Episode Transcript
Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.
Use Ctrl + F to search
0:04
Conversations with Tyler is produced
0:06
by the Mercatus Center at George Mason
0:08
University, bridging the gap
0:10
between academic ideas and real
0:12
-world problems. Learn more at
0:14
mercatus .org. For a full
0:17
transcript of every conversation, enhanced
0:19
with helpful links,
0:21
visit conversationswithtyler.com. Hello
0:26
everyone and welcome back to Conversations
0:28
with Tyler. Today I am
0:31
chatting with Kenneth Rogoff, who is one
0:33
of America's best economists. He
0:35
is a professor at Harvard and
0:37
he has a new book out
0:39
called Our Dollar Your Problem, an
0:42
insider's view of seven turbulent decades
0:44
of global finance and the road
0:46
ahead, can also having extensive experience
0:48
in the IMF and dealing with
0:50
various global crises. Ken,
0:52
welcome! Thank you. It's a
0:55
pleasure to be here, Tyler. Good to speak
0:57
to you. Circa early
0:59
2025, the big
1:01
debate is whether there's such a thing
1:03
as an unsustainable international trade balance. So,
1:07
Orrin Kaff says there is. Michael Pettis
1:09
says there is. Traditional theory is more
1:11
skeptical or agnostic. What's your view? No,
1:14
there's unsustainable debt. There's not particularly
1:17
unsustainable trade deficit. I mean, there's
1:19
Good things about having a trade
1:21
deficit, bad things, but it's a
1:23
result of many factors. So no,
1:26
I wouldn't agree with Pettus on
1:28
that. So what is the mistake
1:30
he and Orrin Cas are making? Well,
1:34
the trade balance depends a
1:36
lot on your savings and
1:38
your investment, these macroeconomic factors.
1:41
If there's an underlying problem, and
1:44
to be fair, when your
1:46
trade deficit's really negative, there
1:48
often is. you know, it
1:50
could be something. I think in the case of
1:52
the United States, when it hit a
1:54
real peak in the
1:56
2005 to 2007, I
1:59
thought there was a problem. I must
2:01
say, I didn't know till very
2:03
close to the event what was
2:06
going on. We weren't regulating well.
2:09
But yeah, I mean, I didn't even know what
2:11
their point is to be honest. I mean, there's
2:13
this mercantilist view. I want to collect all the
2:15
gold in the world. You know, we want to
2:17
be able to buy things. back
2:19
in the day used to have
2:21
to hire an army or navy
2:24
to help fight off invaders and
2:26
such. But today, that's not
2:28
so true. So I
2:30
think the current account deficit, that's a
2:32
broader measure of the deficit. It's
2:35
important. And if it's
2:37
really large, you can probably bet that
2:39
it might go down. But it's not
2:41
something to try to wrestle to the
2:43
ground. There's an
2:45
associated claim I hear, including from Martin
2:48
Wolf, that China
2:50
needs to substitute more into
2:52
consumption to remedy some longer
2:54
term macroeconomic imbalance. Now
2:57
I can see that from a welfare point
2:59
of view, the Chinese oversubsidize investment and might
3:01
be better off consuming more. But is it
3:04
going to boost their growth rate to consume
3:06
more? Well, first of all. They
3:09
subsidize investment like crazy. Of
3:11
course. I mean so investment's
3:14
been 40 % of GDP
3:16
Consumption their different measures, but
3:18
you know 50
3:20
% of GDP maybe we're
3:23
70 % of GDP by
3:25
comparison and it's been very
3:27
imbalanced that it's for a
3:30
command and control economy and
3:32
China's a hybrid economy the central government
3:34
plays a big role Doing
3:36
infrastructure investment subsidizing real estate
3:39
is easy to do and
3:41
they've been doing that for
3:43
a long time and their
3:46
growth has been very imbalanced so
3:48
everybody's been telling them for years
3:50
why don't you build up your
3:52
consumption. But it's
3:55
been hard because they don't have. medical
3:57
care in your old age. They don't
3:59
have social security in their old age.
4:01
They had this one child policy for
4:03
a long time. So there are a
4:05
lot of reasons everyone's had to say
4:07
it. And now their house prices are
4:09
plummeting. And that's for Chinese where a
4:11
lot of their wealth is. So
4:14
I would say it's not a bad idea
4:16
to try a little bit of that, but
4:18
they've dug a very deep hole. It's not
4:21
easy to dig their way out. So
4:23
putting aside the microeconomic distortions, which
4:25
macro model do you use to
4:27
think through the question of whether
4:29
or not China should consume more?
4:31
Do you use the solo model
4:33
or Romer or something else? What's
4:37
your got? Those are nice models, but I
4:39
mean, let's be honest. I mean, they're just
4:41
a piece of things. They do
4:44
tell us that at the end of
4:46
the day, you need to have
4:48
innovation. If you're just
4:50
growing by building more
4:52
machines, by building more
4:54
roads, you run into
4:57
diminishing returns, and you get less
4:59
and less with the output. That's what happened
5:01
to Russia. That's what happened to Japan. That's
5:03
what happened to a lot of Asia. And
5:05
for some reason, people thought that
5:07
wouldn't happen to China. But their
5:09
rate of innovation over the whole
5:11
economy, I'm not talking about the
5:13
highest level, has collapsed by many
5:15
different measures. And the private
5:18
sectors, of course, the root of all
5:20
the innovation. They have oppressed
5:22
the private sector, particularly in the
5:24
last 10 years. And so, you
5:27
know, for them to grow again,
5:29
they need to restore some agency
5:31
to the private sector. We're
5:34
in the midst of some tariff debates
5:36
right now, as you know. And one
5:38
argument I hear sometimes even from the
5:40
anti -tariff people is that if the
5:42
US but higher tariffs on China, while
5:44
the Chinese currency just appreciates the dollar
5:46
strengthens, there isn't that much of a
5:48
net effect. Because arguably they're propping up
5:50
their currency some amount now. Do you
5:53
agree with that? Well,
5:56
what you said is exactly right.
5:58
I mean, so I to a first
6:00
approximation if we put on a I
6:03
don't know whatever it is a 20 %
6:05
tariff it has an effect on our exchange
6:07
rate of making it go up which makes
6:09
our exports more expensive and makes their goods
6:12
less expensive and I mean, I don't really
6:14
get wonky, but if you did it on
6:16
the whole world, you can get wonky. I
6:18
can get wonky with you. Absolutely. If you
6:21
did a 20 % tariff on the whole
6:23
world, to a first approximation, your exchange rate
6:25
goes up 10 % the dollar. And
6:28
so, you know, that rebalances everything.
6:31
That brings the cost of their
6:33
goods back to just a 10 %
6:35
rise. And it makes your exports 10
6:37
% more expensive because the currency appreciate
6:40
it. So that's definitely an effect. Of
6:43
course, they're probably going to
6:45
retaliate and then that cancels it
6:47
out. But do they want
6:49
to retaliate? Don't they prefer the
6:51
outcome where the tariff approaches some
6:53
kind of neutrality? Given that
6:55
they have an overvalued currency right now, they
6:57
could have a decline, basically
7:00
be insulated from the tariff, not have to
7:02
worry about Trump so much anymore. Why
7:04
should they retaliate? They
7:06
have a lot of distortions in their
7:09
economy, but the days when it was
7:11
very clear cut that they had an
7:13
overvalued, Currency, I mean are far gone.
7:16
I mean, but it used to be
7:18
undervalued, right? Those days are very far
7:20
gone. So you're saying that their currency
7:23
now is overvalued. I think And they
7:25
want to bring it down. They have
7:27
all this producer price deflation, right? So
7:30
they should be expansionary on the monetary side
7:32
to have a more predictable path of nominal
7:34
GDP growth, but they're not doing it. So
7:36
probably their currency is a bit too high.
