weaknesses

18:12

of democracy, which is where everyone's free

18:14

riding off of everyone else's hard work, right?

18:16

When you're one of the 12, you know, you're one of the key

18:19

decision makers. When you're one of millions, you're like,

18:21

doesn't really. In fact, you often know that your vote

18:23

de facto doesn't matter. Right?

18:26

Like I

18:27

know that New York's delegates

18:29

are going to go blue. My vote doesn't

18:31

matter in that context of a presidential

18:34

election, right? I mean, whenever an election

18:36

is decided by more than one person, by more

18:38

than one vote, your vote didn't matter, right? So

18:40

the 10% less democracy is really about

18:44

pointing to a lot of empirical evidence, a lot of real

18:46

world evidence that in a lot of areas voters

18:49

are short-sighted. And when

18:51

we look at the real world and we look at the evidence, it looks like

18:53

keeping decisions a little bit further away from

18:55

voters has a good payoff. There are big benefits

18:58

to democracy. Now I should point out the thing we

19:00

usually call democracy today is not wouldn't be democracy

19:02

by the standards of the Greeks, right? We are using

19:05

representative democracy with longer

19:07

terms than Romans would have, than Greeks would have ever wanted,

19:09

right? The ancient Greeks, for them a one-year

19:11

term was pushing it. I'm not kidding,

19:13

right? So, and so the

19:16

moving beyond those simple questions, I

19:18

move a little bit further later in the book and I say, you

19:20

know, if you just look around, Alexander

19:23

Hamilton was right. And having a national

19:25

debt is a way of making sure that the

19:27

international pool of money is keeping an eye

19:29

on your government's policy. It's a way of

19:31

getting the financial markets vote on

19:33

your government's policy. And that's a good idea

19:36

because those folks have a long time horizon.

19:38

They have skin in the game and you

19:40

should pay attention to what they have to say about the likelihood

19:43

of success or failure of your, of at least the economics

19:45

of your government policy. It's not the same as morality, but

19:47

it's something at least worth paying attention to. So, you know, having

19:50

a debt is a way of basically constraining

19:52

your voters. And again, it's something that

19:54

a lot of democracies do. When countries

19:56

get in financial

19:57

trouble, they treat the debt that

19:59

they have to

19:59

pay and how the bondholders feel the way

20:02

that a lot of companies treat their management consultants.

20:04

They say, well, you know, I really don't want

20:06

to have to fire you, but these expensive management consultants

20:08

we just hired say we've got to, right? It's a way

20:10

of having somebody to pass the buck to. And that's

20:12

part of how people we govern each other is

20:15

we want to be the good cop. And so we outsource the bad

20:17

cop. So having the international pool of money, the bondholders

20:20

be a bad cop is actually a good part of governance,

20:22

I think just another reminder that

20:24

purely having the voters making the day to day

20:26

decisions of a government is nobody's bliss point.

20:29

We want to outsource a lot of decisions

20:31

to experts and we want to make it hard for the voters

20:33

to recall those experts by large.

20:39

This is Jason from Team Coleman. If

20:41

you are looking to learn more this year, then we recommend

20:43

the How to Academy podcast, a biweekly

20:46

show from London's home of big thinking.

20:48

The How to Academy invite the world's most

20:50

exciting leaders, scholars and entrepreneurs

20:53

to share their ideas for transforming our lives

20:56

and the world. Past episodes include

20:58

Bill Clinton and James Patterson on creative

21:00

partnerships, Isabel Allende and Gloria

21:02

Steinem on feminism, the late Madeleine Albright

21:05

on diplomacy, Melinda Gates on philanthropy,

21:08

Dr. Gabor made on the body saying no,

21:10

Simon Sinek on leadership and much more.

21:13

If you want to know how Nobel Peace Prize

21:15

winner Maria Ressa stands up to dictators,

21:17

how comic book pioneer Alan Moore boosts

21:19

his imagination, or how Chelsea Manning

21:22

fights for a more transparent society, you'll

21:24

find out with How to Academy. They also

21:26

have episodes

21:26

featuring a few of previous conversations

21:29

with Coleman guests including Neil deGrasse

21:31

Tyson, Noam Chomsky, Steven

21:33

Pinker and Richard Dawkins. The How

21:35

to Academy podcast is your one-stop

21:37

show to broaden your thinking and hear from the artists

21:40

and experts shaping our world.

21:45

Interesting. So I want to sort of

21:47

ask what are the areas

21:51

where the voters are most ignorant

21:53

and what are the areas where the voters are

21:55

most correct? Oh, that's really

21:57

good. I mean, of course, it'll change century by century.

21:59

century, right? I would say that, you

22:02

know, going back to my colleague, Brian Kaplan's

22:05

book, Myth of the Rational Voter, he pointed

22:07

out that voters have a strong

22:09

anti-foreign bias. They seem to be way

22:11

more hostile to free

22:13

trade, to low tariff barriers compared

22:16

to what professional economists think. And

22:19

it seemed, I agree with professional economists

22:21

on this. So basically, regular voters

22:23

are too hostile to free trade. They're too hostile

22:25

to foreigners more generally. They're too

22:27

hostile to the boss.

22:29

I mean, I can picture a scenario like

22:32

let's say,

22:33

let's say that because there are going

22:35

to be winners and losers, right? Even if

22:38

on the aggregate, free trade is a very good thing

22:40

for a population, there are going to be some losers

22:42

from that. People who are going

22:44

to be facing higher competition precisely

22:47

from the consequences of free

22:49

trade. If all of them are

22:51

voting very strongly against

22:54

it, it may look like a population

22:56

has a sort of the wrong opinion.

22:59

Whereas if let's say 100% of economists

23:01

understand the big picture, but 20% of people

23:03

who don't benefit from it are voting against it,

23:06

you can say, well, the population is 20%

23:08

against this policy. They should be 100% for

23:11

it if they were as accurate as the economists. So

23:14

is it a function of legitimate

23:16

self-interest that the voters are, sort

23:18

of have the wrong opinion or does

23:20

it go beyond that just into outright ignorance?

23:22

That's a good question. So I think all the evidence

23:24

points started going far beyond raw self-interest

23:27

to just ignorance. So people who are basic,

23:30

for instance, people who are retired from say,

23:32

auto making industries are who

23:34

used to make cars, but don't make cars anymore, right?

23:37

Those folks are not excited

23:39

about free trade. Now they're just car buyers.

23:41

They're not car makers anymore, right? So to give a, that's

23:43

a glib example, but people who live in towns

23:46

that might be impacted by this seem to, you

23:48

can understand them having a self-interest, but the

23:50

level of hostility is much more than say, the 20%

23:53

you're thinking about. It seems to be more than

23:54

can be explained. And it seems to be because people don't

23:57

understand the possibility that they

23:59

don't understand.

23:59

I understand sufficiently how

24:02

the market creates new opportunities, right?

24:05

So if you're

24:08

a 45 to 65 year old person who's working

24:10

on an assembly line, on net free trade is probably

24:13

pretty bad for you, right? But younger

24:15

people actually can and do readjust

24:18

and they do it at a pretty high level and

24:20

they're not sufficiently supportive of free trade. I mean, they're

24:22

the ones getting the inexpensive stuff at

24:24

the stores and they're not sufficiently excited about it.

24:27

So another one that's more, that's a bigger deal

24:29

is all the labor market regulation stuff, right?

24:32

Europe, of course, has much Europe and

24:34

actually East Asia both have much stronger labor

24:36

market regulations than, you know,

24:39

economists would generally support. And those are really

24:41

popular. People really don't trust the boss,

24:44

right? So this is something that comes out in sort

24:46

of Alberto, late Alberto Alissino's work

24:49

that a lot of hostility to

24:51

a lot of demand for government regulation, the labor

24:53

market comes from not trusting the boss. So

24:55

in high trust societies, people are willing, more willing

24:58

to allow the boss to fire somebody

25:00

because they think that while the boss might be a good guy and

25:02

low trust, lower trust societies, people are like, I

25:04

don't want to, but overall people just aren't, they

25:06

really dislike the prospect. They

25:08

have a, I would say it's a version of the endowment effect,

25:11

right? They're thinking like behavioral, like the way

25:13

behavioral economists describe people when

25:15

people get a job, they have this endowment and they're really

25:17

thinking about like this job that I have as

25:19

a treasure that I want to keep and I don't want somebody to take it away from

25:21

me. So why don't we make it really hard for me to be fired? And

25:24

those rules seem to overall just reduce a lot

25:26

of dynamism. They make it hard to have the kind of creative

25:28

destruction that's at the heart of innovation.

25:31

So it's still the case that, for instance, in

25:33

Western Europe, when people lose their jobs,

25:35

they're still getting replacement rates of their

25:38

old income of like 75% of their old income

25:40

for like a year or two. And it's unbelievable, right?

25:43

So and that keeps the unemployment rates really

25:45

high. In the US, it's just so much lower. We're

25:47

fortunate in the US that voters and

25:49

the opinion differences between the US and Europe

25:51

aren't that high on this. So we're just lucky

25:54

that American institutions don't

25:56

give American voters what they want when it comes to labor

25:58

market regulation. We probably be. We'd have higher

26:00

unemployment rates and we'd have a lot less

26:02

business dynamism. So if I think about

26:05

something like crime, in that case,

26:07

how does expert opinion differ from voter

26:09

opinion and is there as

26:11

big a divergence? That takes me outside

26:14

of my area of expertise because I actually

26:16

don't know surveys of say criminologists.

