Episode Transcript
Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.
Use Ctrl + F to search
0:00
Cologent isn't just for people who want nice
0:02
hair, skin, and nails. It's also
0:04
for people who want nice joints, and needs,
0:07
and bones, and limbs, and
0:09
wrists, and arms, and index fingers,
0:12
and shoulders, and tipulas, and
0:15
ears, and hands, and fingertips.
0:18
Toes and hips and power vital
0:20
proteins for everybody with a body.
0:23
These statements have not been evaluated by the Food and
0:25
Drug Administration. This product is not intended
0:27
to diagnose, treat cure or prevent any disease.
0:31
As if the Macrispy couldn't get any better,
0:34
bacon and ranch just entered
0:36
the chat. The bacon ranch
0:39
with crispy, available and participate
0:41
in McDonald's for a limited time.
0:51
Hey there, it's Steven Dubner. Do you
0:53
ever wonder how your boss became
0:55
a boss in the first place? Yeah.
0:58
We do too, especially when
1:00
things go sideways. In retrospect,
1:03
it's easy to say that Sam Bankman Freed
1:05
was not the best person to be
1:07
running FTX, the bankrupt
1:09
cryptocurrency exchange. But retrospect,
1:12
is always easy. What about right
1:14
now? Do you have
1:17
a bad boss? Have you ever had one?
1:19
Chances are Yes. So
1:22
I hope you enjoy today's episode, which
1:24
we first published last year.
1:26
It's called why are there so many
1:29
bad bosses? My
1:36
name is Katie Johnson, and I'm
1:38
a data scientist. Johnson
1:40
is thirty two years old and lives in London.
1:42
She grew up near Bristol, went to university
1:45
in Birmingham, and since then has held
1:47
series of increasingly impressive jobs
1:49
at a series of companies. These were
1:51
all what are known as I c jobs,
1:54
I c standing for individual
1:55
contributor. Which means what?
1:58
It is someone who makes
2:00
as opposed to managing people who
2:03
make Johnson loved
2:05
being an IC. She loved analyzing
2:07
data, and she was really good
2:09
at her job. But after a while,
2:12
she thought it might be nice to come
2:14
a boss. Yeah. I wanted to manage
2:16
more and more people. And you wanted to
2:18
manage more people because why? You were
2:21
just power hungry like the rest of us?
2:23
I think there's a couple of reasons. So the
2:25
first is that I wanted to start
2:27
getting more autonomy over what I was
2:29
working on. I would be working on staff
2:32
in my IC role and I think this isn't the most
2:34
important thing. And I thought that if
2:36
I became the leader of the
2:37
team, then I would get to pick. What
2:39
I worked on.
2:40
Okay. That seems sensible.
2:42
The other reason was to have
2:44
more impact at the companies I was working
2:47
at, so you could describe this as having a
2:49
seat at the table. Also sensible.
2:52
I guess the final reason is that we
2:54
all kind of, not everyone, I guess, but
2:56
I was included in this, have a concept that
2:58
being more successful means being more senior.
3:01
And so in order to not
3:03
necessarily show others, but definitely myself
3:06
that I had achieved and become successful,
3:08
I needed to keep moving upwards within
3:10
a
3:10
company. Johnson's father
3:12
in his own career had seen things differently.
3:15
So my dad has been a network
3:17
engineer. He recently retired, but he's been that
3:19
for his whole career, and he had absolutely no
3:21
aspiration to become the
3:23
manager. He's like, why would I want to do that?
3:24
But Katie Johnson did want
3:27
to become a manager and several
3:29
firms were willing make her one. She
3:31
took the most appealing offer at
3:34
a software firm that helps companies acquire
3:36
new customers.
3:38
And I was sent on some management training
3:40
and had to do what can only be described
3:42
as a very long personality
3:44
test. And the idea was to tell
3:46
me what I was good at being good at.
3:49
And what was she particularly good at?
3:51
Critical thinking, attention
3:53
to detail, courage, all these
3:55
internal thinking type characteristics.
3:58
You can see why Katie Johnson would seem to
4:00
be a great boss. Her
4:02
new job title was head of data
4:04
and analytics. She had roughly ten
4:06
people reporting to her. The
4:09
promotion came with more money, more
4:11
prestige, more leverage to set
4:13
the agenda. Also however,
4:15
more meetings,
4:17
Oh, so many meetings,
4:19
like compared to being a data scientist, I'd
4:21
maybe have a half hour meeting in the morning
4:23
and then I'd just be free. To do
4:25
coding and thinking and making
4:28
stuff. But I was in
4:29
meetings. I think Tuesdays, I
4:31
used
4:32
to be in meetings for, like, seven hours
4:34
No offense, but did you not see that coming?