7:39
Relative to an optimum? Well, I
7:41
mean, a logical way to do it
7:44
would be to do more expansionary fiscal
7:46
policy, more expansionary monetary policy. We
7:49
don't really try to deal with producer
7:51
price inflation through the exchange rate. I
7:53
mean, exports and imports are important to
7:55
China, but it's also a very big
7:57
economy. There's a lot of stuff, you
7:59
know, like the infrastructure investment and
8:02
other investment that's internal. Sure,
8:04
but if they had higher price inflation, the
8:07
value of the renminbi in real terms would
8:09
fall somewhat, at least for a while, right?
8:12
And that would be better, which means the current rate is
8:14
somewhat higher than it ought to be. I
8:16
mean, they're running a massive surplus to
8:18
the rest of the world. The
8:21
total size of their trade -bound surplus is
8:23
only 2 % of GDP. It's
8:25
not like 10 % the way it was in 2010,
8:28
but They've gotten a lot bigger.
8:30
It's still huge compared to the world. So
8:33
I'm being in crude measures of if
8:35
their exchange rate's overvalued and undervalued. I
8:38
don't think you come to a simple
8:40
answer. The dollar is very rich. I
8:42
mean, so in a sense, everybody seems
8:45
cheap to the dollar right now. I'm
8:48
sure you've experienced that with your anyone
8:50
coming from abroad, even from Japan or
8:52
Switzerland. Oh my gosh, it's so expensive
8:54
here. Feel free to
8:57
give a wonky answer to this one.
8:59
But why do you think it's been
9:01
so hard for economics to develop a
9:04
satisfactory theory of exchange rates? So purchasing
9:06
power parity seems to hold only within
9:08
very broad bands, something like 2x. And
9:11
the rest just seems very murky. Why is that
9:13
so difficult? Well, I
9:16
mean, part of it is if you
9:18
have floating exchange rates, there's a lot
9:20
of financial factors that are hard to
9:22
understand that move it around a lot.
9:25
we're not able to easily
9:27
identify those factors. But
9:29
I think more and more theory empirics
9:32
is coalesced around things
9:34
like bank balance sheets,
9:37
so can banks arbitrage
9:39
exchange rates and various
9:41
pricing imperfections. So
9:44
I think the weight of research the
9:46
past 10 or 15 years has been
9:48
that the exchange rate moves a lot,
9:50
but it's not really moving around the
9:52
economy with it. And we've thought that
9:54
for a long time. But
9:56
I think the general view today, I
9:59
mean, it isn't always true, but that a
10:01
lot of the movements have to
10:03
do with financial frictions and financial
10:05
factors, not some gnomes controlling the
10:08
exchange rate, that there's a lot
10:10
of random noise. But
10:12
do you think we need a
10:14
good theory of both real and
10:16
nominal exchange rates to make reliable
10:19
policy recommendations? If we
10:21
don't really know what the exchange rate will be
10:23
doing and why, doesn't that put us in the
10:25
slightly odd position that we're saying, do this, do
10:27
that, but the most fundamental price variable is a
10:29
mystery to us? As
10:32
you may know, I mean, I think
10:34
my first important paper was showing how
10:36
hard it was to explain exchange rates.
10:38
I'm embarrassed to say it's about 45
10:40
years ago. And I think
10:42
the policy conclusions people drew out of
10:45
that is look at the exchange rate
10:47
when you're trying to figure out what
10:49
policy should be. Look at inflation rate.
10:51
Look at output. I think
10:53
for some countries, they're
10:56
so deep into dollar debt. They're
10:58
so connected with the dollar and trade,
11:00
they do worry about their exchange rate.
11:03
So it sort of depends on if
11:05
you're talking about a big country like
11:07
the United States, or are you talking
11:09
about New Zealand or something like that?
11:12
But I mean, I think generally policymakers
11:14
need to recognize there's a lot of
11:16
noise. So trying to
11:18
target the exchange rate is a fool's
11:21
game. And if
11:23
the Trump administration is trying
11:25
to do it, they might
11:27
get lucky, but it's pure luck.
11:30
So if I take the country of
11:32
Pakistan, I think it's now been through
11:34
maybe 23 or 24 IMF bailouts. That's
11:36
a lot. The problems aren't fixed. So
11:38
we would all say here's ways Pakistan
11:40
could improve. Probably you and I would
11:43
largely agree on those. But just from
11:45
an external point of view, say you're
11:47
dictator of the IMF, you're the dirt
11:49
managing director, you're the board, you're the
11:51
staff. What is it you would actually
11:53
do with Pakistan? I
11:56
mean, that's, you know, the deep.
11:58
Seated problems, the military is very,
12:00
very powerful in the country. The
12:03
military is very corrupt, runs
12:05
a lot of the businesses, has a lot
12:07
of control. So,
12:10
I mean, it really runs deep
12:12
into the institutions in the country.
12:14
It's not something you can like
12:16
airlift some expert like you or
12:18
I and just tell them what
12:20
to do. I mean, believe me,
12:22
there are a lot of very
12:24
smart Pakistani economists who know what
12:26
to do. But do you sign
12:28
off on bailout number 25 when that comes
12:31
along? You're in charge. I
12:33
mean, first of all,
12:36
if you don't sign off on bailout
12:38
number 25, they're going to default on
12:40
bailout number 24. You're rolling over the
12:42
stat all the time. And
12:44
it's very sensitive politically. Pakistan's
12:47
a country that's very, very
12:49
geopolitically important. So you can't
12:51
look at the programs there
12:53
as if you're lending to
12:55
the UK. It's something very
12:58
different. And the amounts are
13:00
small compared to if you're
13:02
lending to the UK. But
13:04
frankly, what I have advised
13:06
on things like Pakistan is just give
13:09
them aid. Don't give loans.
13:11
you're never going to collect the loans.
13:13
You're not seriously meeting their loans. And
13:15
so it sounds great to say, well,
13:17
we just lent the money to Pakistan.
13:20
But I think in general, in money
13:22
we're giving to developing countries, too much
13:24
of it comes in the form of
13:26
loans. And it distorts what we do
13:28
because we don't get them all repaid.
13:32
How many Latin and Caribbean economies
13:34
should dollarize? If you have, right,
13:36
should more? I
13:39
mean, it's a pretty desperate measure
13:41
when you dollarize and there are
13:43
different ways to dollarize. You
13:45
know, when I just came into
13:47
the International Monetary Fund in 2001, Argentina
13:50
had dollarized. They had been dollarized for 10
13:52
years and I said, you know, isn't this
13:54
great? But that was a peg. It wasn't
13:56
real dollars, right? I mean, like El Salvador,
13:59
Ecuador, Paraguay. I mean, actually, you want to
14:01
actually use the dollar, circulate the dollar. Right,
14:03
because that's credible. And those of us,
14:05
whether you like them or not, they've all stuck, right? I
14:08
mean, you can do it. I mean, it has
14:10
its costs. The biggest cost is
14:12
if your banking system runs into trouble,
14:15
you can't bail them out. So
14:17
in most countries, the currency
14:19
that we think of the physical currency
14:21
is just like a little piece of
14:23
the animal. A lot of it, you
14:26
might not think of your checking account
14:28
or your savings account as dollars, but
14:31
they are. That's a lot of the
14:33
money supply. So when you
14:35
say they're just using real dollars, they
14:37
don't have real dollars to back those
14:40
bank accounts. So it can
14:42
work. But you run into
14:44
banking crises. You run into debt
14:46
crises. And then when you're dollarized,
14:48
it's hard to fight it. So
14:50
it's doable. It's absolutely doable. But
14:53
I'm not sure necessarily it's advisable.
14:55
It depends on the alternative. If
14:57
the country's been run into the
15:00
ground for 50 years and you're
15:02
trying to reclaimed territory. It makes
15:04
sense. Why isn't it easy
15:06
for a lot of countries? Say you're Barbados.