26:18

So, I mean, if I just go by, so one

26:21

thing that I have to do in this line of work is make

26:23

sure that I'm not treating say the New York Times

26:25

and the Wall Street Journal op-ed pages as the elites,

26:27

right? I take something much more like Brian

26:30

Kaplan's approach, which is I want to look at experts in

26:32

the field and see what they think. So I mean, I

26:34

know when I look at recent literature reviews

26:36

in the economics of crime, which overlaps a lot

26:38

with criminology, I mean, they're generally finding

26:41

that more police actually reduce rates of

26:47

crime. There is some debate

26:49

on the incarceration effects on crime actually

26:51

does, the incapacitation effects of crime

26:54

are pretty obvious. There are some complicated

26:56

discussions of

26:59

what the optimal amount of time is for a person to

27:02

be in prison, but I'll go to my colleague,

27:04

Alex Tabarok on this, who knows

27:06

literature quite well. And his view is

27:08

that higher numbers of police on the street, so

27:10

you increase the probability of individual

27:13

criminals being caught in the short run and having

27:15

individual folks on police on the street deterring crime,

27:17

that seems to have a large payoff. That

27:20

is, there's still some debate on three

27:22

strikes you're out, long sentences. But

27:26

I'd say I think it's safe to say that experts in the field

27:28

are hostile to the view that cutting

27:31

police budgets as a way will have minimal

27:33

effect on crime.

27:34

And I think that fits with the masses thing. Yeah. I

27:37

mean, my take on this would be people are far too

27:39

pessimistic when they're thinking about the country

27:41

in general. This is what they call the optimism

27:43

gap. You ask people, how is the country

27:46

doing with regards to crime? And they will give you

27:48

the pest, the most pessimistic possible story

27:50

based on the fact that they've been watching the news

27:52

lately. And there's always enough crime for the news. But

27:54

if you ask them what's going on in your neighborhood,

27:57

they will have a pretty accurate take. But

28:00

if you look at voters being upset

28:02

with their local DA with things

28:04

like this, I think they tend to be pretty

28:07

correct in terms of responding

28:10

to changes in local conditions. But

28:12

if you ask them to make an assessment

28:14

globally, they're probably going to be far worse

28:17

than the experts, which is a moot point in

28:19

the case of crime because crime is local and

28:21

crime policy is local. Your local

28:24

police station is largely what you

28:26

have to have to control. Is

28:29

there any sense, how do you view

28:32

the kind of populist

28:35

spirit that has taken

28:37

over a lot of places? The core idea of populism

28:40

is that the people

28:42

know what is best and you're going to

28:45

channel the popular will through

28:47

an individual that has some kind

28:49

of magic line

28:51

into the will of

28:53

the people. Yeah, it's a disaster.

28:56

It's a disaster. Populism is quite generally

28:58

a disaster, right? I mean, our last

29:00

populist movement got

29:03

us prohibition, right, depending on how you want to

29:05

blend together populism and progressivism. And

29:10

I think the new wave of populism

29:12

that is hostile to trade, hostile

29:15

to any kind of insider

29:17

decision making, and hostile

29:19

to following, to actually believing

29:22

results of elections that seem to be

29:24

fairly run about as well as things get

29:26

run in the real world. I

29:28

mean, it's a lot of wish fulfillment, I think, right?

29:31

So I understand

29:33

why people don't want to say like there's other

29:35

people who know more than I do about this and the

29:38

world might not be the way I think it is. But I mean, a

29:40

huge part of my intellectual development, a huge

29:42

part of the number of the gifts that I've been given in life

29:44

have come from the fact that I kept

29:46

the door open to learning that I was wrong about things.

29:50

And yeah, the human soul does

29:52

not contain all knowledge, right? And

29:56

so we have to learn things from each other and we

29:58

usually have to learn things from people who've been thinking.

29:59

thinking about it a long time. Not from any one person, but

30:02

from a sort of an invisible hand that pulls together

30:04

knowledge from a lot of people. So I'm

30:07

trying to think of examples where I think the expert

30:09

class is just atrocious

30:12

and arguably worse than public

30:14

opinion. So for example, I

30:17

pay a lot of attention to the racism literature.

30:19

And if you were to pull the

30:22

racism experts who teach at the

30:24

Ivy League colleges and so forth, my

30:26

sense is you would get a picture of reality

30:28

that is so far from the truth that

30:31

it would make sense to devalue the

30:33

weight of the expert class in that field.

30:35

Economics may not be the same, but

30:38

if you look at like the broader landscape of the expert

30:40

class, there are a few critiques that I

30:42

think are legitimately leveled at it. One

30:44

is that in certain instances has been

30:46

captured by a wokeness

30:49

and social justice or other ideologies

30:52

that have fundamentally warped its attitude

30:54

towards empiricism. So that would be

30:56

true, for example, of gender

30:58

and race, I would say.

30:59

And another different critique

31:02

that would get leveled at it is that the experts

31:04

have been captured by industry, which is

31:06

to some extent people's critique

31:09

of drug experts, right? The experts

31:11

who scientists that need to get their next

31:13

grant from the NIH or the NIAID

31:16

and have a kind of revolving

31:18

door phenomenon with the industries that

31:21

they're delivering information about. To what

31:23

extent do those, you can

31:25

take those critiques sort of one at a time,

31:27

to what extent do those undermine the idea

31:29

that the experts know more than the people?

31:32

Well, for one thing, when I compare them to the

31:35

people, I want to be comparing them to all the

31:37

people, right? Not just a

31:39

subset of the people that happen to be sort of on

31:41

my side or on my political party or

31:43

following my podcast. People who often

31:45

prefer the people over the elites often quickly

31:48

dive into some subset of the people, right? So I wanna

31:50

do that first. So I don't know what the people think

31:52

on a lot of these issues if I just surveyed all of the

31:55

American people, right? I would probably get pretty

31:57

diverse views on issues of both race and gender,

31:59

right? And the average might not

32:02

be that far from those elites. Second, you're

32:04

right, I do think, I do have a bias

32:06

toward quantitative fields that use

32:08

statistical methods, which kind of pulls me in the direction

32:10

of econ. That's a fair point. I

32:13

do see that when economists,

32:16

well, I will say this, Leo

32:18

Strauss has had a lot of, the philosopher

32:20

Leo Strauss, the late philosopher, has had a big

32:22

effect on a lot of us at George Mason. And Leo

32:24

Strauss thought that on controversial topics,

32:27

many philosophers sort of spoke

32:29

in code, sort of speak about, out of both

32:31

sides of their mouth. And part of the reason they do this is because

32:33

the first great philosopher Socrates tried speaking

32:36

his mind and he was given a cup of hemlock

32:38

for it, right? And so the

32:40

Straussian take is that sometimes you have to read between

32:42

the lines. And I've found that

32:44

to be extremely useful when I'm reading

32:47

an areas of research. I mean, I've

32:49

done research on IQ, and I've

32:51

done research on culture, I've done research on immigration.

32:54

And in these areas, I find that I often

32:56

have to make a distinction between the public

32:58

pronouncements and what's included

33:01

in table three, right? So I've noticed

33:03

this on quite a number of issues and

33:06

too long actually covered a podcast. And so

33:08

it is a reminder that the public statements

33:11

of some of these folks, you're right, it's fair to say,

33:13

like sometimes they can't be trusted and you

33:15

have to talk to some of these folks over

33:17

a couple of drinks when the after

33:19

the cell phone batteries have died. Yeah, no,

33:21

that is definitely true. That's definitely my experience too,

33:24

dealing with all kinds of institutions, like

33:26

the truths you will get out of

33:28

people over a drink

33:30

are just diametrically different than what

33:33

they will tweet the very next day or what

33:36

they will say publicly. And I, but I have to say, econ

33:38

has been pretty good on this. Like we've had recent lit reviews

33:41

on the economics of crime and punishment and

33:43

policing. And like, you can learn a lot

33:46

of really good things out of them. And there it's

33:48

not tucked away in table three too much. On

33:50

the most explosive issues where people fear their

33:52

careers being destroyed, I think there is a special

33:54

reason for caution about that and for how we

33:56

interpret things on that. It should be issues. We're

33:58

saying that, you know, everyone.

33:59

hates economists in

34:02

the Academy. Like you're not the most popular.

34:04

No, we are often not

34:07

that popular. Precisely in some

34:09

way because you have preserved

34:12

the empirical spirit

34:14

and that

34:14

sometimes takes you in directions which are not

34:17

congenial to people, not congenial to ideology.

34:20

Yeah, I mean, it's one of the great

34:22

things about being an economist is that especially

34:25

a tenured economist, that you have a moral responsibility

34:27

to tell the truth and you also have some

34:29

intellectual tools that help you think about

34:32

how do you understand the world when you don't really get to

34:34

run experiments very often but you really want to learn about

34:36

cause and effect. So the tools really

34:38

do help you and they've, I mean, I started getting them

34:41

over 25 years ago, started studying in a serious

34:43

way over 25 years ago and it's been paying

34:44

off ever since. So a good intermediate macro book

34:47

and intermediate microeconomics book can change your world.

34:49

So you've pointed to all these examples like

34:51

an independent central

34:53

bank, Supreme Court justices

34:56

or judges in general that serve long terms

34:58

and can't be fired.

35:00

All these examples where taking things out

35:03

of the control of the voters is actually

35:05

good for not just the voters, but the

35:08

entire society.

