Kenneth Rogoff on Monetary Moves, Fiscal Gambits, and Classical Chess

Kenneth Rogoff on Monetary Moves, Fiscal Gambits, and Classical Chess

Released Wednesday, 30th April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Kenneth Rogoff on Monetary Moves, Fiscal Gambits, and Classical Chess

Kenneth Rogoff on Monetary Moves, Fiscal Gambits, and Classical Chess

Kenneth Rogoff on Monetary Moves, Fiscal Gambits, and Classical Chess

Kenneth Rogoff on Monetary Moves, Fiscal Gambits, and Classical Chess

Wednesday, 30th April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:04

Conversations with Tyler is produced

0:06

by the Mercatus Center at George Mason

0:08

University, bridging the gap

0:10

between academic ideas and real

0:12

-world problems. Learn more at

0:14

mercatus .org. For a full

0:17

transcript of every conversation, enhanced

0:19

with helpful links,

0:21

visit conversationswithtyler.com. Hello

0:26

everyone and welcome back to Conversations

0:28

with Tyler. Today I am

0:31

chatting with Kenneth Rogoff, who is one

0:33

of America's best economists. He

0:35

is a professor at Harvard and

0:37

he has a new book out

0:39

called Our Dollar Your Problem, an

0:42

insider's view of seven turbulent decades

0:44

of global finance and the road

0:46

ahead, can also having extensive experience

0:48

in the IMF and dealing with

0:50

various global crises. Ken,

0:52

welcome! Thank you. It's a

0:55

pleasure to be here, Tyler. Good to speak

0:57

to you. Circa early

0:59

2025, the big

1:01

debate is whether there's such a thing

1:03

as an unsustainable international trade balance. So,

1:07

Orrin Kaff says there is. Michael Pettis

1:09

says there is. Traditional theory is more

1:11

skeptical or agnostic. What's your view? No,

1:14

there's unsustainable debt. There's not particularly

1:17

unsustainable trade deficit. I mean, there's

1:19

Good things about having a trade

1:21

deficit, bad things, but it's a

1:23

result of many factors. So no,

1:26

I wouldn't agree with Pettus on

1:28

that. So what is the mistake

1:30

he and Orrin Cas are making? Well,

1:34

the trade balance depends a

1:36

lot on your savings and

1:38

your investment, these macroeconomic factors.

1:41

If there's an underlying problem, and

1:44

to be fair, when your

1:46

trade deficit's really negative, there

1:48

often is. you know, it

1:50

could be something. I think in the case of

1:52

the United States, when it hit a

1:54

real peak in the

1:56

2005 to 2007, I

1:59

thought there was a problem. I must

2:01

say, I didn't know till very

2:03

close to the event what was

2:06

going on. We weren't regulating well.

2:09

But yeah, I mean, I didn't even know what

2:11

their point is to be honest. I mean, there's

2:13

this mercantilist view. I want to collect all the

2:15

gold in the world. You know, we want to

2:17

be able to buy things. back

2:19

in the day used to have

2:21

to hire an army or navy

2:24

to help fight off invaders and

2:26

such. But today, that's not

2:28

so true. So I

2:30

think the current account deficit, that's a

2:32

broader measure of the deficit. It's

2:35

important. And if it's

2:37

really large, you can probably bet that

2:39

it might go down. But it's not

2:41

something to try to wrestle to the

2:43

ground. There's an

2:45

associated claim I hear, including from Martin

2:48

Wolf, that China

2:50

needs to substitute more into

2:52

consumption to remedy some longer

2:54

term macroeconomic imbalance. Now

2:57

I can see that from a welfare point

2:59

of view, the Chinese oversubsidize investment and might

3:01

be better off consuming more. But is it

3:04

going to boost their growth rate to consume

3:06

more? Well, first of all. They

3:09

subsidize investment like crazy. Of

3:11

course. I mean so investment's

3:14

been 40 % of GDP

3:16

Consumption their different measures, but

3:18

you know 50

3:20

% of GDP maybe we're

3:23

70 % of GDP by

3:25

comparison and it's been very

3:27

imbalanced that it's for a

3:30

command and control economy and

3:32

China's a hybrid economy the central government

3:34

plays a big role Doing

3:36

infrastructure investment subsidizing real estate

3:39

is easy to do and

3:41

they've been doing that for

3:43

a long time and their

3:46

growth has been very imbalanced so

3:48

everybody's been telling them for years

3:50

why don't you build up your

3:52

consumption. But it's

3:55

been hard because they don't have. medical

3:57

care in your old age. They don't

3:59

have social security in their old age.

4:01

They had this one child policy for

4:03

a long time. So there are a

4:05

lot of reasons everyone's had to say

4:07

it. And now their house prices are

4:09

plummeting. And that's for Chinese where a

4:11

lot of their wealth is. So

4:14

I would say it's not a bad idea

4:16

to try a little bit of that, but

4:18

they've dug a very deep hole. It's not

4:21

easy to dig their way out. So

4:23

putting aside the microeconomic distortions, which

4:25

macro model do you use to

4:27

think through the question of whether

4:29

or not China should consume more?

4:31

Do you use the solo model

4:33

or Romer or something else? What's

4:37

your got? Those are nice models, but I

4:39

mean, let's be honest. I mean, they're just

4:41

a piece of things. They do

4:44

tell us that at the end of

4:46

the day, you need to have

4:48

innovation. If you're just

4:50

growing by building more

4:52

machines, by building more

4:54

roads, you run into

4:57

diminishing returns, and you get less

4:59

and less with the output. That's what happened

5:01

to Russia. That's what happened to Japan. That's

5:03

what happened to a lot of Asia. And

5:05

for some reason, people thought that

5:07

wouldn't happen to China. But their

5:09

rate of innovation over the whole

5:11

economy, I'm not talking about the

5:13

highest level, has collapsed by many

5:15

different measures. And the private

5:18

sectors, of course, the root of all

5:20

the innovation. They have oppressed

5:22

the private sector, particularly in the

5:24

last 10 years. And so, you

5:27

know, for them to grow again,

5:29

they need to restore some agency

5:31

to the private sector. We're

5:34

in the midst of some tariff debates

5:36

right now, as you know. And one

5:38

argument I hear sometimes even from the

5:40

anti -tariff people is that if the

5:42

US but higher tariffs on China, while

5:44

the Chinese currency just appreciates the dollar

5:46

strengthens, there isn't that much of a

5:48

net effect. Because arguably they're propping up

5:50

their currency some amount now. Do you

5:53

agree with that? Well,

5:56

what you said is exactly right.

5:58

I mean, so I to a first

6:00

approximation if we put on a I

6:03

don't know whatever it is a 20 %

6:05

tariff it has an effect on our exchange

6:07

rate of making it go up which makes

6:09

our exports more expensive and makes their goods

6:12

less expensive and I mean, I don't really

6:14

get wonky, but if you did it on

6:16

the whole world, you can get wonky. I

6:18

can get wonky with you. Absolutely. If you

6:21

did a 20 % tariff on the whole

6:23

world, to a first approximation, your exchange rate

6:25

goes up 10 % the dollar. And

6:28

so, you know, that rebalances everything.

6:31

That brings the cost of their

6:33

goods back to just a 10 %

6:35

rise. And it makes your exports 10

6:37

% more expensive because the currency appreciate

6:40

it. So that's definitely an effect. Of

6:43

course, they're probably going to

6:45

retaliate and then that cancels it

6:47

out. But do they want

6:49

to retaliate? Don't they prefer the

6:51

outcome where the tariff approaches some

6:53

kind of neutrality? Given that

6:55

they have an overvalued currency right now, they

6:57

could have a decline, basically

7:00

be insulated from the tariff, not have to

7:02

worry about Trump so much anymore. Why

7:04

should they retaliate? They

7:06

have a lot of distortions in their

7:09

economy, but the days when it was

7:11

very clear cut that they had an

7:13

overvalued, Currency, I mean are far gone.