4:37
No. I really didn't. I thought
4:39
it would just be like my normal data scientist
4:41
job of a few one to ones on the side.
4:44
That was okay because it's quite interesting. You're talking
4:46
about the work you get into quite depth and problems
4:48
with my team. It's more like the meetings
4:50
like an hours coffee someone to try
4:52
and set up a better working relationship with their
4:55
team times that by like five or
4:57
ten other teams. It's just draining.
5:02
Keep in mind, this was happening during the pandemic
5:05
shutdown, so all these meetings
5:07
were virtual. And as drained
5:09
as Johnson was from all those
5:11
meetings, she was getting good reviews as
5:13
manager.
5:14
Yes. People would tell me what a great job I was
5:16
doing. I was coming across well.
5:19
But she found that being a boss
5:22
made her miserable. I
5:24
would finish my day in my study walking
5:26
to the lip room, put a blanket over
5:28
my head and cry because I was
5:31
in so much pain
5:33
at high board I was. In
5:35
retrospect, Katie Johnson had
5:37
plainly aired in wanting to become
5:39
a boss. But she'd also felt that
5:41
management was the only sensible way to
5:43
advance her career and If
5:46
you look at how most firms and institutions around
5:48
the world operate, you'd have to agree with
5:50
her. The question is, does
5:53
this standard operating procedure produce
5:55
good bosses or bad bosses or
5:57
even horrible ones. The horrible
6:00
boss is a familiar caricature. We
6:02
all know the stereotypes, the screamer,
6:05
the sadist, the idea stealer,
6:07
the passive aggressiveness, These
6:10
are some of our most enduring characters
6:12
in film. You remember Blake
6:14
from Glen Gary Glen Ross played by
6:16
Alec
6:17
Baldwin? Put that coffee
6:19
down. Coffee's
6:21
for clothes is only.
6:24
Do call yourself a salesman who's son of a
6:27
Or in the film office space when Peter
6:29
is trying to escape the office on Friday
6:32
afternoon and he gets snagged by the
6:34
boss. Hello, Peter.
6:36
What's happening? I'm
6:40
gonna need you to go ahead and come
6:42
in tomorrow. So
6:44
if you could be here around
6:48
nine would be great. Okay.
6:51
Oh, oh, and I almost forgot. I'm
6:55
also gonna need you to go ahead and come in
6:58
on Sunday too. Then
7:00
there's Miranda Priestley played by
7:02
Meryl Streep in the devil wears
7:04
Prada.
7:05
You have no style or sense of
7:07
fashion?
7:09
Well, I
7:12
think that depends on what's your No. No.
7:15
That was a new question. The horrible
7:17
boss Motif is so attractive that
7:19
the director Seth Gordon made a film
7:22
called horrible
7:23
bosses.
7:24
Yeah. We gotta trim some of the fat around here.
7:25
Trimmer. What do you mean by trim the fat?
7:28
I want you to fire the fat people. Truly
7:33
horror irrible bosses do occasionally turn
7:35
up in real life, especially in Hollywood
7:37
itself. The producer Scott Ruedin,
7:39
for instance, has been accused of years
7:42
worth of alleged abuses, like
7:44
smashing an assistant's hand with
7:46
a computer monitor. But
7:48
even in Hollywood these days, and especially
7:51
in more normal industries. This sort
7:53
of grotesquery is harder to get
7:55
away with. Bosses who are
7:57
outright monsters are more likely
8:00
to lose their jobs. But how much
8:02
attention are we paying to the more common
8:04
type a bad boss. Someone who's simply
8:07
incompetent or overstretched
8:09
or even just miserable being a
8:12
boss like Katie Johnson was.
8:14
Do you even know how many bad bosses
8:16
are out there? The more
8:18
you dig, the more you learn, the the
8:20
science of boss behavior is not very
8:22
scientific. One Gallip poll
8:24
shows that roughly fifty percent of American
8:26
employees have, at some point in their career,
8:29
left a job because of
8:31
a bad boss. But an employee
8:33
might have ten or twenty bosses
8:35
over a career, so Maybe that
8:37
number isn't so bad. A survey
8:40
of European employees found that
8:42
only thirteen percent rated their
8:44
current boss as bad.
8:47
So maybe the Hollywood caricature is
8:49
way off. Still considering
8:52
that nearly all of us will at some point
8:54
in our lives have a boss or b
8:56
one. We thought there might
8:58
be some boss questions worth asking.