15:08
That's a small country. Most of
15:10
your visitors are from the US also. Your
15:13
banking system, you can just buy external
15:15
insurance, right? There's an insurer that can
15:17
cover the Barbados banking system if need
15:19
be. Buy it from China if
15:21
you have to, and then just dollarize. Why aren't
15:23
they just better off? Okay,
15:26
I'm being naive, but is there an insurer
15:28
who's going to bail out the Barbados banking
15:30
system? I mean, I think our
15:32
regulators would make that difficult. Their regulators would
15:34
make it difficult. I mean, you would need
15:37
to have something like that. And there's a
15:39
lot of moral hazards. So you
15:41
really, if you're going to be an insurer,
15:43
you can't just insure you have to have,
15:45
you know, 150 people on shore looking at
15:47
them all the time. I mean, that's not
15:49
easy to do. The only country in the
15:52
world really, which can bail out its banking
15:54
systems, Hong Kong. they have enough
15:56
dollar reserves to bail out
15:58
everything. But that's the problem with
16:00
dollarization. If you're not
16:03
going to have banks, it's great.
16:05
But we want to have lending
16:07
and mortgages and car loans and
16:09
stuff. And it's very
16:11
easy to run into trouble. Why
16:15
did Japan never have a financial crisis?
16:17
So very high debt to GDP ratio.
16:20
Growth rate is... slow
16:22
in per capita terms. It's not as
16:24
bad as it sounds at first, but
16:26
nothing gangbusters. How have they held on?
16:29
Well, they did have a financial
16:32
crisis the mother of all financial
16:34
crises in the 90s. Oh sure,
16:36
but since then and since then
16:38
well have they hung on in
16:40
1990 and even in the early
16:42
90s their per capita GDP was
16:45
80 % of the United States
16:47
and purchasing power parity measures and
16:49
trying to put into common price
16:51
level. But in dollars,
16:53
it was well over 100 %
16:55
of the US. Today, it's
16:57
60 % in those measures. I mean,
16:59
it is not held on in per
17:02
capita terms. It has just, you know,
17:04
not had growth for a long time.
17:06
And they're running into trouble. There's per
17:08
capita growth in Japan. Maybe,
17:10
I don't know. Yeah, but nothing like
17:12
in the United States. I mean, we...
17:14
Well, we've beaten every advanced economy, not
17:16
just Japan. That's fair, but
17:19
they've fallen behind France, the
17:21
UK, Germany. They were ahead of
17:23
all of them. They've fallen far behind. And
17:26
they're in trouble now because
17:28
they're finally having inflation. They're
17:31
needing to raise interest rates. They've
17:33
stuffed government debt into every
17:36
orifice of the economy, into
17:38
the pension systems, into the
17:40
banks, into their postal savings
17:42
system. And now, they're
17:45
talking about cutting pensions, cutting
17:47
old age benefits, because suddenly
17:50
they're having to make interest
17:52
payments on the debt and
17:55
it's harder. So I
17:57
think people who use Japan as
17:59
an example of everything's fine, you
18:02
know, have their head in the sand.
18:04
I mean, it's an example of if
18:06
you're very rich, you can
18:08
go down slowly. But it's not an
18:11
example of how you know, you can
18:13
have fantastic economy with doubt like that
18:15
But why do some places say
18:17
the much earlier UK they have crises
18:20
and Japan Whatever the standard of living
18:22
issues may be right. There's no crisis.
18:24
There's no run on anything. It's quite
18:27
peaceful It is it is a very
18:29
you know society which obviously is Very
18:31
high degree of cohesion and that's a
18:34
tremendous strength of Japan. I just have
18:36
got a side mention if I can
18:38
I mean I I was a
18:40
visitor at the Bank of Japan in
18:43
the early 90s in the middle of
18:45
their meltdown Although I didn't see it
18:47
and I don't think anyone did at
18:50
the time And I had to eat
18:52
at the cafeteria every day and that
18:54
almost the same food that you had
18:57
to eat and it was good But
18:59
now I saw another line once and
19:01
I asked can I go in
19:03
that line? And the people said, oh,
19:06
well, that's if you want a smaller
19:08
portion. I mean, it's a
19:10
very different society than we have.
19:13
But they have a lot of
19:15
financial oppression. Financial oppression is going
19:17
to be part of the solution
19:19
in every advanced country where you
19:22
force banks, insurance companies, pension funds
19:24
to hold more debt. We've done
19:26
that already. And they've
19:28
done it in a big
19:30
way. It's hurt their financial
19:32
intermediation, so it makes lending
19:34
less efficient. And that's part
19:36
of why their growth has
19:38
suffered. So they've done a
19:40
good job becoming sclerotic slowly.
19:43
But I hardly think we would
19:45
want to imitate them, especially if
19:48
we intend to compete with China.
19:51
Is that what the European Union is going to
19:53
do, financial repression? They
19:55
did it already. I
19:57
mean they'll have to do it
20:00
again. They still have all these
20:02
major debt problems Yeah, I mean
20:04
they did it big time after
20:06
the European debt crisis. So just
20:08
a simple fact about that is
20:10
it used to be that say
20:12
Italian debt was held in Germany
20:14
Spanish that was held in Germany
20:16
spread all over now the
20:18
vast majority of the Italian
20:20
banks are holding all the
20:23
Italian bank. Spanish banks are
20:25
holding all the Spanish. Do
20:28
you think that's because they're diversifying?
20:30
No, it's because they're being ordered to do that.
20:33
So they have a lot of financial oppression already.
20:36
They don't have dynamic capital markets
20:38
for a lot of reasons. And
20:41
obviously, they need to remilitarize
20:43
now. You know, Germany has
20:45
a lot of fiscal space, so. They
20:47
can go all out. But especially now
20:49
that interest rates are real interest rates
20:51
are hitting a higher level, they're going
20:53
to have to do it. But I
20:55
think they're going to find they have
20:57
to give things up in order to
20:59
do it because the interest rates aren't
21:01
zero anymore. So you think they'll
21:04
actually cut spending, say in France? I
21:07
mean, I don't disagree
21:09
with you, but it somehow
21:11
feels unimaginable to me. Yeah,
21:14
I mean, many of the European countries
21:16
actually tighten their pension systems a lot
21:19
during the European crisis. They set it
21:21
in place to take place 10 or
21:23
15 years later, not France. Yeah,
21:25
I do. I think this is a
21:27
real existential challenge to the French state.
21:30
I mean, maybe they'll take over
21:32
as the tech capital the world.
21:34
Maybe they'll, you know, find ways
21:37
to solve their problems. But they've
21:39
been free riding off the United
21:41
States. There's no question about that.
21:43
And now they have to spend
21:46
more. I'm not praising Trump's policies.
21:48
Let's not conflate those two things.
21:51
But yes, I think they're going to
21:53
find they have taxes are very, very
21:55
high in Europe. In fact, so much
21:57
so that there's no question it holds
22:00
back a lot of investment. Europe
22:02
has very few world beaters,
22:05
terms of tech, finance.
22:08
The biggest companies set
22:10
aside the Danish company
22:12
that's Ozenpec, they're things
22:14
like Hermes, Prada, sort
22:17
of lifestyle superpower stuff. No,
22:19
I think this is absolutely an existential
22:21
crisis for real. It may lead to
22:23
them becoming more cohesive. It
22:26
may lead to them becoming
22:28
more of a geopolitical power.