7:16

I mean, but it used to be

7:18

undervalued, right? Those days are very far

7:20

gone. So you're saying that their currency

7:23

now is overvalued. I think And they

7:25

want to bring it down. They have

7:27

all this producer price deflation, right? So

7:30

they should be expansionary on the monetary side

7:32

to have a more predictable path of nominal

7:34

GDP growth, but they're not doing it. So

7:36

probably their currency is a bit too high.

7:39

Relative to an optimum? Well, I

7:41

mean, a logical way to do it

7:44

would be to do more expansionary fiscal

7:46

policy, more expansionary monetary policy. We

7:49

don't really try to deal with producer

7:51

price inflation through the exchange rate. I

7:53

mean, exports and imports are important to

7:55

China, but it's also a very big

7:57

economy. There's a lot of stuff, you

7:59

know, like the infrastructure investment and

8:02

other investment that's internal. Sure,

8:04

but if they had higher price inflation, the

8:07

value of the renminbi in real terms would

8:09

fall somewhat, at least for a while, right?

8:12

And that would be better, which means the current rate is

8:14

somewhat higher than it ought to be. I

8:16

mean, they're running a massive surplus to

8:18

the rest of the world. The

8:21

total size of their trade -bound surplus is

8:23

only 2 % of GDP. It's

8:25

not like 10 % the way it was in 2010,

8:28

but They've gotten a lot bigger.

8:30

It's still huge compared to the world. So

8:33

I'm being in crude measures of if

8:35

their exchange rate's overvalued and undervalued. I

8:38

don't think you come to a simple

8:40

answer. The dollar is very rich. I

8:42

mean, so in a sense, everybody seems

8:45

cheap to the dollar right now. I'm

8:48

sure you've experienced that with your anyone

8:50

coming from abroad, even from Japan or

8:52

Switzerland. Oh my gosh, it's so expensive

8:54

here. Feel free to

8:57

give a wonky answer to this one.

8:59

But why do you think it's been

9:01

so hard for economics to develop a

9:04

satisfactory theory of exchange rates? So purchasing

9:06

power parity seems to hold only within

9:08

very broad bands, something like 2x. And

9:11

the rest just seems very murky. Why is that

9:13

so difficult? Well, I

9:16

mean, part of it is if you

9:18

have floating exchange rates, there's a lot

9:20

of financial factors that are hard to

9:22

understand that move it around a lot.

9:25

we're not able to easily

9:27

identify those factors. But

9:29

I think more and more theory empirics

9:32

is coalesced around things

9:34

like bank balance sheets,

9:37

so can banks arbitrage

9:39

exchange rates and various

9:41

pricing imperfections. So

9:44

I think the weight of research the

9:46

past 10 or 15 years has been

9:48

that the exchange rate moves a lot,

9:50

but it's not really moving around the

9:52

economy with it. And we've thought that

9:54

for a long time. But

9:56

I think the general view today, I

9:59

mean, it isn't always true, but that a

10:01

lot of the movements have to

10:03

do with financial frictions and financial

10:05

factors, not some gnomes controlling the

10:08

exchange rate, that there's a lot

10:10

of random noise. But

10:12

do you think we need a

10:14

good theory of both real and

10:16

nominal exchange rates to make reliable

10:19

policy recommendations? If we

10:21

don't really know what the exchange rate will be

10:23

doing and why, doesn't that put us in the

10:25

slightly odd position that we're saying, do this, do

10:27

that, but the most fundamental price variable is a

10:29

mystery to us? As

10:32

you may know, I mean, I think

10:34

my first important paper was showing how

10:36

hard it was to explain exchange rates.

10:38

I'm embarrassed to say it's about 45

10:40

years ago. And I think

10:42

the policy conclusions people drew out of

10:45

that is look at the exchange rate

10:47

when you're trying to figure out what

10:49

policy should be. Look at inflation rate.

10:51

Look at output. I think

10:53

for some countries, they're

10:56

so deep into dollar debt. They're

10:58

so connected with the dollar and trade,

11:00

they do worry about their exchange rate.

11:03

So it sort of depends on if

11:05

you're talking about a big country like

11:07

the United States, or are you talking

11:09

about New Zealand or something like that?

11:12

But I mean, I think generally policymakers

11:14

need to recognize there's a lot of

11:16

noise. So trying to

11:18

target the exchange rate is a fool's

11:21

game. And if

11:23

the Trump administration is trying

11:25

to do it, they might

11:27

get lucky, but it's pure luck.

11:30

So if I take the country of

11:32

Pakistan, I think it's now been through

11:34

maybe 23 or 24 IMF bailouts. That's

11:36

a lot. The problems aren't fixed. So

11:38

we would all say here's ways Pakistan

11:40

could improve. Probably you and I would

11:43

largely agree on those. But just from

11:45

an external point of view, say you're

11:47

dictator of the IMF, you're the dirt

11:49

managing director, you're the board, you're the

11:51

staff. What is it you would actually

11:53

do with Pakistan? I

11:56

mean, that's, you know, the deep.

11:58

Seated problems, the military is very,

12:00

very powerful in the country. The

12:03

military is very corrupt, runs

12:05

a lot of the businesses, has a lot

12:07

of control. So,

12:10

I mean, it really runs deep

12:12

into the institutions in the country.

12:14

It's not something you can like

12:16

airlift some expert like you or

12:18

I and just tell them what

12:20

to do. I mean, believe me,

12:22

there are a lot of very

12:24

smart Pakistani economists who know what

12:26

to do. But do you sign

12:28

off on bailout number 25 when that comes

12:31

along? You're in charge. I

12:33

mean, first of all,

12:36

if you don't sign off on bailout

12:38

number 25, they're going to default on

12:40

bailout number 24. You're rolling over the

12:42

stat all the time. And

12:44

it's very sensitive politically. Pakistan's

12:47

a country that's very, very

12:49

geopolitically important. So you can't

12:51

look at the programs there

12:53

as if you're lending to

12:55

the UK. It's something very

12:58

different. And the amounts are

13:00

small compared to if you're

13:02

lending to the UK. But

13:04

frankly, what I have advised

13:06

on things like Pakistan is just give

13:09

them aid. Don't give loans.

13:11

you're never going to collect the loans.

13:13

You're not seriously meeting their loans. And

13:15

so it sounds great to say, well,

13:17

we just lent the money to Pakistan.

13:20

But I think in general, in money

13:22

we're giving to developing countries, too much

13:24

of it comes in the form of

13:26

loans. And it distorts what we do

13:28

because we don't get them all repaid.

13:32

How many Latin and Caribbean economies

13:34

should dollarize? If you have, right,

13:36

should more? I

13:39

mean, it's a pretty desperate measure

13:41

when you dollarize and there are

13:43

different ways to dollarize. You

13:45

know, when I just came into

13:47

the International Monetary Fund in 2001, Argentina

13:50

had dollarized. They had been dollarized for 10

13:52

years and I said, you know, isn't this

13:54

great? But that was a peg. It wasn't

13:56

real dollars, right? I mean, like El Salvador,

13:59

Ecuador, Paraguay. I mean, actually, you want to

14:01

actually use the dollar, circulate the dollar. Right,

14:03

because that's credible. And those of us,

14:05

whether you like them or not, they've all stuck, right? I

14:08

mean, you can do it. I mean, it has

14:10

its costs. The biggest cost is

14:12

if your banking system runs into trouble,

14:15

you can't bail them out. So

14:17

in most countries, the currency

14:19

that we think of the physical currency

14:21

is just like a little piece of

14:23

the animal. A lot of it, you

14:26

might not think of your checking account

14:28

or your savings account as dollars, but

14:31

they are. That's a lot of the

14:33

money supply. So when you

14:35

say they're just using real dollars, they

14:37

don't have real dollars to back those

14:40

bank accounts. So it can

14:42

work. But you run into

14:44

banking crises. You run into debt

14:46

crises. And then when you're dollarized,

14:48

it's hard to fight it. So

14:50

it's doable. It's absolutely doable. But

14:53

I'm not sure necessarily it's advisable.