9:00
And so today on Freakonomics
9:02
Radio, when a boss is
9:04
a bad boss, Have you ever wondered
9:06
why? There's no reason to
9:08
believe that a great salesperson who'll be
9:10
a great
9:11
manager. And yet, this kind of promotion
9:13
happens all the time. Why is
9:15
that?
9:16
So there are two ways to motivate people. We can
9:18
pay them a whole lot more or we can
9:20
give them an opportunity for
9:21
promotion. Today on the show
9:24
why good employees become
9:26
bad bosses and whether
9:28
that will ever change. Spoiler
9:30
alert, probably not.
9:46
This is Freakonomics radio. The
9:48
pod cast that explores the hidden side
9:50
of everything with your host,
9:53
Steven Dubner.
10:04
One of the reasons I became a writer
10:06
years ago is because I didn't
10:08
particularly like having a boss.
10:11
Like Katie Johnson, I prefer
10:13
to set my own agenda, my own pace,
10:15
I also really like working alone,
10:18
also like Katie Johnson, I am
10:20
not particularly fond of meetings, so I
10:22
wouldn't be a very good boss either. Fortunately,
10:25
at Freakonomics Radio, There are
10:28
a couple other people who do all the bossy
10:30
stuff, leaving me pretty much free
10:32
to do this. What
10:35
we're doing right now, asking questions
10:37
trying to find answers. So here's
10:39
a question I've always been curious about. How
10:42
important are bosses anyway? I
10:44
don't mean CEOs, the ultimate
10:46
boss. If you're interested in that, we once
10:48
did a series called The Secret Life
10:51
of CEOs. Today,
10:53
we are just talking about your standard issue
10:55
middle manager. Do they really
10:57
matter? Yes.
11:01
Broadly speaking, managers matter.
11:04
Bosses matter for outcomes. That
11:06
is Steve Tedellis. He is an professor
11:09
at UC Berkeley's Hass school
11:11
of business, a training ground for
11:13
future bosses. Management
11:15
is not something that Tadellus himself
11:18
aspires to. Telling me how close
11:20
you are to administration so I know how far
11:22
away to be from you. But he has
11:24
spent time while on Sabbatical working
11:27
as a boss at some well known firms.
11:30
When I was at eBay and
11:32
Amazon, I managed Teams and I enjoyed
11:34
it very
11:34
much. How do you assess yourself
11:37
as a manager in that realm. I'm blushing.
11:39
So Because
11:42
you're the best ever? No.
11:44
But I'm pretty good, so I'm feeling a little
11:46
uncomfortable. Your positive self assessment
11:49
is based on direct feedback
11:51
or just a general warm glow
11:54
feeling. At eBay and Amazon, the
11:56
feedback was actually formal food surveys.
11:59
Surveys, that
12:00
is, with questions like, on
12:02
a scale of one to five, how much do you
12:04
agree with the following statement? My
12:06
boss generates a positive attitude
12:08
in the team. Or my
12:10
boss is someone I can trust, or
12:13
My boss provides continuous coaching
12:15
and guidance on how I can improve my
12:18
performance. These surveys
12:20
led Steve Tedellis to ask his own
12:22
bigger questions about
12:23
bosses. For instance, does
12:25
it really matter? Do these measures of
12:28
manager skills or characteristics
12:31
do they really have any value for the firm?
12:34
Is there some way in which managers
12:36
who score higher on these surveys are
12:39
actually contributing more.
12:43
These are eternal questions in
12:45
the field known as personnel economics.
12:48
You could ask the same questions about any
12:50
manager, the head coach of a football
12:52
team, the chairperson of
12:54
your homeowner's association, the
12:56
president of the United States. But
12:59
as I mentioned earlier, the academic literature
13:01
on the impact of bosses is not
13:03
particularly advanced. can
13:06
see why if you think about it There
13:08
are so many variables in the relationship
13:10
between a boss and their employees that it can
13:12
be hard to pinpoint the effects of
13:14
the
13:15
boss. This is why most research
13:17
focuses on one single
13:19
quantifiable metric, productivity.
13:22
For example, there is a
13:24
paper by the late
13:27
wonderful economist Eddie Lasir, Katherine
13:30
Shaw, and Chris Stanton, where
13:32
they show that there is variation
13:35
in output
13:36
of employees based on the
13:38
managers that are in charge of them
13:41
That paper from twenty fifteen
13:43
analyzed data from a single firm
13:46
that the researchers were not allowed
13:48
to identify, but it appears to be something
13:50
a call center. The analysis
13:52
looked at what happened when a worker moved
13:54
from what the researchers identified as an
13:56
average boss to a high quality
13:59
boss. Such a move, they
14:01
found increased productivity by
14:03
as much as fifty percent. So
14:06
if this were a call center and
14:08
a given worker, handled a hundred
14:10
calls per shift under an average boss,
14:12
an excellent boss could boost that
14:15
to a hundred and fifty calls. So
14:17
at least in this type of setting,
14:19
a quote good boss is doing
14:22
something right, but the data couldn't say what.