35:09

Why not take this all the way and just say

35:12

autocracy is better? Oh, and the

35:14

core reason for this is that, you know, as Amartya Sen,

35:16

the Nobel Laureate showed, there's never been a famine

35:18

in a democracy. And one thing that democracies

35:21

are really good at is making sure their citizens don't starve

35:23

to death in famines. And so India's, he

35:25

studied India, of course, and India's last famine was

35:27

just a few years before independence. And

35:30

since India's independence, I mean, it's not like

35:32

they switched to becoming a capitalist utopia

35:34

or anything, right? They stayed quite socialist

35:37

for quite a long time with bad economic policies for

35:39

decades. But nonetheless, they managed to

35:41

never have a famine again. So Amartya Sen's result

35:43

has held up in broad terms that

35:45

basically voters care about not make,

35:48

they care about one thing that autocrat might

35:50

not care about, which is making sure that large numbers

35:52

of citizens do not starve to death. Another point that Bill

35:54

Easterly made, the NYU economist, is

35:57

that democracies don't kill their citizens very

35:59

often. So I'd say those are the two big ones. There

36:01

are other questions that are more debatable about whether democracy

36:04

causes this or that good outcome. But democracy

36:06

is not murdering their own citizens in large numbers, and

36:08

democracy is not letting their people

36:10

starve to death. Like we'll give you the equivalent

36:13

of food stamps or relief aid or something

36:15

rather than let people die in a famine. Those seem like

36:17

they're good enough that I wouldn't want to trade those off for any other

36:19

alleged benefits of autocracy. I mean, I think

36:21

more generally, it's worth remembering that even

36:24

so-called autocrats are never

36:26

really autocrats. This is one of the big findings

36:28

of studies of dictatorships and monarchies

36:31

more generally is that the equilibrium, as my

36:33

late colleague Gordon Tullock pointed out, equilibrium always seems

36:35

to be king and council. Kings always have some

36:37

kind of senate around them, some kind of body of advisors

36:40

who are actually powerful enough to say no at times

36:42

and powerful enough to stop the leader. So this

36:44

is a reminder that there really is no option of

36:46

autocracy. It's the question of the real

36:49

trade-off that we should be thinking about is not pure democracy

36:52

on the one hand versus oligarchy on the other, not

36:55

a single leader. We romanticize single leaders.

36:57

I think we might have some kind of tribal ancestral

36:59

instinct as human beings to want the one leader. But

37:02

in practice, oligarchy is the only real

37:04

other pole if we're not going to democracy.

37:07

And Aristotle saw this. And so he thought

37:09

that perhaps, he argued that

37:11

perhaps the best practical form of governance was something

37:14

he called polity, some kind of blend of

37:16

democracy with oligarchy. And that's really what

37:18

we have in the rich countries today is we have some

37:20

kind of blend of democracy with oligarchy. And

37:23

getting that balance, I think we can improve that

37:25

balance by moving just a little bit in the direction of oligarchy.

37:28

So it sounds like you're saying,

37:29

and I agree that really the central

37:32

benefit of democracy is avoiding

37:34

worst case scenarios, which are famine,

37:37

mass killing. Democracies are very

37:39

good at preventing those things from happening,

37:41

but not good at choosing the

37:44

best policies on the more mundane

37:46

issues. So is another

37:51

benefit of democracy preventing

37:53

civil unrest in some way? Because this is an

37:55

idea people have had that by having

37:58

frequent elections.

37:59

and especially multiple parties,

38:02

people can discharge their

38:04

kind of civil tensions

38:07

in a nonviolent way, whereas

38:09

in an autocracy or a one-party

38:12

state, things just bubble up over decades

38:14

and then end in bloody revolution. So is there evidence

38:16

to support that idea? I actually don't

38:18

know of evidence to support that, even though I've heard of

38:20

it for decades, right? It's an important idea. I

38:22

actually teach it to my students. I say, the great thing about

38:25

democracy is that it's a regularly scheduled revolution.

38:27

And you're right. It seems to be some kind of release

38:29

valve that moves the government in the

38:32

direction of the masses and social

38:34

pressures in small degrees as

38:37

the voters are changing their views. And if there's one

38:39

thing that, my

38:41

colleague Richard Wagner at GMU, he

38:43

talked about politicians as entrepreneurs. And

38:46

it's obvious that when you actually see politicians

38:49

and watch them working, they do have this

38:51

entrepreneurial spirit. And part of being an entrepreneur is listening

38:53

to your customers. Like they're always trying to

38:55

read the tea leaves. They're trying to put their ear to

38:57

the ground. They're trying to sense what's going on.

39:00

So they can predict, like give these voters

39:02

what they want. I mean, the will of the voters

39:04

is kind of incoherent, difficult

39:06

to quantify in any serious way. And

39:09

politicians are trying to get the best

39:11

information they can to sort of move in that direction. So

39:13

the idea that politicians aren't at all responsive to

39:15

voters, you can only think that if you've never actually,

39:18

never actually talked to a politician, right? I mean, part

39:20

of their job is to act like they're all confidence in everything,

39:22

but they want to, they like to win and

39:24

they really like to win by more than 60%. So

39:27

when you look at senators, for example, and you

39:29

see

39:29

in their first four years, they act

39:32

quote unquote more like statesmen and the last two

39:34

years they act like, well, doing

39:36

whatever they can to get reelected, pandering

39:38

as you. Celebrating

39:41

democracy as you're supposed to say, I guess. Yeah, yeah.

39:43

I mean, in their first four years though, are

39:45

they governing from a sense of

39:47

their own wise, like

39:50

their own wisdom or are

39:53

they favor trading with interest

39:55

groups? Oh, they're doing a lot of that, right? So

39:57

it's not that these guys are saying.

39:59

the first four years, disinterested,

40:02

noble, public servants,

40:04

the first four years. It's that some

40:06

mix of forces gets them to act the way

40:08

economists want them to act, right? So the

40:11

trade deal thing is one of them. But

40:13

they're not doing that because they remember

40:15

their freshman Econ class. They're doing that- They're

40:17

probably doing it because they're lobbyists who are like, hey, we'd

40:19

love to have these tariffs lowered,

40:22

and we might give your son a job. And it just so

40:24

happens that in that case, the lobbyists

40:27

have a view that expert economists would tend

40:29

to agree with. Yeah. So when people complain about

40:31

the swamp and they complain about corruption in government,

40:33

I'm like, a lot of that stuff is working out

40:35

just fine. But they're also handing out corn subsidies

40:38

and stuff that economists wouldn't agree with,

40:40

right? And alas, because we live in a democracy,

40:43

we're going to keep those corn subsidies forever, right? Because

40:45

everybody needs to win Iowa, right? We're stuck with that.

40:49

That's a case where if you did have an autocracy, you probably

40:51

would get rid of the corn subsidies in Iowa. I don't

40:53

want to do that. I'm just willing to take having

40:56

85% ethanol as being the price of a democracy. So

40:59

what do you make of

40:59

the possibility of benign dictatorship?

41:02

And people, I mean, not that Singapore

41:04

is a dictatorship, it's kind of a hybrid, interesting

41:08

case, but people will point to a

41:10

Singapore as an

41:12

example, or many, many decades

41:14

ago, South Korea as an example, where

41:17

autocracy coincided with

41:19

very high economic growth, and

41:22

will kind of romanticize the idea

41:24

of just not being a democracy full

41:27

stop. So what do you make of that idea? Well,

41:29

we have,

41:29

I like to romanticize Singapore, but I also at

41:32

the same time do not recommend it to others, right? Singapore

41:34

is an incredibly impressive country,

41:36

right? And they do not have anything like a full democracy.

41:38

It's very hard to run a competitive election against

41:41

the government. So they have some seats, but

41:43

they're not, they're kept from winning anymore. So

41:45

it is the case that many countries

41:48

that industrialize, industrialize when they're not a

41:50

democracy, and then they get, they

41:52

switch to democracy later on. That fits a

41:54

theory that democracy is sort of a luxury

41:56

good that countries buy, right? And

41:58

it's a reminder that when we're with these, when people

42:00

want to say democracy causes growth, well,

42:03

A, look at a lot of these development miracle countries

42:05

and realize they went for democracy after

42:07

they'd gotten a lot of growth already. But it is a sign

42:09

that, you know, whenever someone plots

42:11

a simple correlation and tells you it might be causation,

42:14

you should say, maybe it's going the other way around. I have to,

42:16

similarly, I have to look at South Korea's example. I mean,

42:18

I spoke to someone who grew up

42:20

in that I taught at George Mason University's Korea

42:23

campus for two semesters. It was a great experience. And

42:25

I talked to someone who grew up there during the dictatorship

42:27

era. And this person saw

42:30

people he loved suffer under

42:32

the dictatorship. But at the same time, he

42:34

knew that the dictator Park Chung-hee, like,

42:37

saved his country from being a wreck. That was his

42:39

theory, right? I have to look at the data and say,

42:42

I think South Korea would have done just fine. Otherwise,

42:44

East Asian countries that were not dictatorships

42:47

did fine, right? Japan

42:49

industrialized after World War Two, real

42:51

democratic elections, where parties were allowed

42:53

to go in and out of power. Maybe the communists were kept

42:55

out. But so it's the

42:58

causal effect of either democracy or

43:00

dictatorship is pretty weak. Here's what I can

43:02

say that's empirically has better evidence.

43:05

Dictatorships are high variants. Dictatorships

43:08

are basically you can get a big up or a big down. Democracies

43:11

are basically the bond

43:13

market fund of political governance systems.

43:15

It's safer. So that's the I

43:18

think most most people should be discouraged from

43:20

taking the risky bet when it comes to governance. And

43:22

so that's why I think that the autocracy

43:24

story, the celebration of autocracy ignores

43:27

the many, many bad cases that happen on the downside.

43:29

Our brains just can't keep all the facts in our head at once. That's

43:32

why some glib statistics can go a long way on something

43:34

like that.