14:55

It depends on the alternative. If

14:57

the country's been run into the

15:00

ground for 50 years and you're

15:02

trying to reclaimed territory. It makes

15:04

sense. Why isn't it easy

15:06

for a lot of countries? Say you're Barbados.

15:08

That's a small country. Most of

15:10

your visitors are from the US also. Your

15:13

banking system, you can just buy external

15:15

insurance, right? There's an insurer that can

15:17

cover the Barbados banking system if need

15:19

be. Buy it from China if

15:21

you have to, and then just dollarize. Why aren't

15:23

they just better off? Okay,

15:26

I'm being naive, but is there an insurer

15:28

who's going to bail out the Barbados banking

15:30

system? I mean, I think our

15:32

regulators would make that difficult. Their regulators would

15:34

make it difficult. I mean, you would need

15:37

to have something like that. And there's a

15:39

lot of moral hazards. So you

15:41

really, if you're going to be an insurer,

15:43

you can't just insure you have to have,

15:45

you know, 150 people on shore looking at

15:47

them all the time. I mean, that's not

15:49

easy to do. The only country in the

15:52

world really, which can bail out its banking

15:54

systems, Hong Kong. they have enough

15:56

dollar reserves to bail out

15:58

everything. But that's the problem with

16:00

dollarization. If you're not

16:03

going to have banks, it's great.

16:05

But we want to have lending

16:07

and mortgages and car loans and

16:09

stuff. And it's very

16:11

easy to run into trouble. Why

16:15

did Japan never have a financial crisis?

16:17

So very high debt to GDP ratio.

16:20

Growth rate is... slow

16:22

in per capita terms. It's not as

16:24

bad as it sounds at first, but

16:26

nothing gangbusters. How have they held on?

16:29

Well, they did have a financial

16:32

crisis the mother of all financial

16:34

crises in the 90s. Oh sure,

16:36

but since then and since then

16:38

well have they hung on in

16:40

1990 and even in the early

16:42

90s their per capita GDP was

16:45

80 % of the United States

16:47

and purchasing power parity measures and

16:49

trying to put into common price

16:51

level. But in dollars,

16:53

it was well over 100 %

16:55

of the US. Today, it's

16:57

60 % in those measures. I mean,

16:59

it is not held on in per

17:02

capita terms. It has just, you know,

17:04

not had growth for a long time.

17:06

And they're running into trouble. There's per

17:08

capita growth in Japan. Maybe,

17:10

I don't know. Yeah, but nothing like

17:12

in the United States. I mean, we...

17:14

Well, we've beaten every advanced economy, not

17:16

just Japan. That's fair, but

17:19

they've fallen behind France, the

17:21

UK, Germany. They were ahead of

17:23

all of them. They've fallen far behind. And

17:26

they're in trouble now because

17:28

they're finally having inflation. They're

17:31

needing to raise interest rates. They've

17:33

stuffed government debt into every

17:36

orifice of the economy, into

17:38

the pension systems, into the

17:40

banks, into their postal savings

17:42

system. And now, they're

17:45

talking about cutting pensions, cutting

17:47

old age benefits, because suddenly

17:50

they're having to make interest

17:52

payments on the debt and

17:55

it's harder. So I

17:57

think people who use Japan as

17:59

an example of everything's fine, you

18:02

know, have their head in the sand.

18:04

I mean, it's an example of if

18:06

you're very rich, you can

18:08

go down slowly. But it's not an

18:11

example of how you know, you can

18:13

have fantastic economy with doubt like that

18:15

But why do some places say

18:17

the much earlier UK they have crises

18:20

and Japan Whatever the standard of living

18:22

issues may be right. There's no crisis.

18:24

There's no run on anything. It's quite

18:27

peaceful It is it is a very

18:29

you know society which obviously is Very

18:31

high degree of cohesion and that's a

18:34

tremendous strength of Japan. I just have

18:36

got a side mention if I can

18:38

I mean I I was a

18:40

visitor at the Bank of Japan in

18:43

the early 90s in the middle of

18:45

their meltdown Although I didn't see it

18:47

and I don't think anyone did at

18:50

the time And I had to eat

18:52

at the cafeteria every day and that

18:54

almost the same food that you had

18:57

to eat and it was good But

18:59

now I saw another line once and

19:01

I asked can I go in

19:03

that line? And the people said, oh,

19:06

well, that's if you want a smaller

19:08

portion. I mean, it's a

19:10

very different society than we have.

19:13

But they have a lot of

19:15

financial oppression. Financial oppression is going

19:17

to be part of the solution

19:19

in every advanced country where you

19:22

force banks, insurance companies, pension funds

19:24

to hold more debt. We've done

19:26

that already. And they've

19:28

done it in a big

19:30

way. It's hurt their financial

19:32

intermediation, so it makes lending

19:34

less efficient. And that's part

19:36

of why their growth has

19:38

suffered. So they've done a

19:40

good job becoming sclerotic slowly.

19:43

But I hardly think we would

19:45

want to imitate them, especially if

19:48

we intend to compete with China.

19:51

Is that what the European Union is going to

19:53

do, financial repression? They

19:55

did it already. I

19:57

mean they'll have to do it

20:00

again. They still have all these

20:02

major debt problems Yeah, I mean

20:04

they did it big time after

20:06

the European debt crisis. So just

20:08

a simple fact about that is

20:10

it used to be that say

20:12

Italian debt was held in Germany

20:14

Spanish that was held in Germany

20:16

spread all over now the

20:18

vast majority of the Italian

20:20

banks are holding all the

20:23

Italian bank. Spanish banks are

20:25

holding all the Spanish. Do

20:28

you think that's because they're diversifying?

20:30

No, it's because they're being ordered to do that.

20:33

So they have a lot of financial oppression already.

20:36

They don't have dynamic capital markets

20:38

for a lot of reasons. And

20:41

obviously, they need to remilitarize

20:43

now. You know, Germany has

20:45

a lot of fiscal space, so. They

20:47

can go all out. But especially now

20:49

that interest rates are real interest rates

20:51

are hitting a higher level, they're going

20:53

to have to do it. But I

20:55

think they're going to find they have

20:57

to give things up in order to

20:59

do it because the interest rates aren't

21:01

zero anymore. So you think they'll

21:04

actually cut spending, say in France? I

21:07

mean, I don't disagree

21:09

with you, but it somehow

21:11

feels unimaginable to me. Yeah,

21:14

I mean, many of the European countries

21:16

actually tighten their pension systems a lot

21:19

during the European crisis. They set it

21:21

in place to take place 10 or

21:23

15 years later, not France. Yeah,

21:25

I do. I think this is a

21:27

real existential challenge to the French state.

21:30

I mean, maybe they'll take over

21:32

as the tech capital the world.

21:34

Maybe they'll, you know, find ways

21:37

to solve their problems. But they've

21:39

been free riding off the United

21:41

States. There's no question about that.

21:43

And now they have to spend

21:46

more. I'm not praising Trump's policies.

21:48

Let's not conflate those two things.

21:51

But yes, I think they're going to

21:53

find they have taxes are very, very

21:55

high in Europe. In fact, so much

21:57

so that there's no question it holds

22:00

back a lot of investment. Europe

22:02

has very few world beaters,

22:05

terms of tech, finance.

22:08

The biggest companies set

22:10

aside the Danish company

22:12

that's Ozenpec, they're things

22:14

like Hermes, Prada, sort

22:17

of lifestyle superpower stuff. No,

22:19

I think this is absolutely an existential

22:21

crisis for real. It may lead to

22:23

them becoming more cohesive. It

22:26

may lead to them becoming

22:28

more of a geopolitical power.