22:31
But yes, they're going to have to make
22:33
choices, which they haven't had to make. If
22:36
the nation is Italy, and I think that
22:38
the birth rate at TFR is about 1
22:40
.3 on average, Are they
22:42
just going to wake up one morning and say
22:44
the whole welfare state thing was a mistake and
22:46
we're getting rid of it? I mean, isn't that
22:48
the implication? Well, that's a
22:51
kind of strong statement and they're
22:53
not going to do that, but
22:55
But if the country keeps on
22:57
shrinking the age pyramid gets worse
23:00
and worse Yeah, we all we
23:02
all face we all face this
23:04
issue and hope that innovation and
23:06
growth or something will help but
23:09
Yeah, I know the demographics is
23:11
a problem in every country in
23:13
Italy, as you say, as much
23:15
far, far ahead of the United
23:17
States on the demographics. I mean,
23:20
an interesting fact is they spend
23:22
a mind -numbing 15 % of
23:24
GDP on old age pensions and
23:26
support now. I mean,
23:28
we're half that, you know, all in. and
23:31
15 % of GDP. And
23:34
so, yeah, they have a lot of constraints
23:36
and their tax rates are very high. They're
23:40
not corrupt like in Pakistan, but
23:43
it's not Sweden either. I mean, it's
23:45
got a lot of problems. And
23:48
just predictively, what do you think the United
23:50
States will do with its fiscal position? That
23:54
is a darn good question. I
23:56
mean, looking Way
23:58
forward, I would just we're on
24:00
an unsustainable path. We will
24:03
continue to have our debt balloon. And
24:06
eventually, not necessarily in a
24:08
planned or coherent way, I
24:11
think we're going to have another big inflation
24:13
soon. Next five to seven years, that's
24:16
maybe sooner with what's going on.
24:19
And that's going to bring it down.
24:21
Just like it did under Biden, it
24:23
brought the debt down. But then the
24:25
markets are, you know, Fool me once
24:27
shame on you, you know fool me
24:30
twice. No, we're raising the interest rate
24:32
and Then we'll have to you know
24:34
make choices. I mean, I think in
24:36
the United States a lot of the
24:38
choices I'd start to say it probably
24:40
point towards higher taxation Because we're hardly
24:43
running a welfare state. It's not all
24:45
due respects and I'm not sure I
24:47
have any due respects to doge They're
24:49
not that many things to cut in
24:51
the United States compared to to many
24:54
other countries. So I don't know what
24:56
the choice will be. I mean, I
24:58
probably won't be here. And you might
25:00
not be either when we're making the
25:02
choices. But I think we'll both be
25:05
here. Well, it
25:07
could be. It could happen much sooner.
25:09
I mean, on the other hand, it's
25:11
hard to know what's going through Trump's
25:13
head. So I, you
25:15
know, I presumed he was
25:17
going to blow up the deficit like everybody
25:19
else. We'll see.
25:22
And when you say big inflation, how big
25:24
is big? Well,
25:26
I think this time it'll be,
25:29
so last time we probably had
25:31
a bonus 10 % inflation over
25:33
the 2 % target cumulatively, maybe
25:35
12%. I think this time it'll
25:37
be more in the order cumulatively
25:39
over the 2 % target, 20%,
25:42
25%. I mean, there's going to
25:44
be an adjustment. I
25:46
don't think the debt is going to
25:48
be the sole contribution to that. There
25:50
are many factors. You have
25:52
to impinge on Federal Reserve independence. Probably
25:55
there'll be some shock, you know, which
25:57
will justify it. I don't know how
25:59
it's going to play out. But
26:02
I think I know that for
26:04
years, people have said the US
26:07
debt is unsustainable. But
26:09
it hasn't come to roost
26:11
because we've lived through this
26:13
post financial crisis. post
26:15
-pandemic era of very, very low
26:17
and negative real interest rates. That
26:20
is not the norm. There's regression
26:22
to mean. You know what? It's
26:24
happened. And suddenly,
26:27
the interest payments start piling up.
26:29
I think they've gone at least
26:31
doubled over the last few years.
26:34
They're on quickly on their way to tripling,
26:36
going up to a trillion dollars. And
26:39
so suddenly, it's more than
26:41
our defense spending. That's the
26:43
most important macro change in the
26:45
world that real interest rates appear
26:48
to have regressed more towards long
26:50
-term trend. What's the
26:52
most plausible scenario you can imagine where the
26:55
US does not have to make any major
26:57
adjustment? I'm not saying you're predicting it. I'm
26:59
not saying you think it's very plausible, but
27:01
you have to come up with something. What
27:03
is it? Oh, I don't
27:06
think there's any question. It's
27:08
that the AI revolution turns
27:10
out to, you know, just
27:12
work magically much better than
27:14
we, you know, anyone imagine
27:16
that people like me quietly
27:18
acquiesce to just getting transfers
27:20
from the government instead of
27:22
having jobs. And we just,
27:24
you know, continue to have
27:26
a high income and the
27:28
robot income pays for everything.
27:31
I mean, but AI is absolutely
27:33
the thing which is most likely,
27:35
you know, some kind of technological
27:37
change. You know, other than that,
27:39
the problems in our politics, it's
27:41
in our DNA. We're convinced
27:43
that, you know, we're immortals, and
27:45
we can just do whatever we
27:48
want. That's you go around Washington
27:50
and whatever they say, I think
27:52
that's what they think. And again,
27:55
this key thing. is that real
27:57
interest rates, the interest rate adjusted
27:59
for expected inflation. And I'm
28:01
looking at the long term, they've come
28:03
up and they're not super high, but
28:05
they're more like they were in the
28:08
early 2000s. And I think of reasonable
28:10
projections, they're going to stay around the
28:12
level they are. I'm
28:14
sure you know the classic Paul Samuelson
28:16
paper on overlapping generations model. And in
28:19
that paper, the real interest rate is
28:21
equal to the rate of population growth.
28:23
There's other papers where the real interest
28:26
rate is in broad harmony with the
28:28
rate of productivity growth. If either of
28:30
those models are correct, aren't we okay
28:33
again? Well,
28:35
first of all, if it's population
28:37
growth and productivity alone, then you're
28:39
losing tax dollars at the same
28:41
time you're paying less interest. But
28:44
it turns out those variables don't
28:46
work so well over a longer
28:49
period. I have a paper in
28:51
the American Economic Review just last
28:53
August about this. you look over
28:56
longer time periods, you
28:58
know, just because economists think that those should
29:00
be the dominant variables, it doesn't turn out
29:02
to work that well. And all this stuff,
29:04
there've been a lot of papers by economists
29:07
looking at the decline, it's going
29:09
the real interest rate going down, demographics
29:11
going down, productivity going down, looks great.
29:13
If you look at a longer period,
29:16
there's no there or there. I mean,
29:18
it just doesn't stand up. So I
29:20
think there are other factors having to
29:22
do with liquidity. default
29:24
risk, changing nature of the
29:27
production function, globalization. I
29:30
think there are many variables where
29:32
assuming there's going to be some
29:34
reversion to mean is just a
29:36
pretty good thing to have in
29:38
the back of your head. You
29:41
know, you know, Carmen Reinhardt and I had
29:43
this book this time is different. Very much
29:45
on the theme of people just looking at
29:47
five years or 10 years and think, oh,
29:49
it's just great. it's just going to go
29:52
like this. And I think the
29:54
real interest rates, an example, I would say
29:56
the low inflation is another example. My
29:58
students for a long time just
30:00
didn't believe there'd ever be inflation
30:02
again. I would teach it, they would
30:04
fall asleep. I mean, I remember
30:07
asking a question even to someone who was
30:09
a research assistant at a big central bank,
30:11
explain this to me about inflation. And
30:14
she said, My generation doesn't ever expect
30:16
to think about inflation. We don't have
30:18
it. Let me give you examples of
30:20
this. So no, I would
30:23
suspect we will have high real estate.