43:39

For a long time, I like to eat well, but

43:41

did not like to cook. And Grubhub was way

43:43

too expensive. Plus, I've been lifting weights

43:45

and have always struggled to get enough daily protein

43:48

to actually build muscle. Luckily, all

43:50

of these problems became way more manageable

43:52

when I started getting six meals per week

43:54

from Factor. Factor, America's number

43:57

one ready to eat meal kit can help you fuel up

43:59

fast with chef. dietitian approved

44:01

ready to eat meals delivered right to your door. You'll

44:03

save time, eat well, and stay on track

44:05

with your healthy lifestyle. Too busy with your end

44:07

of summer goals to cook but want to make sure you're eating

44:10

well? With Factor, skip the extra

44:12

trip to the grocery store and the chopping, prepping,

44:14

and cleaning up too, while still getting flavor

44:17

and nutritional quality that you need. Factor's

44:19

fresh, never frozen meals are ready in just two

44:22

minutes. So all you have to do is heat and enjoy,

44:24

then get back to crushing your goals. Choose from

44:26

over 34 weekly flavor-packed,

44:28

dietitian approved meals ready in just two

44:31

minutes. Level up with gourmet plus

44:33

options, prepared to perfection by chefs, and

44:35

ready to eat in record time. Treat yourself

44:37

to upscale meals with premium ingredients

44:39

like broccolini, leeks, truffle butter, and

44:41

asparagus. Need an extra boost to support

44:44

your wellness goals? Try protein plus meals

44:46

with 30 grams of protein or more per serving.

44:48

Round out your meal and replenish your snack supply

44:50

with an assortment of more than 45 add-ons, including

44:53

breakfast items like apple cinnamon cakes and

44:55

bacon and cheddar egg bites. Or for

44:58

an easy wellness boost, try refreshing

45:00

beverage options like cold-pressed juices,

45:02

shakes, and smoothies. This August,

45:04

get Factor and enjoy eating well without

45:07

the hassle. Simply choose your meals and enjoy

45:09

fresh, flavor-packed meals delivered to

45:11

your door, ready in just two minutes. No

45:13

prep and no mess. Head to factormeals.com

45:16

slash Coleman50 and use code

45:19

Coleman50 to get 50% off. That's

45:21

code Coleman50 at factormeals.com

45:24

slash Coleman50 to get 50% off. So

45:27

in the context of the 10% less

45:29

democracy

45:30

idea, the

45:35

idea that there are certain ways in

45:37

which experts and elites

45:39

actually should wrench a little bit more

45:41

control away from public opinion

45:44

and voter control, how do you view the

45:46

influence of the electoral college? Because

45:48

it's a perpetual fantasy

45:50

of some to get rid of it, especially

45:52

when Democrats have, say, just lost an election

45:55

as a result of the electoral college

45:57

distortions or seemingly as a result.

45:59

influence your kind of view?

46:02

Well suppose let's imagine a scenario where it

46:04

happens like day of sex machinists. Suppose the Supreme Court

46:06

just declares it illegal we have to go proportional voting right?

46:08

It would just straight straight voting for the president. All

46:11

that would happen is that the vote the poll the poll

46:14

are two big political parties would just switch their positions a little

46:16

bit to win right? So I mean it would

46:18

have very little net effect I think. The big effect

46:20

of the what we need to think of with the Electoral College

46:22

is we should we should really be thinking about the European Union

46:25

when we think about the Electoral College right? The

46:27

Electoral College was a deal that was struck to get

46:29

the Constitution written and you know

46:31

if you were creating it from scratch and you didn't have to buy

46:33

off the support of nine of 13 states

46:35

you would never written the Electoral College right? It was

46:37

a gimmick that was written to get up to get the Constitution

46:40

done. Similarly in the European Union they

46:42

had to give a lot of veto

46:45

rights to individual states much stronger than our

46:47

than veto than filibusters in

46:49

the Senate just to get the European Union

46:52

going right? So sometimes we'll make big

46:54

ugly deals in order to get something going and

46:56

it's a little bit of a deus ex machina to imagine

46:59

it's a crazy counterfactual to imagine what would

47:01

it be like if that had never happened right? Like well you wouldn't

47:03

have the you I wouldn't have the EU if everybody had

47:05

to have every vote was given one equal weight.

47:08

I wouldn't have the United States and

47:10

if every vote was given equal weight. So

47:12

if it happened today if I just imagine

47:15

it what are you gonna get you're gonna give a lot less rate to work

47:17

a lot less weight to rural areas right?

47:19

Suburbs and the cities would get more weight.

47:22

I think I'd be in favor of that I think that would probably

47:24

give me better policy. I think I would probably get less

47:26

romanticization of agricultural life

47:28

and less agricultural subsidies. Do I think it would change

47:31

things dramatically? No.

47:32

So let's talk a little bit about about your

47:34

other book which is the Culture Transplant.

47:37

What what was it that drove you to become

47:40

interested in this subject of sort

47:43

of cultural assimilation the stickiness

47:46

of cultures over time the effect

47:48

of importing migrants on

47:51

the long-term culture of a

47:54

nation and so forth? Well it really

47:56

was a result in a way it's a sequel to my

47:59

first book Hive Mind.

47:59

Which is about IQ. I mean thing is that

48:02

I have a lot of there's a lot of good experimental evidence

48:04

that Intelligence has big positive

48:06

spillovers that smarter groups

48:08

are more cooperative that as my

48:11

colleague Brian Kaplan showed smarter individuals

48:13

are more likely to favor Market-oriented policies by

48:15

normal IQ measures thing is that as an economist

48:18

these are all like very short run measures, right? Something

48:20

somebody's taking a test in a lab and I'm watching them do

48:22

play a game I'm looking at the savings rates

48:25

if I'm really interested in economic growth over centuries

48:27

I need to some have some kind of measure that tells me how something

48:30

Reliably and in a trustworthy way how

48:32

something get changes over time over

48:35

centuries even decades I'd be happy

48:37

with decades and so there I couldn't tell

48:39

a lot about how IQ changed

48:41

over time Especially over things like centuries right

48:44

oldest IQ tests are about a century old So I wanted

48:46

some way to say something about growth and development and

48:48

how policies change outcomes That

48:50

looked at the very long run and it turned out there's this

48:52

whole literature that was getting built up from about 2010 onward

48:55

just as I was sort of finishing up my IQ book and This

48:59

part of this literature

48:59

looked at how migrants from different

49:02

countries behaved in America But

49:04

not just how those migrants behaved how their descendants

49:06

behave, right? So for instance, there's a new study

49:09

that's been out that shows that Second

49:11

generation migrants people who are born in the US who

49:13

come from high savings rate countries are Tend

49:16

to save more than people who come from low savings

49:18

rate countries and this is in the second generation, right?

49:20

There's similar studies showing this for in Germany

49:22

and in the UK And so people are importing

49:25

savings behavior from their countries

49:27

of origin And it's not just that the migrants

49:29

have

49:29

it It's that their children who were born in the new

49:32

country have that so this is getting

49:34

me at multi-generational questions

49:36

that I think we should be concerned about if we're interested in

49:38

like where prosperity comes from people import

49:41

part of their savings rate with them is like a good an

49:43

important finding that people should know and That's

49:46

that's the kind of information that I wanted to be able to convey

49:48

to people so that they don't fall for

49:50

these silly romantic views that people

49:52

assimilate and that the melting pot is real

49:54

and That people just become

49:57

that migrants become indistinguishable from

49:59

other folks within a generation

50:01

or two. I mean, my LDS

50:04

ancestors came from Wales. A

50:06

lot of Mormons came from Sweden.

50:09

They moved to Utah. There's still a lot of Swedish

50:11

and English and Scottish and Welsh

50:14

stuff going on in Utah, all these, you know, more

50:16

than a century later. Aren't Mormons a little bit of

50:18

a special case though, in the sense that, and

50:20

I mean, you can obviously tell me

50:22

more about this, but my perception is

50:24

that

50:25

Mormons and certain other cultures

50:27

are more invulnerable to influence

50:30

from other cultures. And that's actually a

50:32

particular feature of certain cultures, right?

50:35

Like the extreme cases, the Amish

50:37

or the ultra-orthodox, the Hasidic

50:39

Jews, that's not like the general

50:41

case of a migrant. Totally true, you're right.

50:44

That's why I like to stick with the broad generalizations

50:46

of big statistical studies, right? Like

50:49

I'll use a personal anecdote as an illustration,

50:51

but really what I should believe is the general research. And

50:54

so for instance, within Europe,

50:55

it turns out that people migrating

50:57

from one European country to another in the second

50:59

generation tend to hold attitudes

51:02

that are a lot like those back home when it comes to the proper

51:04

role of government. So do I think the government should take

51:06

care of people or do I think people should take care of

51:08

themselves? That's something that is like, probably

51:11

has an effect on how people vote, right? Probably

51:13

has an effect on people's political opinions. And how

51:15

people answer a survey question like that is moderately

51:18

carried over from the country of origin. So the

51:20

way that methodology works is you

51:22

ask people in, you

51:24

ask people in Italy, for instance, how much

51:27

should the government take care of people or should people take care of themselves?

51:29

And then you ask second generation, say Italian

51:31

Americans, should the government take care of people

51:34

or should people take care of themselves? And you see a sort of matchup.

51:36

Italian Americans a lot like Italians in Italy in the

51:38

second generation. So when you say a lot like, I mean,

51:40

I'm trying to remember the figures from your book,

51:43

but you were talking about correlations of

51:45

like between 0.5 and 0.25 or something. Something

51:48

like that, yeah. So like you get some that are higher

51:51

and some that are lower. So I would say

51:53

like, yeah, 0.25 to 0.5. So

51:55

I would say, I think of those as explaining, say, a

51:57

quarter to a half of the data by normal measures.

52:00

So so there's there's too much

52:02

to ignore and even when we have

52:04

evidence from up until the fourth generation Which

52:08

doesn't come in on a lot of studies, but it does come in and

52:10

one study of trust Even there

52:12

the you get this sort of 40% persistence Lasting

52:15

into about the fourth generation on people bringing

52:18

their home country attitudes toward trust to

52:20

their new country So there and I also

52:22

learned from your book there

52:24

on different traits. There's a different

52:26

levels of persistence So for example general

52:28

trust seems to be kind of persistent

52:31

Savings rates seem to be persistent,

52:34

but religion strangers Attitudes

52:38

toward whether women should work doesn't is that

52:40

persistent a priori I

52:42

would expect that to to be the opposite.