22:31

But yes, they're going to have to make

22:33

choices, which they haven't had to make. If

22:36

the nation is Italy, and I think that

22:38

the birth rate at TFR is about 1

22:40

.3 on average, Are they

22:42

just going to wake up one morning and say

22:44

the whole welfare state thing was a mistake and

22:46

we're getting rid of it? I mean, isn't that

22:48

the implication? Well, that's a

22:51

kind of strong statement and they're

22:53

not going to do that, but

22:55

But if the country keeps on

22:57

shrinking the age pyramid gets worse

23:00

and worse Yeah, we all we

23:02

all face we all face this

23:04

issue and hope that innovation and

23:06

growth or something will help but

23:09

Yeah, I know the demographics is

23:11

a problem in every country in

23:13

Italy, as you say, as much

23:15

far, far ahead of the United

23:17

States on the demographics. I mean,

23:20

an interesting fact is they spend

23:22

a mind -numbing 15 % of

23:24

GDP on old age pensions and

23:26

support now. I mean,

23:28

we're half that, you know, all in. and

23:31

15 % of GDP. And

23:34

so, yeah, they have a lot of constraints

23:36

and their tax rates are very high. They're

23:40

not corrupt like in Pakistan, but

23:43

it's not Sweden either. I mean, it's

23:45

got a lot of problems. And

23:48

just predictively, what do you think the United

23:50

States will do with its fiscal position? That

23:54

is a darn good question. I

23:56

mean, looking Way

23:58

forward, I would just we're on

24:00

an unsustainable path. We will

24:03

continue to have our debt balloon. And

24:06

eventually, not necessarily in a

24:08

planned or coherent way, I

24:11

think we're going to have another big inflation

24:13

soon. Next five to seven years, that's

24:16

maybe sooner with what's going on.

24:19

And that's going to bring it down.

24:21

Just like it did under Biden, it

24:23

brought the debt down. But then the

24:25

markets are, you know, Fool me once

24:27

shame on you, you know fool me

24:30

twice. No, we're raising the interest rate

24:32

and Then we'll have to you know

24:34

make choices. I mean, I think in

24:36

the United States a lot of the

24:38

choices I'd start to say it probably

24:40

point towards higher taxation Because we're hardly

24:43

running a welfare state. It's not all

24:45

due respects and I'm not sure I

24:47

have any due respects to doge They're

24:49

not that many things to cut in

24:51

the United States compared to to many

24:54

other countries. So I don't know what

24:56

the choice will be. I mean, I

24:58

probably won't be here. And you might

25:00

not be either when we're making the

25:02

choices. But I think we'll both be

25:05

here. Well, it

25:07

could be. It could happen much sooner.

25:09

I mean, on the other hand, it's

25:11

hard to know what's going through Trump's

25:13

head. So I, you

25:15

know, I presumed he was

25:17

going to blow up the deficit like everybody

25:19

else. We'll see.

25:22

And when you say big inflation, how big

25:24

is big? Well,

25:26

I think this time it'll be,

25:29

so last time we probably had

25:31

a bonus 10 % inflation over

25:33

the 2 % target cumulatively, maybe

25:35

12%. I think this time it'll

25:37

be more in the order cumulatively

25:39

over the 2 % target, 20%,

25:42

25%. I mean, there's going to

25:44

be an adjustment. I

25:46

don't think the debt is going to

25:48

be the sole contribution to that. There

25:50

are many factors. You have

25:52

to impinge on Federal Reserve independence. Probably

25:55

there'll be some shock, you know, which

25:57

will justify it. I don't know how

25:59

it's going to play out. But

26:02

I think I know that for

26:04

years, people have said the US

26:07

debt is unsustainable. But

26:09

it hasn't come to roost

26:11

because we've lived through this

26:13

post financial crisis. post

26:15

-pandemic era of very, very low

26:17

and negative real interest rates. That

26:20

is not the norm. There's regression

26:22

to mean. You know what? It's

26:24

happened. And suddenly,

26:27

the interest payments start piling up.

26:29

I think they've gone at least

26:31

doubled over the last few years.

26:34

They're on quickly on their way to tripling,

26:36

going up to a trillion dollars. And

26:39

so suddenly, it's more than

26:41

our defense spending. That's the

26:43

most important macro change in the

26:45

world that real interest rates appear

26:48

to have regressed more towards long

26:50

-term trend. What's the

26:52

most plausible scenario you can imagine where the

26:55

US does not have to make any major

26:57

adjustment? I'm not saying you're predicting it. I'm

26:59

not saying you think it's very plausible, but

27:01

you have to come up with something. What

27:03

is it? Oh, I don't

27:06

think there's any question. It's

27:08

that the AI revolution turns

27:10

out to, you know, just

27:12

work magically much better than

27:14

we, you know, anyone imagine

27:16

that people like me quietly

27:18

acquiesce to just getting transfers

27:20

from the government instead of

27:22

having jobs. And we just,

27:24

you know, continue to have

27:26

a high income and the

27:28

robot income pays for everything.

27:31

I mean, but AI is absolutely

27:33

the thing which is most likely,

27:35

you know, some kind of technological

27:37

change. You know, other than that,

27:39

the problems in our politics, it's

27:41

in our DNA. We're convinced

27:43

that, you know, we're immortals, and

27:45

we can just do whatever we

27:48

want. That's you go around Washington

27:50

and whatever they say, I think

27:52

that's what they think. And again,

27:55

this key thing. is that real

27:57

interest rates, the interest rate adjusted

27:59

for expected inflation. And I'm

28:01

looking at the long term, they've come

28:03

up and they're not super high, but

28:05

they're more like they were in the

28:08

early 2000s. And I think of reasonable

28:10

projections, they're going to stay around the

28:12

level they are. I'm

28:14

sure you know the classic Paul Samuelson

28:16

paper on overlapping generations model. And in

28:19

that paper, the real interest rate is

28:21

equal to the rate of population growth.

28:23

There's other papers where the real interest

28:26

rate is in broad harmony with the

28:28

rate of productivity growth. If either of

28:30

those models are correct, aren't we okay

28:33

again? Well,

28:35

first of all, if it's population

28:37

growth and productivity alone, then you're

28:39

losing tax dollars at the same

28:41

time you're paying less interest. But

28:44

it turns out those variables don't

28:46

work so well over a longer

28:49

period. I have a paper in

28:51

the American Economic Review just last

28:53

August about this. you look over

28:56

longer time periods, you

28:58

know, just because economists think that those should

29:00

be the dominant variables, it doesn't turn out

29:02

to work that well. And all this stuff,

29:04

there've been a lot of papers by economists

29:07

looking at the decline, it's going

29:09

the real interest rate going down, demographics

29:11

going down, productivity going down, looks great.

29:13

If you look at a longer period,

29:16

there's no there or there. I mean,

29:18

it just doesn't stand up. So I

29:20

think there are other factors having to

29:22

do with liquidity. default

29:24

risk, changing nature of the

29:27

production function, globalization. I

29:30

think there are many variables where

29:32

assuming there's going to be some

29:34

reversion to mean is just a

29:36

pretty good thing to have in

29:38

the back of your head. You

29:41

know, you know, Carmen Reinhardt and I had

29:43

this book this time is different. Very much

29:45

on the theme of people just looking at

29:47

five years or 10 years and think, oh,

29:49

it's just great. it's just going to go

29:52

like this. And I think the

29:54

real interest rates, an example, I would say

29:56

the low inflation is another example. My

29:58

students for a long time just

30:00

didn't believe there'd ever be inflation

30:02

again. I would teach it, they would

30:04

fall asleep. I mean, I remember

30:07

asking a question even to someone who was

30:09

a research assistant at a big central bank,

30:11

explain this to me about inflation. And

30:14

she said, My generation doesn't ever expect

30:16

to think about inflation. We don't have

30:18

it. Let me give you examples of

30:20

this. So no, I would

30:23

suspect we will have high real estate.