14:25
Steve Tedellis wanted to learn
14:26
more, so he teamed up with Mitchell
14:28
Hoffman, an economist at the
14:30
University of Toronto's Rockman School
14:32
of Management, to write a research
14:34
paper. I have access
14:37
to interesting data and people
14:39
in this company that will
14:41
have to be unnamed because when it comes
14:44
to personnel data, companies are very
14:46
hesitant. Ted Ellis would only
14:48
say that this firm did high-tech
14:51
knowledge based work. Maybe
14:53
given his history, you might picture
14:55
a firm like an eBay or
14:58
an Amazon. In any case, he
15:00
is looking at a very different type
15:02
of work than the earlier research with
15:04
its narrow measure of
15:05
productivity. What we're doing
15:07
is opening the hood
15:09
up a little bit and what sort of data
15:11
did they have access
15:12
to? We have data that
15:14
allows us to measure the impact of a
15:16
particular manager skill
15:18
that we're calling people management skills
15:21
as opposed to just do managers
15:23
matter. People management skills,
15:25
meaning the sort of things you find on
15:27
those employee feedback surveys.
15:30
How well the manager coaches and communicates?
15:33
How trustworthy they are. So
15:35
that's the boss data on the
15:37
employee side. Ted Ellis and Hoffman
15:39
had a lot of concrete data. Subjective
15:42
performance scores, as well as how
15:44
often a given employee was promoted or given
15:46
a raise, the number of patents
15:49
they
15:49
filed, and whether they stayed
15:51
at the firm or left. In
15:53
these high-tech knowledge based companies,
15:56
retention is a very, very
15:59
important focus because
16:02
getting these high skilled workers is
16:04
not easy, and there's a lot of
16:06
competition. And when you
16:08
lose an employee, especially an
16:11
employee that's very valuable, then
16:13
it could take
16:15
months to replace them.
16:17
So Tedllis and Hoffman set about
16:19
to sort through all this data to look for any
16:21
causal relationships between the rating
16:24
of a given manager and the various
16:26
outcomes of the employees working
16:28
under
16:28
them. Would they find? For
16:31
the most part, it was a big bag of
16:33
nothing. We didn't find
16:35
that the ratings of
16:37
the managers seemed to impact
16:40
the subject performance of their employees,
16:42
their income, their promotions,
16:44
or patent applications in a
16:46
meaningful way. That's right. On all
16:48
those employee outcomes, performance,
16:52
earnings, patents, it
16:54
just didn't seem to matter whether
16:56
the manager was highly rated
16:58
were poorly rated. But there
17:00
was one other outcome to look
17:02
at employee
17:04
retention, bingo, To
17:06
Dallas and Hoffman look at employees at
17:08
this one firm who moved from a manager
17:11
with a poor rating to one with a high rating.
17:13
That's associated with an attrition drop
17:15
of about sixty percent That is
17:18
huge and within that huge
17:20
effect was an important
17:21
nuance. What we see then
17:24
is that managers
17:27
help retain better employees more
17:30
than worse employees, which shows that the
17:32
impact of being a better manager is
17:34
strongest where it matters the
17:36
most. So
17:38
a good boss seems capable of
17:40
keeping the best employees happy
17:43
and presumably productive. Conversely,
17:46
a bad boss might drive away
17:48
the best employees. The
17:50
Fidelis Hoffman paper was published
17:52
in twenty twenty one in the journal of
17:54
political economy, one of the best econ
17:57
journals. So okay.
17:59
The economics literature on bosses and management
18:01
just got a little bit deeper But
18:04
remember, employee retention was
18:06
the only outcome where it seemed to matter
18:08
whether a boss was good or
18:10
bad. And if you ask Steve
18:12
Tedellis a more fundamental question,
18:14
like, what does a good boss
18:16
actually do to instill this
18:19
loyalty. This is where
18:21
I have to take a step back and say
18:24
that there are certain things that may
18:26
be outside the scope of
18:27
what economists should be dealing
18:29
with?