30:25
And by the way, AI will raise
30:27
the interest rate. But productivity, too. the
30:30
case where it goes up with productivity. It
30:32
does raise productivity, but the usual
30:34
thing about demographics is there are
30:36
less people to work with the
30:38
machines, and therefore, the return on
30:40
the machines is lower and the
30:42
interest rate goes down. But
30:45
if the people are being
30:47
substituted for, which is new,
30:50
I mean, we've always found a
30:53
way to reinsert ourselves. You won't
30:55
necessarily, even in a theoretical model,
30:57
like Samuel Sons or Solos, get
31:00
that effect. You
31:02
wrote a famous 1987 paper on
31:05
political business cycle theory. How
31:07
relevant do you think political business cycles have
31:09
been since then? Well, there's
31:11
been a lot of papers on it. I mean, I
31:13
don't think there's any question. Every politician
31:16
in the world, if they have
31:18
the power, tries to goose up
31:20
the economy before it happens. I
31:23
think empirically, it's overwhelming that it's
31:25
true. The question is, why does
31:27
it fool anyone? Everybody should understand
31:30
why that's going on. And
31:32
without going to tales, that paper
31:34
was about the paradox that I
31:36
know you're just making things look
31:38
good. I know you're hiding something from
31:41
me so that you're exaggerating how long
31:43
this can go on, how much
31:45
it's costing, but I'm going to vote
31:47
for you anyway. And so
31:49
that's what that paper was. It
31:52
looked at as a signaling model
31:54
that's getting really wonky. But
31:56
the fiscal versions of political business cycle
31:58
theory, they don't have to fool anyone,
32:00
right? You do get
32:03
the money, and society as a whole has to
32:05
pay it back, but you can come out ahead.
32:09
There's another, I'm going to just
32:11
translate it a little bit from
32:13
my model, one that Alberto Ellisina,
32:15
my late colleague Alberto Ellisina did
32:17
and a number of others that
32:20
said, part of the reason debt
32:22
keeps piling up is we have,
32:24
you know, the liberal party, the
32:26
conservative party, when the liberal parties
32:28
in power, they know that debt
32:30
is bad, but they know they
32:33
can spend now. And they know
32:35
they might not control it in
32:37
the future, so they spend a
32:39
lot and they borrow. When the
32:41
conservatives are in power, they cut
32:43
taxes and build up the debt.
32:46
I think that's a very powerful, very,
32:48
very powerful theory of part of why
32:50
debt builds up is whoever's in power,
32:53
you know, says, don't pay any attention to
32:55
it. And of course, you know, I
32:57
think we end up where we
33:00
are now. In an
33:02
earlier book, you called for the phasing out
33:04
of currency and large denomination bills. Do you
33:06
still want to do this? I
33:09
call out for phasing most
33:12
currency. I'm not phasing
33:14
it all out right away. That takes,
33:16
you know, generation. Well, Sweden's done it.
33:18
I mean, it doesn't take that long
33:20
if people are on board. It's very
33:22
hard to run across currency in Sweden
33:25
today. You're right and they didn't even
33:27
pass laws. You're right. You have to
33:29
travel 150 kilometers to get to an
33:31
ATM machine, but it's not completely phased
33:33
out by any means and it's still
33:35
there. So, first
33:38
of all, we've had enough inflation
33:40
that the $100 bill is now
33:43
a $75 bill, I'll say to
33:45
start with. But, you know,
33:47
most of the world's currencies held in
33:49
these large denomination notes. I
33:52
mean, I done further work, very
33:54
little of it's used in transactions.
33:56
I think most of it is in
33:58
the underground economy. It's
34:01
not necessarily nefarious. There's drug
34:03
dealing, human smuggling and
34:06
everything, human trafficking. But I
34:08
think the large majority of it is tax
34:10
evasion. I mean, lots of people do that.
34:13
Okay, I mean, I'm not
34:15
trying to be holier than
34:17
thou and just say everybody
34:19
does that is evil. But
34:22
I'm looking from the government's point of view, making
34:25
money by saying, hey, people love
34:27
these $100 bills and not figuring
34:29
out that they're using them not
34:31
to pay taxes. I've argued that
34:33
that's pennywise and pound foolish. And
34:36
yeah, that's sort of the core of
34:38
the argument. But from an efficiency point
34:40
of view, don't you want to kind
34:42
of price discrimination in your tax system?
34:44
Just say people pay their nannies with
34:46
$100 bills. They wouldn't hire the nanny
34:49
if they had to pay taxes. Furthermore,
34:51
if the transaction were recorded, they'd have
34:53
to worry about social security issues. It's
34:55
a lot of paperwork and bureaucracy, very
34:57
forbidding for a lot of people. And
35:00
you're just lowering output by not making
35:02
it easy for them to pay the
35:04
nanny with cash. So I do think
35:06
about that, but the questions why we
35:08
need $100 bills for that mean you
35:10
can pay your nanny with 20s and
35:12
they'll be perfectly happy because actually the
35:15
$100 bills are harder to work with,
35:17
you know, for them. So,
35:19
no, I think you want to
35:21
have ways that you can evade
35:24
the law up to a point.
35:26
I mean, marijuana is now legal
35:28
in most places and maybe the
35:30
whole culture and society wouldn't have
35:32
them all. if we didn't have
35:34
a cash economy that could pay
35:37
for that. So again,
35:39
I think it's a question of
35:41
calibration, regulation, where you want
35:43
to put things. Do you
35:45
worry about the example of the Canadian truckers
35:48
where it becomes too easy to cut off
35:50
people's bank accounts and there's too much social
35:52
power over a lot of people? Well,
35:55
again, I'm getting rid
35:58
of the large denomination notes and
36:00
not straightforwardly the
36:02
others and so yeah no we don't
36:04
want to over I absolutely agree there's
36:06
government accesses. The questions you know do
36:08
we have you know we have we
36:10
have drugs that you know help people
36:13
after an operation but it and we
36:15
want to have them but does it
36:17
want to mean mean we want to
36:19
have them freely floating in the economy.
36:22
And also, we can phase out $100
36:24
bills and $50 bills and we can
36:27
change our mind later and decide that
36:29
we overdid it. I don't think we
36:31
would. I think continue to go in
36:33
that direction. But it's a
36:36
matter of costs and benefits. Do
36:38
we also have to ban stablecoins
36:40
then? Because you can make $100,
36:43
$500 transaction in stablecoins. And
36:45
not everyone's used to doing that now, but you
36:47
figure within two years, your AI can do it
36:50
for you if need be. And
36:52
we're just pushing more people into stablecoins. Well,
36:55
absolutely. So in the same book,
36:57
I said we need to regulate
37:00
cryptocurrency. And there are different kinds
37:02
of stablecoins. And it's not clear
37:05
where it's ending up in the
37:07
long run. But I think stablecoins
37:09
eventually have to have some kind
37:12
of parallel revealability. to
37:14
what bank accounts have, not necessarily
37:16
exactly the same, but I know
37:18
that's where we're headed. I think
37:20
the regulators are pretty favorable to
37:23
stablecoins actually on the whole, but
37:25
not if they're being used to
37:27
evade taxes and all kinds of
37:29
regulations. But the issuers can
37:31
be abroad. In that sense, it's quite different
37:33
from domestic banks, from currency. Someone
37:36
has a stablecoin account in the Cayman
37:38
Islands, and they make a transaction with
37:40
someone with a stablecoin account in Estonia.
37:43
How much say do the US regulators really
37:45
have over that? Well,
37:47
we don't have much say over that.
37:49
I mean, you already have that the
37:51
case to some extent with bank accounts,
37:54
and you can mitigate the problem. You
37:56
can't eliminate it. I mean, that's generally
37:58
true of cryptocurrency. You
38:01
can try to regulate it.
38:03
You can't completely eliminate it.
38:05
I mean, probably a lot
38:07
of sanctions evasion. is being
38:09
done with stablecoins and cryptocurrency.
38:12
And clearly, we have not been able to touch that.
38:16
Should the US issue a
38:18
CBDC, a digital coin? Let
38:20
me put it this way. I don't think
38:23
we should be the first to try this.