30:25

And by the way, AI will raise

30:27

the interest rate. But productivity, too. the

30:30

case where it goes up with productivity. It

30:32

does raise productivity, but the usual

30:34

thing about demographics is there are

30:36

less people to work with the

30:38

machines, and therefore, the return on

30:40

the machines is lower and the

30:42

interest rate goes down. But

30:45

if the people are being

30:47

substituted for, which is new,

30:50

I mean, we've always found a

30:53

way to reinsert ourselves. You won't

30:55

necessarily, even in a theoretical model,

30:57

like Samuel Sons or Solos, get

31:00

that effect. You

31:02

wrote a famous 1987 paper on

31:05

political business cycle theory. How

31:07

relevant do you think political business cycles have

31:09

been since then? Well, there's

31:11

been a lot of papers on it. I mean, I

31:13

don't think there's any question. Every politician

31:16

in the world, if they have

31:18

the power, tries to goose up

31:20

the economy before it happens. I

31:23

think empirically, it's overwhelming that it's

31:25

true. The question is, why does

31:27

it fool anyone? Everybody should understand

31:30

why that's going on. And

31:32

without going to tales, that paper

31:34

was about the paradox that I

31:36

know you're just making things look

31:38

good. I know you're hiding something from

31:41

me so that you're exaggerating how long

31:43

this can go on, how much

31:45

it's costing, but I'm going to vote

31:47

for you anyway. And so

31:49

that's what that paper was. It

31:52

looked at as a signaling model

31:54

that's getting really wonky. But

31:56

the fiscal versions of political business cycle

31:58

theory, they don't have to fool anyone,

32:00

right? You do get

32:03

the money, and society as a whole has to

32:05

pay it back, but you can come out ahead.

32:09

There's another, I'm going to just

32:11

translate it a little bit from

32:13

my model, one that Alberto Ellisina,

32:15

my late colleague Alberto Ellisina did

32:17

and a number of others that

32:20

said, part of the reason debt

32:22

keeps piling up is we have,

32:24

you know, the liberal party, the

32:26

conservative party, when the liberal parties

32:28

in power, they know that debt

32:30

is bad, but they know they

32:33

can spend now. And they know

32:35

they might not control it in

32:37

the future, so they spend a

32:39

lot and they borrow. When the

32:41

conservatives are in power, they cut

32:43

taxes and build up the debt.

32:46

I think that's a very powerful, very,

32:48

very powerful theory of part of why

32:50

debt builds up is whoever's in power,

32:53

you know, says, don't pay any attention to

32:55

it. And of course, you know, I

32:57

think we end up where we

33:00

are now. In an

33:02

earlier book, you called for the phasing out

33:04

of currency and large denomination bills. Do you

33:06

still want to do this? I

33:09

call out for phasing most

33:12

currency. I'm not phasing

33:14

it all out right away. That takes,

33:16

you know, generation. Well, Sweden's done it.

33:18

I mean, it doesn't take that long

33:20

if people are on board. It's very

33:22

hard to run across currency in Sweden

33:25

today. You're right and they didn't even

33:27

pass laws. You're right. You have to

33:29

travel 150 kilometers to get to an

33:31

ATM machine, but it's not completely phased

33:33

out by any means and it's still

33:35

there. So, first

33:38

of all, we've had enough inflation

33:40

that the $100 bill is now

33:43

a $75 bill, I'll say to

33:45

start with. But, you know,

33:47

most of the world's currencies held in

33:49

these large denomination notes. I

33:52

mean, I done further work, very

33:54

little of it's used in transactions.

33:56

I think most of it is in

33:58

the underground economy. It's

34:01

not necessarily nefarious. There's drug

34:03

dealing, human smuggling and

34:06

everything, human trafficking. But I

34:08

think the large majority of it is tax

34:10

evasion. I mean, lots of people do that.

34:13

Okay, I mean, I'm not

34:15

trying to be holier than

34:17

thou and just say everybody

34:19

does that is evil. But

34:22

I'm looking from the government's point of view, making

34:25

money by saying, hey, people love

34:27

these $100 bills and not figuring

34:29

out that they're using them not

34:31

to pay taxes. I've argued that

34:33

that's pennywise and pound foolish. And

34:36

yeah, that's sort of the core of

34:38

the argument. But from an efficiency point

34:40

of view, don't you want to kind

34:42

of price discrimination in your tax system?

34:44

Just say people pay their nannies with

34:46

$100 bills. They wouldn't hire the nanny

34:49

if they had to pay taxes. Furthermore,

34:51

if the transaction were recorded, they'd have

34:53

to worry about social security issues. It's

34:55

a lot of paperwork and bureaucracy, very

34:57

forbidding for a lot of people. And

35:00

you're just lowering output by not making

35:02

it easy for them to pay the

35:04

nanny with cash. So I do think

35:06

about that, but the questions why we

35:08

need $100 bills for that mean you

35:10

can pay your nanny with 20s and

35:12

they'll be perfectly happy because actually the

35:15

$100 bills are harder to work with,

35:17

you know, for them. So,

35:19

no, I think you want to

35:21

have ways that you can evade

35:24

the law up to a point.

35:26

I mean, marijuana is now legal

35:28

in most places and maybe the

35:30

whole culture and society wouldn't have

35:32

them all. if we didn't have

35:34

a cash economy that could pay

35:37

for that. So again,

35:39

I think it's a question of

35:41

calibration, regulation, where you want

35:43

to put things. Do you

35:45

worry about the example of the Canadian truckers

35:48

where it becomes too easy to cut off

35:50

people's bank accounts and there's too much social

35:52

power over a lot of people? Well,

35:55

again, I'm getting rid

35:58

of the large denomination notes and

36:00

not straightforwardly the

36:02

others and so yeah no we don't

36:04

want to over I absolutely agree there's

36:06

government accesses. The questions you know do

36:08

we have you know we have we

36:10

have drugs that you know help people

36:13

after an operation but it and we

36:15

want to have them but does it

36:17

want to mean mean we want to

36:19

have them freely floating in the economy.

36:22

And also, we can phase out $100

36:24

bills and $50 bills and we can

36:27

change our mind later and decide that

36:29

we overdid it. I don't think we

36:31

would. I think continue to go in

36:33

that direction. But it's a

36:36

matter of costs and benefits. Do

36:38

we also have to ban stablecoins

36:40

then? Because you can make $100,

36:43

$500 transaction in stablecoins. And

36:45

not everyone's used to doing that now, but you

36:47

figure within two years, your AI can do it

36:50

for you if need be. And

36:52

we're just pushing more people into stablecoins. Well,

36:55

absolutely. So in the same book,

36:57

I said we need to regulate

37:00

cryptocurrency. And there are different kinds

37:02

of stablecoins. And it's not clear

37:05

where it's ending up in the

37:07

long run. But I think stablecoins

37:09

eventually have to have some kind

37:12

of parallel revealability. to

37:14

what bank accounts have, not necessarily

37:16

exactly the same, but I know

37:18

that's where we're headed. I think

37:20

the regulators are pretty favorable to

37:23

stablecoins actually on the whole, but

37:25

not if they're being used to

37:27

evade taxes and all kinds of

37:29

regulations. But the issuers can

37:31

be abroad. In that sense, it's quite different

37:33

from domestic banks, from currency. Someone

37:36

has a stablecoin account in the Cayman

37:38

Islands, and they make a transaction with

37:40

someone with a stablecoin account in Estonia.

37:43

How much say do the US regulators really

37:45

have over that? Well,

37:47

we don't have much say over that.

37:49

I mean, you already have that the

37:51

case to some extent with bank accounts,

37:54

and you can mitigate the problem. You

37:56

can't eliminate it. I mean, that's generally

37:58

true of cryptocurrency. You

38:01

can try to regulate it.

38:03

You can't completely eliminate it.

38:05

I mean, probably a lot

38:07

of sanctions evasion. is being

38:09

done with stablecoins and cryptocurrency.

38:12

And clearly, we have not been able to touch that.