18:30
If you were to make a list of things that
18:32
you would like to measure, were it possible given
18:34
the data? What would some of those things be? Really
18:36
good question. Something that's
18:39
very hard to measure
18:41
that I believe is
18:43
important is compassion.
18:46
I guess if this is gonna be on the radio or
18:48
might lose my Economist card. Steve
18:50
Didellis is not the only Economist who's
18:52
been frustrated by the lack of evidence
18:55
for what makes a good boss
18:57
good. Maybe compassion
18:59
is as important as he suspects,
19:01
but We just don't have any
19:04
large scale empirical evidence yet.
19:06
The Stanford Nicholas Blum,
19:09
has been studying leadership and management
19:11
for years. And yet,
19:14
no one could really give us a straight answer
19:16
on what to find a good or a bad leader you
19:18
look at the data and there's ten different recipes
19:20
for success. Maybe they each work for a particular
19:23
case study, but I've still twenty years
19:25
later struggled to find anything
19:27
that's the secret recipe beyond
19:29
saying, sure there are some people that are better than others,
19:31
but it's damn hard to tell what it is.
19:33
This has not stopped leadership gurus
19:36
from promoting their pet theories.
19:39
As Bloom puts it, there is a
19:41
ton of BS around this from
19:43
airport bookstore pulp fiction.
19:46
And here's another reason to question the
19:48
literature on management and bosses.
19:51
As we've been hearing, most of the
19:53
BOSS data comes from employee
19:56
surveys. Have you ever
19:58
taken a survey that rates your manager?
20:01
If so, were you told it was
20:04
anonymous? Did you
20:06
believe it was anonymous? Were
20:08
your answers objective? Or
20:12
did you maybe think, well, my
20:14
boss thinks I'm good at my job, so
20:16
I'm gonna say they're good at theirs. Or
20:18
vice versa, I don't think my boss
20:21
likes me, so I'm sure not gonna give them
20:23
a good rating. As we have
20:25
said before on this show, survey data
20:27
can be the lowest form
20:29
of
20:30
data. Here again is Steve
20:32
Tedellis. I'm sure you know
20:34
that he economists are very wary about
20:36
using surveys. And
20:38
economists believe in what we call a
20:40
revealed preference approach. Meaning
20:43
how you behave
20:44
is telling me a lot more about you than
20:47
what you say about yourself. Just
20:49
how big is the gap between what people
20:51
say and how they behave? Over
20:54
the years, I have heard many economists give
20:57
many examples of this gap
20:59
Steve Tedellis' example is my
21:01
all time favorite. There is a lot
21:03
of discussion about privacy and privacy
21:06
regulation these days.
21:07
And you hear a lot of people saying how
21:09
their privacy is important to them, and
21:12
then you turn them and say, here's the snickers
21:14
bar. Could I have your mother's maiden name? And they
21:16
say yes. So it's a little
21:18
bit confusing when you tell me that you
21:20
really care about privacy and then you just
21:23
scroll down on every app you
21:25
download and click yes, yes, yes,
21:27
that doesn't tell me that you really care
21:29
about privacy.
21:31
So the same is true for many other
21:34
types of behavior. So
21:37
let's keep in mind that much of what we have
21:39
been told in the past about good
21:41
bosses and bad bosses is not
21:43
exactly evidence based. Researchers
21:46
like Fidelis and Hoffman and
21:49
Bloom have been shipping away
21:51
at the black box of boss behavior, but
21:53
we've got a long way to go. This
21:56
means we need to keep looking for
21:58
good data and asking Good
22:00
questions. So coming up after the break,
22:02
who becomes a boss and why?
22:05
If so many people think the boss selection
22:07
process is stupid, Why
22:10
do firms keep doing it? And whatever
22:13
happened to Katie
22:14
Johnson.
22:15
I get to the end of the day and the lack thing I
22:17
wanna do is talk to someone else.
22:19
I'm Steven Dubner. This is Freakonomics
22:21
Radio, and remember, you can get our series
22:24
the Secret Life of CEOs and
22:26
all our past episodes on any podcast
22:29
app will be right back.
22:32
Freakonomics radio sponsored
22:35
by Staples. Did you know that with
22:37
Staples' business advantage, you've got access
22:39
to a team two thousand real life
22:41
purchasing experts to help your business
22:44
run better and your dollar go
22:46
further. They take data to
22:48
the next level and add human insight to
22:50
create custom solutions for you that
22:52
data alone could never provide. They
22:54
do the leg work for you, curating a
22:56
selection of products so you can be sure
22:58
you are getting just what your business needs.