52:44

I would expect religion to be one of the

52:46

most persistent and say

52:49

like saving savings rate to

52:51

be Kind of environmentally

52:53

contingent or even trust level to be environment I

52:56

mean environmentally contingent I can picture

52:58

taking someone from a very

53:00

high crime low trust environment If

53:02

they move to Sweden and they realize actually

53:04

everyone is nice here I can finally afford

53:07

to be trusting it

53:08

would seem within one Trenton within

53:10

one generation

53:11

You would get a more trust trust

53:14

trusting person What is your theory

53:16

of why those certain traits don't persist

53:18

which traits persist in which don't yeah? That's

53:21

I'm glad to speculate on it. I will say

53:23

that for instance There's here's one that doesn't

53:25

persist at all is basically can I trust the police and

53:28

that fits what you're saying? Does it where it's like it's

53:30

what happens right around you on the police from

53:32

our trustworthy in some places than in others? And

53:35

your opinion is mostly shaped based on what you're

53:37

seeing right in front of you, right? So it's an opinion

53:39

of somebody else right a sort of can

53:41

I trust my local government might be much something?

53:44

That's much more that moves with the country that you're

53:46

in also language is not very persistent Exactly

53:48

you're not gonna find a generation is

53:50

really high right third generation that

53:52

um, so thanks the home Leah

53:55

Buston in her research she

53:57

makes a big point of the fact that in the among Among

54:00

US migrants in the second generation, there's a lot of

54:02

name assimilation, right? And further

54:04

on, I'm sure there's even more in name assimilation. And so

54:06

you can imagine sometimes it's something as simple

54:08

as I want my kid to fit in in school, right? I

54:11

don't want my kid to get picked on. So, and it's unfortunate

54:13

the kids do that, but that ends up shaping some assimilation

54:15

as fear of the other. So I don't

54:17

have a grand ultimate theory, but I do know

54:19

that some of the ones that do fit line up

54:22

with things that look more

54:24

like simple economic parameters, right? So

54:26

in economics, we have this one idea that actually

54:28

I first learned from Austrian economics, the idea of the rate

54:31

of time preference, how patient a person is, how much

54:33

you give thought for the morrow. And that

54:35

seems to be something that people sort of carry with them from

54:37

one country to another, that sort of rate of patience,

54:39

that's going to be shaping your level of frugality.

54:42

Like how much, you know, do I spend on things

54:44

right now? Do I help out my family right now? Do

54:46

I help out my loved ones right now? Or do I say no, I

54:48

got to say no to that because there's something might

54:50

happen in the future. What do you make of the fact

54:52

that

54:53

people that leave a country to go to another

54:55

country are in the general case, let's say

54:57

economic migrants are a very

54:59

non-random sample of the countries that they come

55:02

from. And therefore, you

55:04

know, naively, I wouldn't necessarily

55:06

expect there to be a big correlation. Well,

55:09

it may be as simple as the basic. So

55:11

let's be optimistic about this, which is

55:13

fair enough here. Let's assume that the people who come to America

55:16

are on average, like, you know, in the top third of

55:18

the countries they're coming from, right? Like it's plausible,

55:21

right? But then they'll

55:23

each be the top third of their own country and

55:25

their countries will each differ on those traits. So

55:27

my hunch would be, for instance, that say second

55:30

generation Italian Americans

55:32

will be more trusting than other Italians

55:35

and but still less trusting than the

55:37

Swedish Americans. Right. So and that

55:39

actually is what ends up happening in the data when you look around.

55:42

So basically, we're getting the selection ends up,

55:44

in many cases, bumping people up, but you still get

55:47

the correlation. So it's a, if you think in old

55:49

high school algebra terms, y equals mx plus b,

55:51

we're shifting up the slope, but we're we're

55:53

we're keeping the same slope, but we're shifting the intercept.

55:55

So let's say I come from a very low

55:57

trust country, probably a country where

55:59

it makes sense to be low trust. And

56:02

then I moved to my sort

56:04

of an immigrant enclave in the new country. So

56:07

for example, to take my grandparents

56:09

from Puerto Rico, moved to the South Bronx

56:11

in the late 50s.

56:13

They are now in a neighborhood,

56:16

largely with other people from low trust

56:18

countries and in context where it

56:20

still makes sense to be low trust. Now, if you

56:22

measure the trust of the entire country,

56:25

you're gonna say, well, these are the low trust migrants

56:28

have remained low trust. They're bringing

56:30

their culture with them, but they are bringing

56:32

their culture with them in the sense that they are around the same

56:34

people from the mother country. So

56:36

it kind of, they haven't really necessarily moved

56:39

into yet the segment of society

56:41

where it no longer makes sense to be

56:43

low trust. They're still in the immigrant enclave.

56:46

So what would be interesting to me is if you could

56:48

parse the difference between say, and

56:50

to keep with the example, the

56:53

descendants of Puerto Ricans that have now

56:55

moved to places in the country that

56:57

have no crime, that are high income, do

57:00

they remain low trust relative

57:02

to their peers or relative

57:04

to the Puerto Ricans that stay in

57:07

immigrant enclaves with other Puerto Ricans

57:09

who are all from a low trust mother

57:11

country? So A, that's an important question,

57:13

but B, if I'm writing a non-utopian

57:15

book, I don't wanna spend that much of my time

57:17

thinking about scenarios that aren't actually

57:20

happening, right? If for instance,

57:22

it is very common for folks to stay in ethnic conflict,

57:24

conclaves, and that keeps down their

57:26

trust to their initial country of origin levels,

57:29

that's something I want to report, right? So

57:31

there might be a reason why assimilate, if merely

57:34

finding a reason why assimilation is not happening

57:36

doesn't mean assimilation is happening, right? No, but

57:38

it does importantly changes the causal

57:40

mechanism because under one reading,

57:43

the

57:43

thesis is just that immigrants

57:45

don't assimilate full stop. Culture

57:48

is sticky. The culture of your mother, of your parents

57:50

just goes to you with high likelihood regardless

57:53

of what happens in the country

57:55

you're moving to. The other

57:57

would say, well, no, there's nothing inherent.

57:59

and it's definitely sticky about culture.

58:02

It's the fact that if you create

58:05

a little Puerto Rico in the new place you go to,

58:07

you're gonna stay very similar to Puerto Rican.

58:09

Whereas if you actually move to a different

58:12

environment where you are now a minority

58:15

shoulder to shoulder with a totally different

58:17

culture, your kids will turn out like the

58:19

new culture, not the old one. Those are very different

58:21

causal mechanisms. Those are, you're right. Yeah. Absolutely.

58:24

Yeah. I mean, some of this- And one would, I mean,

58:26

so like, the second causal

58:28

mechanism would imply

58:29

that low rates of immigration

58:32

properly handled so as to avoid

58:34

enclaves would actually lead

58:36

to like, more

58:39

assimilation per person than high rates

58:42

of immigration that you allow to

58:44

become enclaves, for example.

58:46

In some cases, I might not want assimilation,

58:48

right? If I'm bringing in folks who are higher savings

58:51

rates, who have higher savings

58:53

rates and better attitudes toward government, I don't want

58:55

them assimilating to the crummy attitudes of other Americans,

58:58

right? My longstanding claim is that I believe

59:00

in open borders for anyone

59:02

who believes in Uber surge pricing,

59:05

right? And if I give

59:07

instant green cards and instant voting rights to anyone who

59:09

comes to America and believes in Uber, just because

59:11

they believe in Uber surge pricing, I don't want them coming to

59:13

America and getting contaminated by the

59:15

crummy anti-market views of the average American.

59:18

So there's, so notice we quickly

59:20

have to start having to quickly become social planners

59:23

once we're going down the path you're describing. And I don't

59:25

object to trying it out as an example, right?

59:27

As a mental exercise. But if

59:30

my goal is to make America the best

59:32

country it can be, I want to bring in folks who have

59:34

better attitudes than the folks who've got here. Not just

59:36

people who are no worse than the current folks.

59:39

Yeah, so let's talk about open

59:41

borders because this actually, in my

59:43

view, connects to both of your books. One

59:46

of the

59:46

problems that I've highlighted

59:49

with open borders in the past is

59:51

that it takes immigration policy

59:54

out of democratic control. That's actually,

59:57

it may not be a problem according to your view, but

59:59

it's a, it's.

59:59

It's a fact. The people who come to this

1:00:02

country on the southern border are not determined

1:00:04

by the voters or by the representatives of

1:00:06

the voters, but largely by the push

1:00:08

factors in Central America. If

1:00:11

there's a civil war in Guatemala tomorrow,

1:00:14

a lot of people are going to flee and they're going to end up

1:00:16

in Texas and Arizona, right? Because

1:00:19

we don't have great border control. We don't

1:00:21

have very solid border control there. If

1:00:23

I were someone that was very pro-democracy

1:00:25

and felt everything should be under

1:00:28

Democratic control, I would want a

1:00:29

very strong border so that the

1:00:32

profile of immigrants that come to the country

1:00:34

are decided by the voters, just like we

1:00:36

would decide healthcare policy or school

1:00:39

funding or anything like that. So, if you

1:00:41

would agree with me that currently our de

1:00:43

facto immigration policy is out of Democratic

1:00:46

control, nor is it in expert

1:00:48

control, for example, what would be

1:00:50

the implications of

1:00:53

having a strong border for our

1:00:55

immigration policy? Of

1:00:58

bringing it under Democratic control, in other words.