38:16

Should the US issue a

38:18

CBDC, a digital coin? Let

38:20

me put it this way. I don't think

38:23

we should be the first to try this.

38:25

Right now, we're on top. I mean,

38:28

I kind of think we peed, but

38:30

that's another question. We're winning.

38:32

Why do you want to change the

38:34

rules of the game when we're winning?

38:36

Because it's not about the currency. It's

38:38

about treasury bills. It's about the interest

38:40

payment. It's about market clearing. And

38:43

also, we're so big, we

38:45

probably are more likely

38:47

headed towards having competitive

38:49

stablecoins, which are regulated,

38:51

which have some kind of lender

38:54

of last resort than a CBDC.

38:57

I'm skeptical about it. you

38:59

put yourself in a position where

39:01

one screw -up can paralyze everything.

39:04

And it wouldn't be good if

39:06

we had five stablecoins and one

39:08

of them had a problem. But

39:10

I tend to think that's something

39:12

for Latvia or Singapore to try

39:14

and not necessarily the US, maybe

39:17

in 50 years. To

39:19

be fair, Europe's talking about it. But

39:21

they're talking about what we call a

39:23

wholesale CBDC, which is among the banks.

39:26

And that's a completely different animal. A

39:29

standard macro puzzle today, we had

39:31

a disinflation from post COVID inflation.

39:33

It went from 8 .9 %

39:35

to something not too far from

39:37

3%. And there's no big recession.

39:39

How do you interpret that? Were the

39:41

rational expectations people write that it was credible and

39:43

we just did it? Or the people who say

39:45

it was all supply shocks, are they right? Or

39:47

it's a big puzzle to me. What do you

39:50

think? Well,

39:52

I think it is a big puzzle. It's the

39:54

first thing to say. I mean, I'm not gonna

39:56

claim I thought that was going

39:58

to be painless bringing the inflation rate down.

40:00

I don't think I was out there quite

40:02

at the Larry Summers level, banging on the

40:04

table, saying that there had to be a

40:06

big recession. I certainly do

40:09

not buy the idea was all supply

40:11

shocks. That's just nonsense. So

40:13

there are these people who say, oh,

40:15

it was just the supply chain, the

40:17

shipping lanes were closed and all that

40:19

stuff. And as soon as the supply

40:21

chains were back, inflation was down. Excuse

40:23

me, the supply chain problems make the

40:25

price go up. when they go away,

40:28

the price should come down. It did

40:30

not. And so there

40:32

clearly was, you know, even in

40:34

countries which didn't do as much

40:36

macro stimulus as we did, they

40:38

did a lot. And they all,

40:40

of course, kept their monetary policy

40:42

easy. But yeah, I mean,

40:44

the credibility is remarkable. I

40:47

mean, if you look at inflation expectations, they

40:50

moved a little bit. I mean, I'm

40:52

talking about the professional the consumer

40:55

ones moved a little more, but

40:57

consider what just happened. That

41:00

inflation expectations didn't move more. It's remarkable.

41:02

And to come back to the earlier point

41:05

about solving our debt, if we ever have

41:07

an inflation, I don't think that's

41:09

going to happen again. When we have a

41:11

second inflation, that time the

41:13

credibility is really going to be shot. What

41:16

else do you think of as an

41:18

unresolved puzzle in macro besides the disinflation?

41:22

Boy, that's a really good. thing because

41:24

I think about research questions all the

41:26

time. It's certainly been

41:28

very surprising to me of

41:31

how much bank regulation has

41:33

created all these arbitrage issues

41:35

across things that didn't exist.

41:38

I'm not sure this completely

41:40

unresolved, but when I was

41:42

doing my book with Mori

41:45

Absel, we thought of what

41:47

we call covered interest parity

41:49

as just something that holds.

41:52

you know, law. In other words, if

41:55

you borrow in one country and you

41:57

borrow in another country but do some

41:59

kind of forward contract undo it, you

42:01

get the same interest rate. It's not

42:04

true anymore. And I think

42:06

there's just a range of these puzzles that

42:08

have come up since the crisis. I

42:11

suppose another one would be, you know,

42:13

what kind of inflation rate do we

42:15

really want to have? There's a lot

42:17

of debate about that. There are people

42:19

who say, it shouldn't be

42:21

2%, it should be 4%, some

42:23

people it should be 0%. I

42:25

think that's a big question. Do

42:28

you have any guess on the covered

42:31

interest parity issue because that bugs me

42:33

all the time? Do you think it's

42:35

an institutional friction or there's some kind

42:38

of unmeasured risk that we're not seeing

42:40

or picking up or something else? I

42:42

mean it seems to be that the

42:45

banks are prevented from undoing it that

42:47

we have some of these regulations for

42:49

example that just restrict the size of

42:52

your balance sheet and the banks used

42:54

to just be able to freely borrow

42:56

and lend and undo things to borrow

42:58

in one currency land in the other

43:01

currency. That's how you'd undo it. But

43:03

there's just been a range of puzzles

43:05

like that. And of course, the biggest

43:08

puzzle is productivity. Like, if

43:10

I go to a country like the UK, how

43:12

do we get productivity? And exchange rates are

43:14

still a puzzle. I mean, you

43:17

asked a question about it before, but we

43:19

don't have a good, you know, fully

43:21

satisfactory explanation of them. You'll

43:24

be doing a book tour in the

43:26

UK soon. Why is their growth, their

43:28

productivity growth been so slow? Again,

43:31

we might admit this is a puzzle,

43:33

but it surprised me. They have plenty

43:35

of science. They have some great universities.

43:37

They played a key role in developing

43:39

vaccines, other innovations, and

43:42

they seem entirely stuck. Well,

43:45

I mean, it's been a generalized problem

43:48

in Europe, although you think they'd been

43:50

doing better. I think

43:52

part of it is this sucking sound

43:54

of the United States with the brain

43:56

drain that we have. You

43:58

and I both know about DeepMind. British

44:01

company, you know, ends

44:03

up in California. And

44:06

I think there are many examples like that

44:08

where when something goes well, the

44:10

US sucks them off. Probably

44:13

they have this profound problem of

44:15

the North and the South. The

44:17

South is rich and the North

44:19

is poor. And they just

44:21

have not been able to figure that

44:24

out. So that, you know, if you

44:26

go to London, they're doing great. And

44:28

they're still doing great. But they've had

44:30

trouble finding jobs that the manufacturing jobs

44:32

are going, they haven't figured

44:34

out how to substitute for them. The US

44:37

has had the tech revolution. I mean, if

44:39

you took that away, we don't

44:41

look so good anymore. A

44:43

lot of countries don't seem to

44:45

have a sucking sound problem, though.

44:47

So the talented people in northern

44:50

UK go to southern UK. But

44:52

you look at Germany, the Netherlands, you don't

44:54

see the same thing happening in those places.

44:57

Is it because London is so good that

44:59

the country as a whole grows more slowly?

45:01

Is that a kind of curse for the

45:03

aggregate number? You

45:06

know, it's still the case

45:08

that those countries have

45:11

hardly been models of dynamism,

45:13

Germany and the Netherlands. You're

45:16

right. They've been able to keep people

45:18

more partly because they're not English speaking.