23:00
That is the Staples Business Advantage
23:03
sign up at staplesbusinessadvantage dot
23:06
com Freakonomics
23:11
radio sponsored by Satya. This is
23:13
story of one company whose products fly
23:15
in the face of everything we've learned as consumers.
23:18
The company is Satva, and the luxury
23:20
mattresses they make are unique. Unique
23:22
in that they are so luxury various, so
23:24
plush, so comfortable, you'd think they'd
23:26
cost a small fortune. But in reality,
23:29
they cost half the price of the top retail
23:31
brands. But that's not possible.
23:33
Our consumer experience tells us.
23:35
Right? Wrong. SatBA has been
23:37
in the mattress business for a long time.
23:40
They will also set it up for you and take your old
23:42
mattress no extra charge, all of
23:44
which proves that luxury and affordability can
23:47
peacefully coexist, you just have
23:49
to know where to look. Right now,
23:51
save two hundred dollars on a thousand dollars
23:54
or more at sottva dot com
23:56
slash freakonomics. That's s
23:58
double ATBA dot
24:00
com slash freakonomix. Have
24:10
you ever thought about where a boss
24:12
comes from? What I mean is,
24:14
why a given employee will
24:17
rise from the ranks to become
24:19
a
24:19
manager? Here's someone
24:21
who's been thinking about that a lot.
24:23
My name is Kelly Xu. I'm a professor
24:26
of finance at the Yale School of Management.
24:29
Kelly Xu, along with Allen Benson
24:31
and Danielle Lee, published a paper
24:33
in the Quarterly Journal of
24:35
Economics, another top journal
24:37
called Promotions and the
24:39
Peter Principle. So the
24:41
Peter Principle is a very funny
24:44
and popular management book written
24:46
by Lawrence j, Peter, and his
24:48
book offers an explanation for why
24:50
we might see incompetent bosses
24:52
everywhere.
24:53
Incompetent bosses everywhere. Okay.
24:56
I'm listening. What is this
24:59
explanation? Let's go back to
25:01
Lawrence j Peter himself. This
25:03
is from a nineteen seventy three documentary.
25:07
The Peter principal states very simply that
25:09
in any hierarchy, an employee
25:12
tends to rise to his level of
25:14
incompetence. I'm
25:17
sorry. As many times as I've heard that, phrase,
25:20
I still laugh at it just because it
25:22
sounds like it's gonna be not irreverent
25:25
and then it turns immediately irreverent which
25:27
makes me
25:27
chuckle. Well, except I think it's a funny
25:30
idea, but it also rings true
25:32
and it's funny in a kind of unpleasant
25:34
way because it reminds people how much
25:36
they dislike their bosses.
25:38
Peter was a Canadian education scholar.
25:41
He used his daily observations
25:43
to form a theory about job
25:45
promotions. I saw that very often
25:47
a competent individual was
25:50
promoted to something he
25:52
couldn't do. I saw
25:54
a competent mechanic where
25:56
he stayed in my car. He
25:58
was terrific. He
26:01
was very responsible, very precise,
26:03
knew exactly what he was doing. So they made
26:05
an informant. Now he's no longer
26:07
fixing
26:07
cars, and he's trying to manage other mechanics,
26:11
and he's very incompetent. The
26:13
more Peter looked around. The more
26:15
he saw people who were good at
26:17
their jobs routinely stumbling into
26:20
bigger jobs they weren't good
26:21
at. In any organization where
26:25
competence is essentially
26:27
eligibility for
26:29
promotion, and incompetence is
26:31
a bar to promotion. People
26:33
who arise to the level of incompetence intend
26:36
to stay there. The book he wrote
26:38
with Raymond Hall was called
26:40
the Peter Principle, why things
26:43
always go wrong. It wound up
26:45
selling millions of copies. The
26:47
book was meant to saturize corporate
26:49
strategy. Nevertheless, a
26:52
variety of big firms tried to recruit
26:54
Peter to become their management
26:56
guru. He declined saying
26:58
that he didn't wish to rise
27:00
to his own level of
27:02
incompetence. Kelly Shoe again.
27:04
His idea is that
27:06
firms and organizations tend to promote
27:08
people based upon their performance so
27:10
far. What that means is a worker
27:12
who is good at her job will be quickly promoted
27:15
to a new job role, which might require
27:17
different set of skills. If she's
27:19
good at that new role, she's gonna be promoted
27:21
again, until she reaches a position
27:23
where she's actually a bad match for that
27:26
new job role. And then she will no longer
27:28
be promoted. On the one hand, it
27:30
would seem to make perfect sense that you promote
27:32
someone who's good at their
27:33
job. You don't want to promote the bad workers.