1:00:59

To point out, if the

1:01:02

idea is that anything that changes our country a lot

1:01:04

should be under Democratic control, then we're going

1:01:06

to have to have the government in charge of fertility policy and I

1:01:08

definitely don't want that, right? Who are all these people having kids

1:01:10

without government permits? I definitely don't want

1:01:12

that. So, there are a lot of personal decisions that

1:01:14

should be not under government control. And

1:01:16

so, part of being in a democracy is,

1:01:19

part of living in a country that has something like a bill of rights

1:01:21

is saying there are certain rights that

1:01:23

we all agree on that are just outside of

1:01:25

debate. And so, one question is, should certain forms

1:01:28

of migration be outside of debate, just

1:01:30

like what religion you are as part of debate, out of debate,

1:01:32

thank goodness. So right now, we have open borders between

1:01:34

all 50 states, right? If

1:01:36

there's really high crime in Washington DC and people

1:01:38

decide to move to Northern Virginia, nothing people in Northern Virginia

1:01:41

can do about that, right? So we just live with that. That's

1:01:43

just part of the deal. Again, that's part of the 1789 deal in a way, right? So,

1:01:47

if now, take your hypothetical seriously

1:01:49

though. If the United States

1:01:51

were like literally able to be in

1:01:54

control of the southern border and could, basically

1:01:56

it would be just like coming in at the airport at LaGuardia,

1:01:58

right? They can decide whether what the deal is with

1:02:00

each individual person who comes in. It seems pretty obvious

1:02:03

that the American voters

1:02:05

would still favor a pretty

1:02:07

soft family reunification policy. The

1:02:09

average American really likes for families

1:02:12

to be together. So I suspect that in terms

1:02:14

of net total flows, if we

1:02:16

actually had voters in charge, we would

1:02:18

have a lot of people would be continuing

1:02:20

to come from Mexico

1:02:23

and to some extent from Central America, more or less

1:02:26

matching the flows of people who've arrived in the last

1:02:28

generation or two. And American voters have been

1:02:30

really unwilling to separate families

1:02:32

or to say like your sick grandpa or your uncle

1:02:34

or your nephew who's trying to go to college shouldn't

1:02:37

be allowed to come in. So I actually have my doubts about

1:02:39

whether the total flows would change that

1:02:41

much. I mean, I'm just speculating here, but American

1:02:43

voters are a bunch of softies deep down. They

1:02:46

might not like, they don't seem to like seeing

1:02:48

a lot of chaotic activity in

1:02:51

border towns. They feel sorry for the people in those border towns and

1:02:53

what they have to put up with. If you regularize that, can

1:02:55

you imagine them saying like you can't bring your two year

1:02:57

old kid along to America? No, I can't.

1:03:00

Yeah. I think that I can definitely, I can definitely

1:03:04

imagine Americans voting for a

1:03:06

de facto, like tough

1:03:08

for a single male economic migrant

1:03:10

to get access with no, with no family.

1:03:12

Yeah, you're right. You would probably get a lot less of that. And

1:03:15

I mean, it might be, I mean, if I were just speculating,

1:03:17

it would probably be more female biased. The

1:03:19

voters would probably be more, you know, more open to creating

1:03:22

opportunities for female migrants, partly

1:03:25

because bias is against men overall, right? Men do

1:03:27

commit a lot more, you know, like 10 times the violent

1:03:29

crime of women, right? So, and,

1:03:31

and a lot of family reunification. And if a lot

1:03:33

of that family reunification is folks who are, you know,

1:03:35

under 25, they're going to be raising families here too. So

1:03:38

I just have a hunch about that, that like, that might not change things much.

1:03:40

I mean, that wouldn't be my utopian policy from

1:03:42

the point of view of making America the best nation it

1:03:44

could be forever might be part of it. How

1:03:47

big is the gap between public opinion on immigration

1:03:50

policy

1:03:50

and economist opinion

1:03:52

on immigration policy? Oh, this is, this

1:03:54

is, this is one where I can't really, I

1:03:56

don't really know what economist opinion is for real on

1:03:58

immigration policy because all the.

1:03:59

questions are phrased in weird

1:04:02

ways when economists get asked them. And I think there's

1:04:04

some Straussian stuff going on, some like hiding

1:04:06

of their true views. So I mean,

1:04:09

it does seem as though, you know, economists

1:04:11

are very excited about high skilled immigration. So

1:04:14

economists, I mean, like a lot of policy

1:04:16

activists and entrepreneurs, they are aware

1:04:18

of the fact that you're a lot more likely to get a lot of

1:04:20

positive externalities, lots of positive

1:04:23

spillover effects, more on the things that

1:04:25

they'll highlight, not precisely what I'll highlight

1:04:28

is you'll get a lot more people who are

1:04:30

scientists, engineers, you have less,

1:04:32

fewer fiscal concerns about people taking more out

1:04:34

of the public till than they're putting in. In

1:04:37

fact, it's the other like they might be putting in much, much more, right?

1:04:39

This is one of the things I try to have to remind people of when

1:04:41

we're talking about immigration policy. Why not the best?

1:04:44

What? I mean, there are a lot of people who'd like to

1:04:46

come to America. Why not bring in the folks who are going to pay 10 times

1:04:48

more in taxes than they're going to drain out

1:04:50

so they can take some of the burden off of me. So

1:04:52

I think that some version of high skilled

1:04:54

immigration seems to get a lot of support from

1:04:57

economists because it has clear positive spillovers

1:04:59

for the whole economy and it eliminates a

1:05:02

lot of concerns about being any kind of drain

1:05:04

on the fiscal, on the FISC. Concerns

1:05:06

about low skilled immigration, drawing on the

1:05:09

government's debt or maybe overrated some it

1:05:11

gets a little complicated, but why not just pick the thing

1:05:13

that's not debated at all?

1:05:15

So when you talk about the importance

1:05:17

of trust and the stickiness of attitudes towards

1:05:19

trust among migrants and immigrants,

1:05:22

your colleague, Brian Kaplan, who wrote a book called

1:05:25

Open Borders for which I had him on the

1:05:27

podcast a while ago at this point, he

1:05:29

made the point in that book that ironically,

1:05:32

like democracy, there may be a kind

1:05:34

of lafer curve for trust where like a

1:05:37

certain amount, there's an optimal amount. Yeah,

1:05:39

there isn't. There isn't. So you disagree with that

1:05:41

study wrong. She read that study wrong. Okay.

1:05:44

Well, just just briefly.

1:05:45

If you look at income levels across countries, it's like this. He

1:05:47

picked something weird. Okay. So

1:05:49

I think what he said in that book was like, if you look at the highest trust

1:05:51

states, like the Dakotas, they're not the highest productivity

1:05:54

states. Yeah. Whereas New York,

1:05:56

Boston. The US things are kind of weird. Yeah. Okay.

1:05:59

How does that all hang together though?

1:06:02

Yeah, I mean,

1:06:03

part of it is that trust is

1:06:05

only one part of my story. So I

1:06:07

think it's better to spend more

1:06:09

of our time on the things that are really easy to measure

1:06:11

concretely, like savings rates, and something where

1:06:14

we know it's more likely to have an effect on

1:06:16

policy, like your view on the role of government. So

1:06:18

yeah, it's a reminder that there's more than one thing

1:06:20

going on. The Dakotas

1:06:23

are not a great place for people to take on high productivity

1:06:26

projects. And so you have some folks there

1:06:28

who tend to come from ethnic groups that are quite

1:06:30

high trust. A lot of people of Scandinavian descent

1:06:32

who by any measure are on top of these ratings on

1:06:34

trust. But entrepreneurs

1:06:37

aren't excited to launch the highest productivity

1:06:40

projects there unless it

1:06:42

comes to fracking. So yeah,

1:06:44

the coastal cities have been

1:06:47

magnets for high innovation

1:06:49

projects, and they get the

1:06:51

benefits of American institutions that are created by

1:06:53

people all across America, that are voted on by

1:06:56

politicians all across America. And

1:06:58

that's great. Yeah, it's just

1:07:00

a reminder that when you're looking within

1:07:03

the United States, the amount of variation

1:07:05

is restricted in a way. You're looking

1:07:07

at one of the best places in the world. Let me tell you what it's

1:07:09

like, actually. Here's one of my favorite correlations.

1:07:11

You hear this all the time online. Do you know that within the

1:07:13

NBA, there's no correlation between height

1:07:15

and how good you are at the sport? Yeah. So

1:07:18

basically, America is one big country like that. There's

1:07:20

a term for this. Is it a restricted range

1:07:22

problem? It's not just restricted range,

1:07:24

right? It's because so you're right

1:07:27

about that restriction range is a big problem in a lot

1:07:29

of statistics. That's when you're only looking at a group

1:07:31

of super smart people so that the correlations get

1:07:33

weaker. That could be the whole story here. But I

1:07:35

have a hunch that it's more than that. When we talk

1:07:37

about the NBA case, it's that the reason you're letting

1:07:39

the NBA is because you're good, not because you're high.

1:07:42

So height does help. But there are other people who are really

1:07:44

good at doing great things in the NBA who do

1:07:46

make it up through some other way than height. So basically, it's

1:07:48

that X anti selection. So I don't

1:07:50

know if that's what I doubt that's really what's going on in

1:07:53

the US like what is the economic

1:07:56

engine of the United States has always,

1:07:58

you know, New York has always

1:07:59

New York City since it's its Central

1:08:02

Chicago. Yeah. Yeah. And even New York, just

1:08:04

compared to all of the other early cities was clearly,

1:08:07

it was different from Boston and Philadelphia. I

1:08:09

would assume it's always been lower trust than Boston

1:08:11

and Philadelphia too. I don't know that that's true.