45:21

But again, a lot of the difference in

45:23

how we've done is our tech sector. That's

45:26

been a lot of the innovation going through

45:28

the economy. And I don't want to sound

45:30

like I'm drunk with what's going on with

45:32

our tech sector and how it affects other

45:35

things. But if you took that away, our

45:37

numbers would look like theirs. Is

45:40

Malay going to make it succeed in

45:42

Argentina? What does it depend upon? Well,

45:45

I hope so. I think he's the

45:47

best chance that Argentina has had in

45:50

a long time, which is fair to

45:52

say a very low bar. The

45:55

thing that he's done that I

45:57

have not seen before is balancing

45:59

the budget. If you're a

46:01

big borrower and you keep defaulting, sort of

46:03

a starting point. is figuring out how not

46:06

to have to borrow money. He's

46:08

managed to do that. I mean,

46:10

I don't know that all his

46:12

libertarian visions necessarily will come to

46:14

pass. You know, he's provided

46:16

some stability for the inflation number. Argentina,

46:21

as you know, was one of the

46:23

richest countries in the world by any

46:25

measure at the turn of the 20th

46:27

century in 1900. Now, they're

46:29

lower middle income country. They're per

46:32

capita incomes below Brazil, which is

46:34

hard to get your head wrapped

46:36

around. So, I

46:38

mean, I think there are many

46:41

reasons, but certainly, you know, perinism,

46:43

socialism has not done well by

46:45

Argentina. But has he balanced

46:47

the budget? I know he announced a

46:49

balanced budget, but this is April 2025

46:51

and they just borrowed $20 million from

46:54

the IMF. It doesn't sound like a

46:56

very balanced budget. Well, I

46:58

mean, it's counting the interest payments on

47:00

the IMF. And yeah, I mean, he

47:03

inherited this big debt. They're paying the

47:05

interest. It's very low interest on the

47:08

big debt. And I don't know how

47:10

that's ultimately going to get resolved. I

47:12

mean, they have a lot of problems

47:15

ahead. You know, there's a

47:17

lot of strength in Argentina if they can

47:19

grow again. I don't want to sound, you

47:21

know, panglossian about

47:23

Argentina. But goodness,

47:25

they had inflation of 200 %

47:27

when he took over. The economy

47:29

was in free fall. So

47:32

look, you know, there's no

47:34

magic wand you can wave

47:36

over the last 80, 90

47:38

years of Argentina and make

47:41

everything right. Okay,

47:43

some chess questions. Once a grandmaster,

47:45

always a grandmaster, so you can't

47:47

just say you don't know. Do

47:49

cash the next dominant chess player?

47:52

Or will he be first to monkey equals? Well,

47:54

he's not even nearly first, now,

47:57

even among... know, others. I mean,

47:59

there's a number of Indian players

48:01

who are very good. I wouldn't

48:03

put him ahead of Nakamura or

48:06

Karawana much less Carlson, but he's

48:08

ambitious. He's talented. I

48:10

wish him the best. I mean, it's

48:12

wonderful that he won, but I mean,

48:14

he's got a long ways to go

48:16

to be Casperot, Fisher, Carlson. It'd be

48:18

fabulous for Chas if he does that.

48:21

I don't see it yet. Do you? Well,

48:24

Nakamura. Karawana in five years

48:26

they'll be out of the scene, maybe

48:28

before then. Carlson is already in a

48:30

sense out of the scene. I

48:33

think he has a 30 or 40

48:35

% chance of being not a truly

48:37

dominant player, but say the way Anand

48:39

or Kramnik were at their peak. You

48:42

know, one of the top two or three

48:44

very consistently and world champion for some number

48:46

of cycles. Not the way Kasparov

48:48

was, but something quite impressive. I'm close to it.

48:50

Well, it may be fantastic. Yeah, yeah. Okay, I

48:53

thought you were asking a different question. No, the

48:55

next, not the current dominant, but is he the

48:57

player? No, he could

48:59

absolutely, I mean, Anand and Kramnick were

49:01

amazing, and he could absolutely do that.

49:04

I mean, he's close to having done

49:06

it. If he met, he'll have a

49:08

much more difficult challenger next time, I

49:10

would suspect. I mean, Ding

49:13

is an uber talent, the person he

49:15

beat. but clearly had all

49:17

sorts of mental problems in the match.

49:19

I mean, he's been depressed and you

49:21

could see him sort of losing it

49:23

in some games. What

49:25

were your impressions of Bobby Fisher when you

49:27

met him? Well,

49:30

I mean, he was amazing. First

49:33

of all, when I met him,

49:35

he came every day to the

49:38

1969 US Junior Championship over 10

49:40

days. And he sat and he

49:42

analyzed with us. And the first thing was just

49:44

that. What's he doing with us? Why is he

49:46

wasting his time with us? We just thought he

49:48

was so generous. But obviously,

49:51

his absolute intensity, his

49:54

commitment, I don't know if you

49:56

remember, it's hard to imagine.

49:58

But he actually used to be weak

50:00

at rock endings, weak for somebody like

50:02

that. So he locked himself

50:05

in a room for three months and

50:07

did nothing. but study rock endings and

50:09

got to be very good. He got

50:11

a hotel, he told us about it,

50:14

got a hotel room, you know, with

50:16

no, no view. And then, you know,

50:18

certainly some of the ideas he showed,

50:21

I still think about it. I won

50:23

a game and he went over it

50:25

with me against Steve Spencer. It was

50:27

the last game of the tournament, which

50:30

I won. And he showed me his

50:32

ideas as like I Hadn't

50:34

thought of any of them, you know, it

50:36

was just the his fertile I don't know

50:39

if they were better to be completely honest

50:41

Then what I played I mean, of course,

50:43

he's much better than me But I mean

50:45

just the imagination of there was this then

50:47

we're talking about on move for on move

50:49

five of just things that wouldn't occur to

50:51

me And part of the Fisher legend was

50:54

that at least supposedly he was the greatest

50:56

over -the -board analyst of any chess player

50:59

Well, Gary Kasparov was so fool

51:01

and same as Carlson, I mean,

51:04

I don't know. But he

51:06

was way above everybody in his generation.

51:08

He did not have the prep that

51:10

the Russians had. He worked on his

51:13

own. he was not working with a

51:15

team. The Russians had all this communication

51:17

and coaches and everything. And by the

51:20

way, you know, I was representing the

51:22

U .S. and the World Junior Championships

51:24

and things like that. Everybody was a

51:27

big disadvantage that you didn't have a

51:29

trainer or a coach, you know, organizing

51:31

information. Fisher was doing that

51:33

at the highest level. So he must have

51:35

been by far the best over the board

51:38

player then. But not the

51:40

player. I mean, does someone, if you would

51:42

sit down with them at the board and

51:44

show them your game, The claim I've heard

51:46

is that Fisher was a more astute analyst,

51:48

even than Kasparov. Kasparov might have been the

51:51

better player, but just willing

51:53

to put his entire mental energy into

51:55

over -the -board analysis, sitting there. I

51:57

think that's part of the Fisher legend.

52:00

I mean, it's part of the legend.

52:02

I mean, he was amazing. I played

52:05

against really all the top players then,

52:07

with the exception of Spassky. And,

52:09

you know, they were all phenomenal,

52:11

but they weren't all equally good

52:13

calculators. So the best

52:15

calculator I ever played was actually

52:18

a Yugoslav player reached second or

52:20

third named Lubejevic. And he

52:22

beat me. I don't know. I was 16 years

52:24

old. And to try to

52:26

salvage some ego, I said, well, what

52:28

did you, what if I did this?

52:30

What were you going to do? And

52:32

I showed him my best. I thought

52:34

it was just like a great variation.

52:36

I don't remember how long, 10 moves.

52:39

And he goes, mm -hmm, mm -hmm. Yeah,

52:41

but then I do this. Actually,

52:43

it's this. And he goes, something 15

52:45

moves. I never played Fisher. He wrote

52:47

an article about me once, as you

52:49

know, but I never played him.