27:36
On the other hand, managing is
27:38
not the same as
27:39
doing. There's no reason to
27:41
believe that a great salesperson who knows
27:43
how to negotiate deals will be a great manager.
27:46
That again is the Berkeley economist Steve
27:48
Tedellis. I look here in my
27:50
company, Berkeley great researchers often make
27:53
for lousy department chairs. Great engineers
27:55
often
27:55
make for lousy engineering managers. But
27:59
here's the thing about the Peter principle. Even
28:01
though the theory had been around, for
28:03
half a century. No one had ever
28:06
checked with real data from
28:08
real companies whether Lawrence
28:10
Peter was right. A
28:12
few observations about car
28:15
mechanic or an academic researcher
28:17
turned department chair, those
28:19
do not constitute empirical proof,
28:22
especially in the realm of management
28:24
in all that airport bookstore pulp
28:27
fiction. This is where Kelly Shoe
28:29
and her coauthors come in. They wanted
28:31
to see if the Peter Principle actually
28:34
exists. And if so, what
28:36
should be done about it? First
28:38
step, get hold of some
28:40
data.
28:41
We got our data from a company
28:43
that offers sales performance management
28:46
software and services
28:48
Shoe can't tell us the name of the company,
28:50
but pictures something like Salesforce.
28:52
A typical client of our data provider
28:55
is a firm that employs business
28:57
to business sales workers. And
29:00
that client firm would input the
29:02
sales numbers and the whole organizational structure
29:05
into a software program,
29:07
and what we're doing is we're studying the data
29:10
that these client firms uploaded into
29:12
the software
29:12
program. How
29:13
many firms and how many workers? We
29:15
see data for about forty
29:18
thousand business to business sales workers
29:20
at over a hundred and thirty different US
29:22
based firms. And how many of
29:24
those were in managerial roles?
29:27
Five thousand managers and about
29:29
fifteen hundred promotion events.
29:32
So in terms of empirical
29:34
studies in your realm, this is
29:36
considered a pretty large and robust data
29:38
set or would you have liked it to be even
29:41
bigger than
29:41
that? I would always prefer a bigger data
29:43
set, but for this type of question, a
29:45
very large and comprehensive data set.
29:48
So these are sales
29:50
workers and sales managers, what
29:53
makes sales a good business
29:55
function to study?
29:56
One is important to study sales workers
29:58
because almost ten percent of the
30:00
US labor force or somehow involved
30:02
in the sales function. The other
30:04
benefit is that we have
30:07
a very good measure of their
30:08
performance, so we can test
30:11
are the stronger performers more likely
30:13
to be promoted. So that makes
30:15
a lot of sense from your perspective as
30:17
the scholar from my perspective as
30:20
someone who's not in sales, I would think,
30:22
well, your findings may not translate
30:24
very well that in a field like journalism
30:26
or in healthcare or in many
30:28
other fields, the measurables
30:31
aren't nearly as measurable as
30:33
they are in sales. So how generalizable
30:35
do you think your findings
30:36
are? I believe it's likely to
30:39
apply to other settings where
30:41
the skills required to succeed at one
30:43
level differ from skills required
30:46
to succeed in the next level. So
30:48
some examples are science,
30:51
manufacturing,
30:52
academia, entrepreneurship.
30:55
Can you think of industries or
30:57
sectors where this problem
30:59
wouldn't apply? It's actually hard
31:02
for me to think of a setting which this problem
31:04
wouldn't apply at all. I've also
31:06
seen it in the context of government structures.
31:09
A good example is actually the ancient
31:11
Chinese Imperialexamination system.
31:15
It's famous for being a meritocracy even
31:17
thousands of years ago. So you would take
31:19
a test and the top scores on the
31:21
test would become administrators
31:24
within the government bureaucracy. But
31:26
their problem was they would make the test based
31:28
upon familiarity with classical
31:31
poetry. And the people who are
31:33
vest at that test would then become
31:35
tax
31:36
collectors, which is a different skill set.
31:38
But ancient Chinese poetry was
31:41
an incredibly rich and diverse
31:43
body of literature. Yes. So I could imagine
31:45
how a mastery or even a
31:47
deep appreciation of that could theoretically
31:50
apply across a number
31:52
of skills? Theoretically, yes.