1:08:14

Yeah, it seems plausible. Yeah. It seems plausible just

1:08:16

because of the history of New York and the, the

1:08:18

grittiness, the immigration, the

1:08:20

quote unquote unwashed masses, the

1:08:23

crime, the crime, Ellis Island, everything,

1:08:25

right? But notice the institutions that

1:08:27

New York lives under are designed in the United

1:08:29

States as

1:08:29

a whole, right? They're living under the constitution. They

1:08:32

appeal to federal courts that are no part

1:08:34

of which, you know, New Yorkers are only a small

1:08:37

part of the federal judiciary and the people voting for the federal

1:08:39

judiciary. So part of my story is that

1:08:41

voters in the Midwest, voters in Wyoming, voters

1:08:44

in Texas, they're all building this America

1:08:47

and the American institutions that New Yorkers

1:08:49

get to take advantage of. I mean, I was just walking around town this

1:08:51

morning and I saw, I saw a US federal court, right? Right

1:08:53

down there, just a couple of blocks Southeast here. And

1:08:56

that US federal court exists through

1:08:58

the legal, through the voting

1:08:59

behavior of people far from New

1:09:02

York. They're building the institutions. I would agree with

1:09:04

that. So New Yorkers are building a small part of American institutions. I

1:09:06

agree with that. At the same time,

1:09:08

if I, if I think of the

1:09:11

prototype of the ambitious entrepreneur

1:09:14

who can flourish best

1:09:16

in a high trust system with courts and

1:09:19

enforcement of contracts and so forth, nevertheless,

1:09:21

that ambitious entrepreneur is not a particularly

1:09:24

high trust person. And in

1:09:26

some ways is kind of a low trust person. So

1:09:29

how does that hang together? Is it that

1:09:31

the ambitious entrepreneurs that,

1:09:34

who provide the kind of energy exists

1:09:37

best within paradoxically a very high

1:09:39

trust, predictable system that is sort

1:09:41

of in some way run by people that

1:09:43

are unlike him? I'm a big fan of the view

1:09:45

that trust is a large party measure

1:09:48

of trustworthiness. And a large, a lot

1:09:50

of what you need to run in a society is

1:09:52

you don't need people who are trusting. What you need is people who

1:09:54

are trustworthy, right? And so an entrepreneur

1:09:57

who's skeptical of other people still would prefer to

1:09:59

work with people who. be trusted and don't have to be

1:10:01

monitored that much, right? A whole lot of game theory,

1:10:03

a whole lot of information economics is about the

1:10:05

so-called principal agent problems. Like how can I lend

1:10:07

a hundred dollars to somebody to take on a project

1:10:10

and be pretty sure the person is going to actually work on

1:10:12

the project? How can I hire an employee to

1:10:14

work at the yogurt shop and not have the guy just

1:10:16

give away yogurt to all his friends? You need some trustworthiness

1:10:19

in order to make the yogurt shop work. Otherwise, you're going

1:10:21

to have to put in cameras. So having

1:10:23

employees who are relatively trustworthy,

1:10:26

having business partners who are relatively trustworthy,

1:10:28

turn out to be an important part of

1:10:30

being able to run a business, many businesses at least,

1:10:33

in an efficient way. And so if we treat trust

1:10:35

as a proxy for trustworthiness in many cases,

1:10:38

you'll see something important there. That shows up in a fair amount of the

1:10:40

literature.

1:10:40

So one really interesting fact from your

1:10:42

book was that the cultural

1:10:45

differences which are sticky, such as

1:10:47

trustworthiness and some of the others

1:10:49

you mentioned, savings rates,

1:10:51

are much more sticky from mother to child

1:10:53

than from father to child. Yeah, that's one

1:10:55

study that shows that. I found another one after the book came

1:10:58

out that found the same thing. Yeah.

1:11:00

So is that just a function of the common

1:11:02

sense point that a lot of fathers aren't around,

1:11:04

fathers are more likely to disappear?

1:11:07

Or is it actually, is

1:11:09

it the case that even in split culture

1:11:12

families, you're inheriting more of your

1:11:14

mother's culture somehow? I've

1:11:16

got two studies now finding this, right? And I

1:11:18

can't say that's definitive, right? We shouldn't be, we

1:11:20

like five or 10

1:11:21

or something run with different data sets.

1:11:24

But to me, A, I think

1:11:26

the first thing I'll say is that the idea of fathers

1:11:28

being completely absent isn't enough, that's not

1:11:30

happening enough in the data for the matter. B,

1:11:32

it does raise the likelihood that this

1:11:34

really is a cultural, child

1:11:37

rearing environment you're in

1:11:39

kind of phenomenon, right? Rather than, rather

1:11:41

they, what some might think is, hey,

1:11:44

a lot of this stuff must just be genetic. It's just

1:11:46

code for genetics. And I'm sure it is. A lot of people online

1:11:48

will tell, will say this, right? The fact that this is

1:11:50

showing up mother to child

1:11:51

is really a strong sign that

1:11:53

like the hundreds of hours of parenting

1:11:56

are changing how the child turns out and

1:11:58

how that child treats others. At least on those days.

1:11:59

At least on those dimensions. I don't know if that's going to be true

1:12:02

with savings, right? I don't know if that's going to be true with

1:12:04

views toward government, but at least it should

1:12:06

be opening my mind toward it, right? So

1:12:08

how would this interact with the body of research,

1:12:12

which has generally found

1:12:14

that, so not

1:12:16

talking about the genetic influence from parent to child,

1:12:18

but

1:12:19

the rest of the variants that most

1:12:21

of that comes from the quote unquote

1:12:24

non-shared environment. Non-shared environment, right? Right. The

1:12:27

mystery of sight, right? The shared

1:12:29

environment would by definition be like the home and the

1:12:31

parent, but to the extent

1:12:33

your case you're

1:12:35

making is true, that would imply that maybe

1:12:38

more of the shared environment is having

1:12:40

an influence on kids than like

1:12:42

Judith Rich Hill

1:12:44

would have said. So for instance, I mean, one

1:12:46

area where shared environment turns out to matter more than

1:12:49

a lot of people would suspect if they know behavioral genetics

1:12:51

is actually education, for instance, right?

1:12:53

It doesn't show up as much with IQ, but it does

1:12:56

show up with education, years of education. And

1:12:58

education does seem to have some causal effects.

1:13:01

So basically what family you get adopted into has some

1:13:03

effect on how much education. If you get

1:13:05

adopted into a really smart family with a lot of education,

1:13:07

you probably get more education. I'm adopted myself, so

1:13:09

I can kind of, I live a lot of the behavioral genetics

1:13:12

literature on a daily basis. But that,

1:13:15

we're pretty sure by now that education

1:13:17

does have a causal effect on say social attitudes,

1:13:20

on like multicultural type, wokeness attitudes

1:13:22

in a way, you might say. Not too much on economic

1:13:25

policy issues, but on these sort of social issues.

1:13:28

Similarly, it looks like this trust, trust may be

1:13:30

another one where just your acculturation matters.

1:13:33

And to go back to something you said earlier, right? Language

1:13:35

is obviously something where the

1:13:37

local culture you're in matters a huge amount, right?

1:13:40

You end up speaking a language that you're raised around. And so figuring

1:13:43

out which the culture

1:13:45

transplant ends up discussing a lot of attitudes

1:13:47

that are along this continuum of things that are heavily

1:13:50

culturally influenced, like the language you speak, to

1:13:52

things that normal

1:13:53

behavioral genetics people would say,

1:13:56

you know, a lot of that's got to be genetic. And

1:13:58

so, but we've got things all over the map.

1:13:59

here. And I'm

1:14:02

hoping that this ends up turning into an area of

1:14:04

future research for behavioral

1:14:06

geneticists, for anthropologists,

1:14:08

for social scientists, trying to figure out

1:14:11

which cultural traits persist and why over

1:14:13

the generations.

1:14:15

So it's my understanding that Mormons have

1:14:17

very high savings rates. Is that correct?

1:14:19

You know, like higher than the American average? I

1:14:22

actually don't know about that. I mean, they're really

1:14:24

good at tithing, right? But I've seen data

1:14:26

to that effect.

1:14:28

And you said you grew up Mormon.

1:14:30

Yeah. Are you still

1:14:32

Mormon? No, no, I went to BYU, I had a great

1:14:34

experience there. Was Mormon missionary

1:14:37

for four months and decided I didn't

1:14:39

believe in it, but decided that Mormons were

1:14:41

still better than the average American. So I didn't like

1:14:43

leave Mormonism and say, Oh, you guys are bad. I left

1:14:45

Mormonism saying, wow, you guys are maybe better than me.

1:14:48

Yeah. So I just don't. Well,

1:14:50

you know, the high social capital is really

1:14:52

fantastic, right? The fact that loneliness

1:14:55

among the elderly is really, really diminished among

1:14:57

Latter-day Saints just by having congregations

1:15:00

that are just the right size where people see each other on a regular

1:15:02

basis socialize a little bit, but not too much. They

1:15:04

really seem to have hit a sweet spot of basically

1:15:07

finding a strong community. And

1:15:09

then also the fact that the church

1:15:11

is really run by volunteers means that

1:15:13

even young people are given small to

1:15:15

medium size opportunities for leadership.

1:15:18

So it really is a good leadership training process.

1:15:20

And I think those are both really

1:15:23

important. The fact that the LDS

1:15:25

have this missionary program that gets young people to

1:15:27

go learn a language and try something kind of crazy when they're 19,

1:15:29

that has big social

1:15:31

pluses too. You end up building a lot of social capital,

1:15:33

but not just social capital in this sort of touchy

1:15:36

feely sense, but organizational capital. It's no surprise

1:15:38

to me that the Latter-day Saints do well working in a lot of organizations.