38:25
Right now, we're on top. I mean,
38:28
I kind of think we peed, but
38:30
that's another question. We're winning.
38:32
Why do you want to change the
38:34
rules of the game when we're winning?
38:36
Because it's not about the currency. It's
38:38
about treasury bills. It's about the interest
38:40
payment. It's about market clearing. And
38:43
also, we're so big, we
38:45
probably are more likely
38:47
headed towards having competitive
38:49
stablecoins, which are regulated,
38:51
which have some kind of lender
38:54
of last resort than a CBDC.
38:57
I'm skeptical about it. you
38:59
put yourself in a position where
39:01
one screw -up can paralyze everything.
39:04
And it wouldn't be good if
39:06
we had five stablecoins and one
39:08
of them had a problem. But
39:10
I tend to think that's something
39:12
for Latvia or Singapore to try
39:14
and not necessarily the US, maybe
39:17
in 50 years. To
39:19
be fair, Europe's talking about it. But
39:21
they're talking about what we call a
39:23
wholesale CBDC, which is among the banks.
39:26
And that's a completely different animal. A
39:29
standard macro puzzle today, we had
39:31
a disinflation from post COVID inflation.
39:33
It went from 8 .9 %
39:35
to something not too far from
39:37
3%. And there's no big recession.
39:39
How do you interpret that? Were the
39:41
rational expectations people write that it was credible and
39:43
we just did it? Or the people who say
39:45
it was all supply shocks, are they right? Or
39:47
it's a big puzzle to me. What do you
39:50
think? Well,
39:52
I think it is a big puzzle. It's the
39:54
first thing to say. I mean, I'm not gonna
39:56
claim I thought that was going
39:58
to be painless bringing the inflation rate down.
40:00
I don't think I was out there quite
40:02
at the Larry Summers level, banging on the
40:04
table, saying that there had to be a
40:06
big recession. I certainly do
40:09
not buy the idea was all supply
40:11
shocks. That's just nonsense. So
40:13
there are these people who say, oh,
40:15
it was just the supply chain, the
40:17
shipping lanes were closed and all that
40:19
stuff. And as soon as the supply
40:21
chains were back, inflation was down. Excuse
40:23
me, the supply chain problems make the
40:25
price go up. when they go away,
40:28
the price should come down. It did
40:30
not. And so there
40:32
clearly was, you know, even in
40:34
countries which didn't do as much
40:36
macro stimulus as we did, they
40:38
did a lot. And they all,
40:40
of course, kept their monetary policy
40:42
easy. But yeah, I mean,
40:44
the credibility is remarkable. I
40:47
mean, if you look at inflation expectations, they
40:50
moved a little bit. I mean, I'm
40:52
talking about the professional the consumer
40:55
ones moved a little more, but
40:57
consider what just happened. That
41:00
inflation expectations didn't move more. It's remarkable.
41:02
And to come back to the earlier point
41:05
about solving our debt, if we ever have
41:07
an inflation, I don't think that's
41:09
going to happen again. When we have a
41:11
second inflation, that time the
41:13
credibility is really going to be shot. What
41:16
else do you think of as an
41:18
unresolved puzzle in macro besides the disinflation?
41:22
Boy, that's a really good. thing because
41:24
I think about research questions all the
41:26
time. It's certainly been
41:28
very surprising to me of
41:31
how much bank regulation has
41:33
created all these arbitrage issues
41:35
across things that didn't exist.
41:38
I'm not sure this completely
41:40
unresolved, but when I was
41:42
doing my book with Mori
41:45
Absel, we thought of what
41:47
we call covered interest parity
41:49
as just something that holds.
41:52
you know, law. In other words, if
41:55
you borrow in one country and you
41:57
borrow in another country but do some
41:59
kind of forward contract undo it, you
42:01
get the same interest rate. It's not
42:04
true anymore. And I think
42:06
there's just a range of these puzzles that
42:08
have come up since the crisis. I
42:11
suppose another one would be, you know,
42:13
what kind of inflation rate do we
42:15
really want to have? There's a lot
42:17
of debate about that. There are people
42:19
who say, it shouldn't be
42:21
2%, it should be 4%, some
42:23
people it should be 0%. I
42:25
think that's a big question. Do
42:28
you have any guess on the covered
42:31
interest parity issue because that bugs me
42:33
all the time? Do you think it's
42:35
an institutional friction or there's some kind
42:38
of unmeasured risk that we're not seeing
42:40
or picking up or something else? I
42:42
mean it seems to be that the
42:45
banks are prevented from undoing it that
42:47
we have some of these regulations for
42:49
example that just restrict the size of
42:52
your balance sheet and the banks used
42:54
to just be able to freely borrow
42:56
and lend and undo things to borrow
42:58
in one currency land in the other
43:01
currency. That's how you'd undo it. But
43:03
there's just been a range of puzzles
43:05
like that. And of course, the biggest
43:08
puzzle is productivity. Like, if
43:10
I go to a country like the UK, how
43:12
do we get productivity? And exchange rates are
43:14
still a puzzle. I mean, you
43:17
asked a question about it before, but we
43:19
don't have a good, you know, fully
43:21
satisfactory explanation of them. You'll
43:24
be doing a book tour in the
43:26
UK soon. Why is their growth, their
43:28
productivity growth been so slow? Again,
43:31
we might admit this is a puzzle,
43:33
but it surprised me. They have plenty
43:35
of science. They have some great universities.
43:37
They played a key role in developing
43:39
vaccines, other innovations, and
43:42
they seem entirely stuck. Well,
43:45
I mean, it's been a generalized problem
43:48
in Europe, although you think they'd been
43:50
doing better. I think
43:52
part of it is this sucking sound
43:54
of the United States with the brain
43:56
drain that we have. You
43:58
and I both know about DeepMind. British
44:01
company, you know, ends
44:03
up in California. And
44:06
I think there are many examples like that
44:08
where when something goes well, the
44:10
US sucks them off. Probably
44:13
they have this profound problem of
44:15
the North and the South. The
44:17
South is rich and the North
44:19
is poor. And they just
44:21
have not been able to figure that
44:24
out. So that, you know, if you
44:26
go to London, they're doing great. And
44:28
they're still doing great. But they've had
44:30
trouble finding jobs that the manufacturing jobs
44:32
are going, they haven't figured
44:34
out how to substitute for them. The US
44:37
has had the tech revolution. I mean, if
44:39
you took that away, we don't
44:41
look so good anymore. A
44:43
lot of countries don't seem to
44:45
have a sucking sound problem, though.
44:47
So the talented people in northern
44:50
UK go to southern UK. But
44:52
you look at Germany, the Netherlands, you don't
44:54
see the same thing happening in those places.
44:57
Is it because London is so good that
44:59
the country as a whole grows more slowly?
45:01
Is that a kind of curse for the
45:03
aggregate number? You
45:06
know, it's still the case
45:08
that those countries have
45:11
hardly been models of dynamism,
45:13
Germany and the Netherlands. You're
45:16
right. They've been able to keep people
45:18
more partly because they're not English speaking.