52:51

But of course, I could well imagine it

52:54

would be the same. But I'm not sure

52:56

I could tell the difference with Kasparov, Carlson,

52:58

you know, at that level. When

53:00

Magnus spoke with Lex Friedman, he

53:03

drew a distinction between players who

53:05

were incredible calculators. He called Goukache

53:07

one of those, and players who

53:09

were incredible with evaluation. And

53:11

he called himself one of those. He thinks

53:13

he's actually not the best calculator. Do

53:16

you broadly agree with that distinction? Well,

53:19

I think it's an interesting question. It's

53:21

funny, because I've seen him write about

53:23

Karpov, who I did play, and he

53:25

said, I don't know how Karpov does

53:28

it. He just knows where to put

53:30

the pieces. He just knows where everything

53:32

goes. And he's not having to calculate

53:34

like I do. And between his great

53:36

nemesis was Karpov. And between the two

53:38

of them, he was the calculator and

53:40

Karpov was no slouch, but Kasparov was

53:43

better. I think maybe as

53:45

Gary gets older, you know,

53:47

I mean, your comparative advantage as a

53:49

calculator is probably at your peak at

53:51

a younger age. And Gary, you know,

53:53

developed other tools. But I'm

53:55

going to He was really good at

53:57

both. I so I But I would

54:00

have put Casper up as a calculator

54:02

like a fierce calculator Now you must

54:04

have been out of practice, but I

54:06

believe you drew Magnus in a game

54:08

of speed chess in 2012. Is that

54:10

the correct year? Yeah, it

54:12

really it really happened. How did it happen?

54:14

What's what's the story? Well

54:17

sort of what I tell people

54:19

is if you were a professional

54:21

golfer once and you play three

54:23

holes with somebody anything can

54:26

happen, you know, the law of large numbers.

54:29

But, you know, going more into it,

54:31

he led me up white. We played

54:33

a Ruy Lopez Spanish opening, which he

54:35

had been playing all the time. He

54:37

played a variation. I looked, I hadn't

54:39

prepared. I mean, it's just what he

54:42

was playing all Did he play the Briar like he used

54:44

to do? He played the Briar. No, that's right. He played

54:46

the Briar. And I didn't. I didn't

54:48

even know that he played it at the time. I

54:50

mean, he played a lot of things. I didn't know

54:52

he was playing that. And so I

54:54

knew where the pieces go. I knew what I

54:56

was trying to do and where the pieces go.

54:59

And at one point, he

55:01

made an overly aggressive move

55:03

that just was a big

55:06

mistake. And I saw it.

55:08

And I got a winning advantage.

55:11

It wasn't an easy winning advantage.

55:13

I'm convinced that if he had continued the

55:16

game, he would have won. But at some

55:18

point he had a choice of repeating moves

55:20

and he was losing. And

55:22

so, you know, he just repeated moves. I'm

55:24

not saying I would have won. I think

55:26

I would have lost if he kept playing,

55:28

but it just happened. I did it 10

55:30

,000, 20 ,000 times more. I don't think

55:33

it would happen. What do

55:35

you think of Fisher Random as the future

55:37

of chess? Because that seems to be what

55:39

Magnus wants. I don't like it, frankly, but

55:41

what's your opinion? I'm with you, Tyler. I

55:44

mean... mean, I take joy

55:46

from classical chess. I love

55:48

watching a beautiful classical chess

55:50

game. I can relate to

55:52

it. I mean, I'm hardwired

55:54

to think about it. And

55:56

fish or random chess, I mean, it's

55:58

a little bit like looking at problems.

56:00

I respect chess problems, but the positions

56:03

are often weird and improbable. I

56:05

just have trouble relating to fish

56:07

or random chess. I hope I

56:09

change. I'm just speaking from my

56:11

age, but I'm so invested. in

56:13

classical chess. I love classical

56:16

chess. I think about classical chess

56:18

all the time. I

56:20

don't know, why don't you like

56:22

it? With classical chess,

56:25

not every game, but most games, I feel I

56:27

can look at the board and have a decent

56:29

idea what's going on. And I might be wrong,

56:31

but even then, I can figure out exposed why

56:33

I was wrong. With Fisher Random,

56:36

I don't have that sense unless it

56:38

evolves back into a classical looking like

56:40

position. So from a spectator's point of

56:42

view, why should I care? That's how I would

56:44

put it. Yeah. I

56:47

mean, we're on the same page

56:49

on that. But on the other

56:51

hand, you mentioned Gukesh and the

56:53

computers have just dominated the preparation.

56:55

That's why Carlson stopped. He's

56:57

in West Fendall. Yeah. How are we going to solve that

56:59

problem then? If we don't do Fisher random, what

57:02

is your proposed solution? Because I have one. I'll tell

57:04

you mine, but you tell me yours. Tell

57:06

me yours. That we randomize the

57:08

first few moves of the opening.

57:11

So some percentage of games, through

57:13

computer randomization, would be like 1B4,

57:15

1B6, and then they start playing.

57:18

But you do that with many

57:20

permutations. They're all playable positions. As

57:22

you well know, no Grandmaster game

57:24

would go 1B4, 1B6. But

57:26

there's no reason why you can't play from

57:28

that position. And if you have 500 opening

57:31

alternatives like that that the players don't control,

57:33

I just don't think they can prep that much.

57:35

The Berlin, the Marshall, the whatever, all these force

57:38

draws, I think they actually have to play chess.

57:41

I love that idea. And yeah, it

57:43

creates some randomness in what initial positions

57:45

you get. But I love that idea.

57:47

I mean, that sounds much better to

57:49

me. I would much. I have to say

57:51

as a player, I played like

57:54

that because I was very isolated in

57:56

the United States. I wasn't following all

57:58

the opening innovations. So I

58:00

played all kinds of openings to be unpredictable.

58:04

But if everyone does it, it's easier to do.

58:06

It's like every game is between two Ken Reagan's

58:08

is one way to put it. Yeah,

58:11

no, no. I like your idea. I

58:13

think it's a great idea. I endorse

58:16

it. Thank you. Final question for you,

58:18

for our listeners. Your book's

58:20

coming out. It's on very important

58:22

issues of currencies, international trade, international

58:25

finance. It draws upon

58:27

a lifetime of your learning and

58:29

practice and advising. What is

58:31

it you think you'll do next? Well,

58:34

I have a lot, you know, like any academic, I

58:36

already have my next. Few years

58:38

of projects some of them right frankly,

58:40

you know grow out of the book.

58:42

I think people forgotten about political economy

58:45

They just think you know if the

58:47

central bank says the inflation rates 2

58:49

% on average It'll be 2 %

58:51

and we go home and I worked

58:53

on that early in my life I

58:55

wrote the first paper on why you

58:57

should have an independent central bank And

59:00

I'm working on it again, admittedly

59:02

with some very talented young

59:04

people, including Marina Halleck at

59:06

Yale and Pierre Yarra, who's at

59:09

Columbia, but now actually on the

59:11

Council of Economic Advisers, and just

59:14

thinking that. No, the political

59:16

pressures are important. So that's an

59:18

important topic. I'm also working

59:20

on China as an area I've been

59:22

working on for a long time. So

59:24

I have some thoughts about comparing China

59:27

and Japan, for example. But

59:29

I have a lot of things I'm excited about. The

59:31

part of what was so great about

59:33

the book is I had sort of,

59:36

I would describe a mini renaissance in

59:38

my research and I'm able, at

59:40

least I feel that way. I mean,

59:42

the rest of the world thinks that,

59:45

but it It gives me joy to

59:47

have some confidence about some of the

59:49

ideas, although as you say, there's much

59:51

more to it. Again, everyone,

59:53

Ken's new and excellent book is Our

59:56

Dollar, Your Problem. Ken Rogoff, thank you

59:58

very much. Thank

1:00:00

you. Thanks

1:00:05

for listening to Conversations with Tyler.

1:00:07

You can subscribe to the show on

1:00:10

Apple Podcasts, Spotify, or your

1:00:12

favorite podcast app. If you like this

1:00:14

podcast, please consider giving us a

1:00:16

rating and leaving a review. This

1:00:18

helps other listeners find the show.

1:00:20

On Twitter, I'm at Tyler Cowan,

1:00:22

and the show is at Cowan

1:00:25

Convos. Until next time, please

1:00:27

keep listening and learning. you.

Rate

Join Podchaser to...

  • Rate podcasts and episodes
  • Follow podcasts and creators
  • Create podcast and episode lists
  • & much more

Episode Tags

Do you host or manage this podcast?
Claim and edit this page to your liking.
,

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features