1:15:41

So I've never been a Mormon that wasn't very

1:15:44

nice. Yeah, yeah, it's a culturated.

1:15:46

And so you look at it and you're like, well, maybe

1:15:48

it's because a lot of them are from England and maybe there's some

1:15:50

kind of normal culture transplant thing going on

1:15:52

there, like Swedes or whatever. Maybe

1:15:55

it's that kind of thing going on.

1:15:58

because

1:16:00

I'm sure if you took the other immigrants

1:16:02

from those same places, they would not measure

1:16:04

up to Mormons in terms of niceness, community

1:16:07

ties, close-knitness.

1:16:09

Getting

1:16:10

five, six hours a week of practice in different church

1:16:12

meetings, behaving that way for

1:16:15

decades probably has a payoff, right? So

1:16:17

when you decided you didn't believe

1:16:19

anymore, what triggered that? I was really

1:16:22

driven by religious epistemology. So

1:16:25

I took the LDS truth claim

1:16:27

seriously, and I weighed them. There

1:16:30

are two key claims, right? One is you can learn

1:16:32

the truth of the religion through a private

1:16:34

spiritual experience. Mormons often use the term testimony

1:16:36

for that. The second is, boy, the Book of

1:16:38

Mormon's really hard to explain. So there

1:16:41

you get something much more like Christian apologetics. Does

1:16:43

this book look like a miracle? So I spent some

1:16:45

time figuring out whether the personal

1:16:47

spiritual experience was a valid way of learning the truth.

1:16:50

And I ultimately decided it wasn't. I had too many

1:16:52

good spiritual experiences toward other faiths

1:16:54

to

1:16:55

keep it short there.

1:16:56

And on the Book of Mormon, similarly, I

1:16:58

realized a little bit like the unmanned aerial

1:17:01

phenomenon thing. I realized I don't quite

1:17:03

know how this book was written, but it doesn't seem like

1:17:05

it has to be a miracle. And there are a lot of other books

1:17:07

that are written in really impressive ways, often

1:17:09

through a method called automatic writing, where people get in trance-like

1:17:12

states and dictate all books. So some

1:17:14

books get dictated by automatic writing, it turns out,

1:17:16

trance-like states where people write books that seem

1:17:18

like it was beyond their capability.

1:17:20

I don't have an explanation for how automatic writing works.

1:17:22

I just know people can write non-miraculous books with it.

1:17:24

Apparently, Jane Eyre, one of the Bronte sisters,

1:17:27

was wrote that way. So yeah, learning that

1:17:29

the world was intellectually more complex than

1:17:32

I knew at a young age, and learning that

1:17:34

spiritual experiences were kind of a dime a dozen,

1:17:36

those were formative experiences, and that's what pushed me

1:17:38

out. How old were you when?

1:17:40

I was 19. I was knocking doors as a missionary one

1:17:42

day.

1:17:43

I was like, hm, nice people.

1:17:45

Have you ever seen the Book of Mormon? Oh, yeah, I went

1:17:47

and saw it while I was still in previews, the musical, yeah, yeah. How

1:17:49

did you feel about it? I mean, I thought it was good

1:17:51

fun. So it was too optimistic at the

1:17:54

end, because at the end, they say, kind of

1:17:56

the message at the end of the Book of Mormon, the musical, to spoil

1:17:58

it, is, well.

1:17:59

We're just going to have a new made up book and

1:18:02

we don't need to believe it anymore. And our religion

1:18:04

won't have any rules now, but we'll still be nice Mormons.

1:18:07

And it was the idea that you can take

1:18:10

the parts of religion out that you don't like and

1:18:12

keep the rest and the religion will still stay there. I'm

1:18:14

a big fan of what's known as the strict church theory

1:18:16

of Rodney Stark, my former colleague, Larry Anaconey.

1:18:19

The reason organized religions work is

1:18:21

because they have some rules. They weed out the people

1:18:23

who are just going to free ride, who are not

1:18:25

going to give anything to the community. And so the

1:18:27

strict church theory, I think holds up pretty well. You

1:18:29

need to have a religion with rules in order to make it, in

1:18:31

order to get people to contribute to the public good.

1:18:34

To bring, a religion needs to weed

1:18:36

out the people who bring potato chips to the church

1:18:38

potluck and they need to weed in the people who

1:18:40

bring good casseroles to the potluck. And a

1:18:43

little bit of fear of God is one way to get people to bring a

1:18:45

good casserole to the potluck. If I think of my

1:18:48

friends who are, for example, reformed

1:18:50

Jews,

1:18:51

and I grew up in a heavily Jewish area,

1:18:54

they seem to have a sense

1:18:57

of community without any sense of fear

1:18:59

of God. Yeah. Is that

1:19:01

an exception that proves a rule or is there some

1:19:04

way that that works into the strict church

1:19:07

theory? Without knowing, I mean,

1:19:09

I've

1:19:10

learned something about reformed Judaism over time.

1:19:12

I find it very appealing. And the

1:19:14

idea of trying to keep the best parts of your faith while

1:19:16

adapting to modernity. I think the strictness,

1:19:19

if I can speculate on this, just wildly without

1:19:21

any expertise, it's that reformed

1:19:24

Judaism is held together by the need to

1:19:26

keep Judaism alive. Reform

1:19:28

Jews, like most

1:19:30

Jews the world over, know that it's really important

1:19:33

to make sacrifices to keep Judaism

1:19:35

alive. They know that there are forces in the world

1:19:37

that would absolutely love for very

1:19:39

evil reasons

1:19:40

to destroy Judaism as a whole. And

1:19:43

I think that gets a level of commitment and it gives a

1:19:45

willingness to sacrifice for the group

1:19:47

that very few, that perhaps no other religion can

1:19:50

muster up in this world. And there may be a confound

1:19:53

of just the historical consciousness

1:19:55

that Jewish people have, the

1:19:57

recency of the Holocaust, the fact that

1:19:59

it

1:19:59

that in many ways is an ethnicity as well.

1:20:02

So those things may help hold it together in a

1:20:04

way that- It gives enough focal points for people to know. So

1:20:06

that it maybe doesn't need fear

1:20:08

of God. It's possible, it's possible that's

1:20:10

what's going on. Knowing that

1:20:12

there are people around the world currently, hopefully

1:20:15

small in number, who would like to destroy you, but that there

1:20:17

recently have been incredibly powerful people

1:20:19

trying to destroy you. That creates, that

1:20:21

solves, I think, the strict church theory

1:20:24

in a way that I hope no one ever has to solve

1:20:26

again. So I'm assuming you're an atheist

1:20:28

now at this point. I'm an atheist enough,

1:20:29

yeah.

1:20:31

So do you have kids? No, no.

1:20:33

So if you did have kids, and given

1:20:36

that you have this kind of strict church

1:20:38

theory, like you sort of can't get the good without

1:20:40

the, I don't know if you would say bad

1:20:43

necessarily, but without like the dogma,

1:20:45

enforced, socially enforced dogma, would

1:20:48

you want to raise your kids in a context

1:20:50

to get the nice aspects of, say, Mormonism?

1:20:53

Would you just bite the bullet and say, okay, well,

1:20:55

I'm not gonna

1:20:57

inculcate them about the skepticism of the faith

1:21:00

because I want them to enjoy the boons of the community.

1:21:02

How do you think that you would manage that trade-off?

1:21:05

No, I think that if I were in a situation

1:21:07

like that, I would have found some sort of soft religious

1:21:10

commitment that was easy to drift in and out

1:21:12

of on some level, but that would give my kids

1:21:14

a religious background. So, and it might

1:21:16

actually have been Reformed Judaism. I have my maternal

1:21:19

grandmother, a blessed memory was Jewish. And

1:21:22

so I also have some interest in, say,

1:21:25

Anglo-Catholic Anglicanism. So

1:21:27

Catholicism, some sort of

1:21:30

Christmas and Easter Catholicism could have been appealing. I

1:21:32

don't know what path it would have taken me, but definitely something

1:21:34

that exposed, like I might, here's

1:21:37

the secret story. The secret story is I would

1:21:39

want to, it would only be worth my time if

1:21:41

it would end up also teaching them some of

1:21:43

the, you know, greats of the Western humanistic

1:21:45

tradition, right? So if they

1:21:47

end up reading the Bible along the way,

1:21:50

ended up being exposed to great art along the way and

1:21:52

great music, that really makes it worthwhile. Because

1:21:54

I feel like the humanities training that I got from

1:21:56

being raised LDS, from getting to read the scriptures

1:21:59

at a young age.

1:21:59

and for being exposed to good music of

1:22:02

a variety of eras. That was really valuable

1:22:04

and I wouldn't have gotten it otherwise. Okay, so

1:22:07

I guess that brings me to the end of my questions for now. It's

1:22:10

been great to have you on. Before I let you go, where

1:22:12

should I direct

1:22:13

my followers that may want to encounter some more

1:22:16

of your work? Sure.

1:22:18

My website is easy to find. It's jonesgarrett.com

1:22:21

and my Twitter, I'm Garrett Jones.

1:22:24

And easy to find there. One R,

1:22:26

two Ts. If you type two Rs, you'll find

1:22:28

the former Yankees player. I think I did

1:22:30

that. Yeah, Garrett with one R is me. All

1:22:33

right. Thanks so much, Garrett. Thanks for having me.

1:22:39

Thanks for listening to this episode of Conversations

1:22:41

with Coleman.

1:22:42

If you enjoyed it, be sure to follow me on social

1:22:44

media and subscribe to my podcast to stay

1:22:46

up to date on all my latest content. If

1:22:48

you really want to support me, consider becoming

1:22:51

a member of Coleman Unfiltered for exclusive

1:22:54

access to subscriber-only content.

1:22:56

Thanks again for listening and see you next time.

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features