45:21
But again, a lot of the difference in
45:23
how we've done is our tech sector. That's
45:26
been a lot of the innovation going through
45:28
the economy. And I don't want to sound
45:30
like I'm drunk with what's going on with
45:32
our tech sector and how it affects other
45:35
things. But if you took that away, our
45:37
numbers would look like theirs. Is
45:40
Malay going to make it succeed in
45:42
Argentina? What does it depend upon? Well,
45:45
I hope so. I think he's the
45:47
best chance that Argentina has had in
45:50
a long time, which is fair to
45:52
say a very low bar. The
45:55
thing that he's done that I
45:57
have not seen before is balancing
45:59
the budget. If you're a
46:01
big borrower and you keep defaulting, sort of
46:03
a starting point. is figuring out how not
46:06
to have to borrow money. He's
46:08
managed to do that. I mean,
46:10
I don't know that all his
46:12
libertarian visions necessarily will come to
46:14
pass. You know, he's provided
46:16
some stability for the inflation number. Argentina,
46:21
as you know, was one of the
46:23
richest countries in the world by any
46:25
measure at the turn of the 20th
46:27
century in 1900. Now, they're
46:29
lower middle income country. They're per
46:32
capita incomes below Brazil, which is
46:34
hard to get your head wrapped
46:36
around. So, I
46:38
mean, I think there are many
46:41
reasons, but certainly, you know, perinism,
46:43
socialism has not done well by
46:45
Argentina. But has he balanced
46:47
the budget? I know he announced a
46:49
balanced budget, but this is April 2025
46:51
and they just borrowed $20 million from
46:54
the IMF. It doesn't sound like a
46:56
very balanced budget. Well, I
46:58
mean, it's counting the interest payments on
47:00
the IMF. And yeah, I mean, he
47:03
inherited this big debt. They're paying the
47:05
interest. It's very low interest on the
47:08
big debt. And I don't know how
47:10
that's ultimately going to get resolved. I
47:12
mean, they have a lot of problems
47:15
ahead. You know, there's a
47:17
lot of strength in Argentina if they can
47:19
grow again. I don't want to sound, you
47:21
know, panglossian about
47:23
Argentina. But goodness,
47:25
they had inflation of 200 %
47:27
when he took over. The economy
47:29
was in free fall. So
47:32
look, you know, there's no
47:34
magic wand you can wave
47:36
over the last 80, 90
47:38
years of Argentina and make
47:41
everything right. Okay,
47:43
some chess questions. Once a grandmaster,
47:45
always a grandmaster, so you can't
47:47
just say you don't know. Do
47:49
cash the next dominant chess player?
47:52
Or will he be first to monkey equals? Well,
47:54
he's not even nearly first, now,
47:57
even among... know, others. I mean,
47:59
there's a number of Indian players
48:01
who are very good. I wouldn't
48:03
put him ahead of Nakamura or
48:06
Karawana much less Carlson, but he's
48:08
ambitious. He's talented. I
48:10
wish him the best. I mean, it's
48:12
wonderful that he won, but I mean,
48:14
he's got a long ways to go
48:16
to be Casperot, Fisher, Carlson. It'd be
48:18
fabulous for Chas if he does that.
48:21
I don't see it yet. Do you? Well,
48:24
Nakamura. Karawana in five years
48:26
they'll be out of the scene, maybe
48:28
before then. Carlson is already in a
48:30
sense out of the scene. I
48:33
think he has a 30 or 40
48:35
% chance of being not a truly
48:37
dominant player, but say the way Anand
48:39
or Kramnik were at their peak. You
48:42
know, one of the top two or three
48:44
very consistently and world champion for some number
48:46
of cycles. Not the way Kasparov
48:48
was, but something quite impressive. I'm close to it.
48:50
Well, it may be fantastic. Yeah, yeah. Okay, I
48:53
thought you were asking a different question. No, the
48:55
next, not the current dominant, but is he the
48:57
player? No, he could
48:59
absolutely, I mean, Anand and Kramnick were
49:01
amazing, and he could absolutely do that.
49:04
I mean, he's close to having done
49:06
it. If he met, he'll have a
49:08
much more difficult challenger next time, I
49:10
would suspect. I mean, Ding
49:13
is an uber talent, the person he
49:15
beat. but clearly had all
49:17
sorts of mental problems in the match.
49:19
I mean, he's been depressed and you
49:21
could see him sort of losing it
49:23
in some games. What
49:25
were your impressions of Bobby Fisher when you
49:27
met him? Well,
49:30
I mean, he was amazing. First
49:33
of all, when I met him,
49:35
he came every day to the
49:38
1969 US Junior Championship over 10
49:40
days. And he sat and he
49:42
analyzed with us. And the first thing was just
49:44
that. What's he doing with us? Why is he
49:46
wasting his time with us? We just thought he
49:48
was so generous. But obviously,
49:51
his absolute intensity, his
49:54
commitment, I don't know if you
49:56
remember, it's hard to imagine.
49:58
But he actually used to be weak
50:00
at rock endings, weak for somebody like
50:02
that. So he locked himself
50:05
in a room for three months and
50:07
did nothing. but study rock endings and
50:09
got to be very good. He got
50:11
a hotel, he told us about it,
50:14
got a hotel room, you know, with
50:16
no, no view. And then, you know,
50:18
certainly some of the ideas he showed,
50:21
I still think about it. I won
50:23
a game and he went over it
50:25
with me against Steve Spencer. It was
50:27
the last game of the tournament, which
50:30
I won. And he showed me his
50:32
ideas as like I Hadn't
50:34
thought of any of them, you know, it
50:36
was just the his fertile I don't know
50:39
if they were better to be completely honest
50:41
Then what I played I mean, of course,
50:43
he's much better than me But I mean
50:45
just the imagination of there was this then
50:47
we're talking about on move for on move
50:49
five of just things that wouldn't occur to
50:51
me And part of the Fisher legend was
50:54
that at least supposedly he was the greatest
50:56
over -the -board analyst of any chess player
50:59
Well, Gary Kasparov was so fool
51:01
and same as Carlson, I mean,
51:04
I don't know. But he
51:06
was way above everybody in his generation.
51:08
He did not have the prep that
51:10
the Russians had. He worked on his
51:13
own. he was not working with a
51:15
team. The Russians had all this communication
51:17
and coaches and everything. And by the
51:20
way, you know, I was representing the
51:22
U .S. and the World Junior Championships
51:24
and things like that. Everybody was a
51:27
big disadvantage that you didn't have a
51:29
trainer or a coach, you know, organizing
51:31
information. Fisher was doing that
51:33
at the highest level. So he must have
51:35
been by far the best over the board
51:38
player then. But not the
51:40
player. I mean, does someone, if you would
51:42
sit down with them at the board and
51:44
show them your game, The claim I've heard
51:46
is that Fisher was a more astute analyst,
51:48
even than Kasparov. Kasparov might have been the
51:51
better player, but just willing
51:53
to put his entire mental energy into
51:55
over -the -board analysis, sitting there. I
51:57
think that's part of the Fisher legend.
52:00
I mean, it's part of the legend.
52:02
I mean, he was amazing. I played
52:05
against really all the top players then,
52:07
with the exception of Spassky. And,
52:09
you know, they were all phenomenal,
52:11
but they weren't all equally good
52:13
calculators. So the best
52:15
calculator I ever played was actually
52:18
a Yugoslav player reached second or
52:20
third named Lubejevic. And he
52:22
beat me. I don't know. I was 16 years
52:24
old. And to try to
52:26
salvage some ego, I said, well, what
52:28
did you, what if I did this?
52:30
What were you going to do? And
52:32
I showed him my best. I thought
52:34
it was just like a great variation.
52:36
I don't remember how long, 10 moves.
52:39
And he goes, mm -hmm, mm -hmm. Yeah,
52:41
but then I do this. Actually,
52:43
it's this. And he goes, something 15
52:45
moves. I never played Fisher. He wrote
52:47
an article about me once, as you
52:49
know, but I never played him.
52:51
But of course, I could well imagine it
52:54
would be the same. But I'm not sure
52:56
I could tell the difference with Kasparov, Carlson,
52:58
you know, at that level. When
53:00
Magnus spoke with Lex Friedman, he
53:03
drew a distinction between players who
53:05
were incredible calculators. He called Goukache
53:07
one of those, and players who
53:09
were incredible with evaluation. And
53:11
he called himself one of those. He thinks
53:13
he's actually not the best calculator. Do
53:16
you broadly agree with that distinction? Well,
53:19
I think it's an interesting question. It's
53:21
funny, because I've seen him write about
53:23
Karpov, who I did play, and he
53:25
said, I don't know how Karpov does
53:28
it. He just knows where to put
53:30
the pieces. He just knows where everything
53:32
goes. And he's not having to calculate
53:34
like I do. And between his great
53:36
nemesis was Karpov. And between the two
53:38
of them, he was the calculator and
53:40
Karpov was no slouch, but Kasparov was
53:43
better. I think maybe as
53:45
Gary gets older, you know,
53:47
I mean, your comparative advantage as a
53:49
calculator is probably at your peak at
53:51
a younger age. And Gary, you know,
53:53
developed other tools. But I'm
53:55
going to He was really good at
53:57
both. I so I But I would
54:00
have put Casper up as a calculator
54:02
like a fierce calculator Now you must
54:04
have been out of practice, but I
54:06
believe you drew Magnus in a game
54:08
of speed chess in 2012. Is that
54:10
the correct year? Yeah, it
54:12
really it really happened. How did it happen?
54:14
What's what's the story? Well
54:17
sort of what I tell people
54:19
is if you were a professional
54:21
golfer once and you play three
54:23
holes with somebody anything can
54:26
happen, you know, the law of large numbers.
54:29
But, you know, going more into it,
54:31
he led me up white. We played
54:33
a Ruy Lopez Spanish opening, which he
54:35
had been playing all the time. He
54:37
played a variation. I looked, I hadn't
54:39
prepared. I mean, it's just what he
54:42
was playing all Did he play the Briar like he used
54:44
to do? He played the Briar. No, that's right. He played
54:46
the Briar. And I didn't. I didn't
54:48
even know that he played it at the time. I
54:50
mean, he played a lot of things. I didn't know
54:52
he was playing that. And so I
54:54
knew where the pieces go. I knew what I
54:56
was trying to do and where the pieces go.
54:59
And at one point, he
55:01
made an overly aggressive move
55:03
that just was a big
55:06
mistake. And I saw it.
55:08
And I got a winning advantage.
55:11
It wasn't an easy winning advantage.
55:13
I'm convinced that if he had continued the
55:16
game, he would have won. But at some
55:18
point he had a choice of repeating moves
55:20
and he was losing. And
55:22
so, you know, he just repeated moves. I'm
55:24
not saying I would have won. I think
55:26
I would have lost if he kept playing,
55:28
but it just happened. I did it 10
55:30
,000, 20 ,000 times more. I don't think
55:33
it would happen. What do
55:35
you think of Fisher Random as the future
55:37
of chess? Because that seems to be what
55:39
Magnus wants. I don't like it, frankly, but
55:41
what's your opinion? I'm with you, Tyler. I
55:44
mean... mean, I take joy
55:46
from classical chess. I love
55:48
watching a beautiful classical chess
55:50
game. I can relate to
55:52
it. I mean, I'm hardwired
55:54
to think about it. And
55:56
fish or random chess, I mean, it's
55:58
a little bit like looking at problems.
56:00
I respect chess problems, but the positions
56:03
are often weird and improbable. I
56:05
just have trouble relating to fish
56:07
or random chess. I hope I
56:09
change. I'm just speaking from my
56:11
age, but I'm so invested. in
56:13
classical chess. I love classical
56:16
chess. I think about classical chess
56:18
all the time. I
56:20
don't know, why don't you like
56:22
it? With classical chess,
56:25
not every game, but most games, I feel I
56:27
can look at the board and have a decent
56:29
idea what's going on. And I might be wrong,
56:31
but even then, I can figure out exposed why
56:33
I was wrong. With Fisher Random,
56:36
I don't have that sense unless it
56:38
evolves back into a classical looking like
56:40
position. So from a spectator's point of
56:42
view, why should I care? That's how I would
56:44
put it. Yeah. I
56:47
mean, we're on the same page
56:49
on that. But on the other
56:51
hand, you mentioned Gukesh and the
56:53
computers have just dominated the preparation.
56:55
That's why Carlson stopped. He's
56:57
in West Fendall. Yeah. How are we going to solve that
56:59
problem then? If we don't do Fisher random, what
57:02
is your proposed solution? Because I have one. I'll tell
57:04
you mine, but you tell me yours. Tell
57:06
me yours. That we randomize the
57:08
first few moves of the opening.
57:11
So some percentage of games, through
57:13
computer randomization, would be like 1B4,
57:15
1B6, and then they start playing.
57:18
But you do that with many
57:20
permutations. They're all playable positions. As
57:22
you well know, no Grandmaster game
57:24
would go 1B4, 1B6. But
57:26
there's no reason why you can't play from
57:28
that position. And if you have 500 opening
57:31
alternatives like that that the players don't control,
57:33
I just don't think they can prep that much.
57:35
The Berlin, the Marshall, the whatever, all these force
57:38
draws, I think they actually have to play chess.
57:41
I love that idea. And yeah, it
57:43
creates some randomness in what initial positions
57:45
you get. But I love that idea.
57:47
I mean, that sounds much better to
57:49
me. I would much. I have to say
57:51
as a player, I played like
57:54
that because I was very isolated in
57:56
the United States. I wasn't following all
57:58
the opening innovations. So I
58:00
played all kinds of openings to be unpredictable.
58:04
But if everyone does it, it's easier to do.
58:06
It's like every game is between two Ken Reagan's
58:08
is one way to put it. Yeah,
58:11
no, no. I like your idea. I
58:13
think it's a great idea. I endorse
58:16
it. Thank you. Final question for you,
58:18
for our listeners. Your book's
58:20
coming out. It's on very important
58:22
issues of currencies, international trade, international
58:25
finance. It draws upon
58:27
a lifetime of your learning and
58:29
practice and advising. What is
58:31
it you think you'll do next? Well,
58:34
I have a lot, you know, like any academic, I
58:36
already have my next. Few years
58:38
of projects some of them right frankly,
58:40
you know grow out of the book.
58:42
I think people forgotten about political economy
58:45
They just think you know if the
58:47
central bank says the inflation rates 2
58:49
% on average It'll be 2 %
58:51
and we go home and I worked
58:53
on that early in my life I
58:55
wrote the first paper on why you
58:57
should have an independent central bank And
59:00
I'm working on it again, admittedly
59:02
with some very talented young
59:04
people, including Marina Halleck at
59:06
Yale and Pierre Yarra, who's at
59:09
Columbia, but now actually on the
59:11
Council of Economic Advisers, and just
59:14
thinking that. No, the political
59:16
pressures are important. So that's an
59:18
important topic. I'm also working
59:20
on China as an area I've been
59:22
working on for a long time. So
59:24
I have some thoughts about comparing China
59:27
and Japan, for example. But
59:29
I have a lot of things I'm excited about. The
59:31
part of what was so great about
59:33
the book is I had sort of,
59:36
I would describe a mini renaissance in
59:38
my research and I'm able, at
59:40
least I feel that way. I mean,
59:42
the rest of the world thinks that,
59:45
but it It gives me joy to
59:47
have some confidence about some of the
59:49
ideas, although as you say, there's much
59:51
more to it. Again, everyone,
59:53
Ken's new and excellent book is Our
59:56
Dollar, Your Problem. Ken Rogoff, thank you
59:58
very much. Thank
1:00:00
you. Thanks
1:00:05
for listening to Conversations with Tyler.
1:00:07
You can subscribe to the show on
1:00:10
Apple Podcasts, Spotify, or your
1:00:12
favorite podcast app. If you like this
1:00:14
podcast, please consider giving us a
1:00:16
rating and leaving a review. This
1:00:18
helps other listeners find the show.
1:00:20
On Twitter, I'm at Tyler Cowan,
1:00:22
and the show is at Cowan
1:00:25
Convos. Until next time, please
1:00:27
keep listening and learning. you.
Podchaser is the ultimate destination for podcast data, search, and discovery. Learn More