31:55
Ethan, I'm convinced. And to be
31:58
fair, I do not have the historical data
32:00
to prove that being
32:02
the best at classical poetry means
32:05
you are not the best at tax collection. Since
32:08
you don't have that data, let's look at, say,
32:10
modern US politics, how
32:12
would you assess the relationship
32:14
between a person who's electable
32:17
and a person who will govern well. Oh,
32:20
that is a very good point. So someone
32:22
who is electable might be very charismatic,
32:25
very good at public speaking, whereas
32:28
the actual function once someone
32:31
has been elected might involve being
32:33
good at deal
32:34
making, back office politics,
32:37
or understanding the actual details
32:39
of the policies that they're passed
32:41
Do you know anything about that question
32:43
empirically? I'm drawing a blank, but
32:45
you really did raise a very good research
32:48
idea. Maybe I will look into this. We've
32:50
been thinking about settings where this type
32:52
of problem might apply for a long
32:54
time, but somehow it never thought about
32:56
the government or elected official example
32:59
you just raised, but it seems like spot
33:01
on for having potential as a problem.
33:04
Okay. Before I hijacked this conversation
33:06
with Kelly Xu to talk about politics in
33:08
ancient Chinese poetry. We were talking
33:10
about her research paper that tried to
33:13
identify the Peter principle in
33:15
the wild. As Shu
33:17
told us, she had performance data
33:20
on roughly forty thousand sales workers
33:22
and around a hundred thirty companies. The
33:25
next step was to confirm that
33:27
companies indeed use an
33:29
employee's job performance as a
33:31
trigger for
33:32
promotion. The answer? Yes.
33:36
We find that doubling in
33:38
worker sales corresponds to
33:41
a thirty percent increase in their probability
33:43
of being promoted. Another
33:45
way to look at it is if someone
33:48
is the top sales worker, within
33:50
their team of five or six people, then
33:53
that top sales worker has about
33:55
tripled the probability
33:57
of being promoted relative
33:59
to the average sales worker.
34:00
Now is that alone evidence
34:03
of the Peter principle? No.
34:06
Just to promote based upon past performance
34:08
isn't necessarily a Peter principal problem
34:11
because it could be that the best salespeople
34:13
really
34:14
are. The best managers of salespeople.
34:16
In that case, you wanna promote the best salespeople.
34:19
Okay. So the next step, I guess,
34:21
is seeing whether the best salespeople
34:24
indeed do become the best
34:26
managers. How do you do that? So first,
34:28
we're going to measure the quality
34:30
of each manager. Managers
34:32
in our data are no longer directly
34:35
involved in sales. Their job as
34:37
a manager is to coordinate and
34:39
facilitate the sales of their subordinate.
34:42
And
34:42
presumably those subordinates are people
34:44
they worked with side by side and maybe
34:46
competed against just the week before they were
34:48
promoted. Is that the case often? We actually
34:50
see for the most part, people when they're
34:53
promoted, they're rotated to a different
34:55
team. Possibly because the
34:57
firm overall is exactly afraid
35:00
of those internal team dynamics
35:02
that you've just described. So we don't
35:04
want to call someone a good manager because
35:07
her team sells a lot. Because we're
35:09
worried that maybe she was lucky and she
35:11
was assigned to great sales workers.
35:13
And those sales workers could have been great regardless
35:16
of her manager input. To
35:18
get around that problem, we're gonna measure
35:20
manager quality as the manager's
35:23
value added to her subordinate
35:25
sales. If my subordinate sell
35:27
more when they work under me, than
35:29
when they worked under other managers,
35:32
then I would be considered a high
35:34
quality manager.
35:40
So here's the key question Kelly
35:42
Xu is asking. Does being
35:44
a good salesperson make you a good
35:46
manager of other
35:47
salespeople? Here's what she found.
35:49
The manager with double
35:52
the pre promotion sales as another
35:54
manager
35:55
leads to about a six percent decline
35:58
in subordinate sales.
35:59
Oh my goodness. Yes. What we
36:01
find is that among promoted managers,
36:05
those with low sales prior
36:07
to their promotion
36:08
they are actually better at managing
36:11
their supportness. Let
36:13
me say that again. Oh, my
36:15
goodness. When these firms
36:18
select people to be managers based on their current
36:20
job performance, they are actively making
36:22
themselves worse off. In
36:25
other words, the Peter principle is
36:27
as real as Lawrence Peter said
36:29
it was. And I'm
36:31
editorializing here, it would also seem
36:33
to be incredibly stupid.
36:37
If the firm's only goal were
36:40
to have the best possible managers, then
36:43
the firm could by putting more weight
36:45
on collaboration experience and
36:47
less weight on sales numbers. The
36:50
firm could promote better managers
36:52
and raise overall firm sales numbers
36:54
by about thirty percent.
36:56
That's assuming that collaboration experience
36:59
is in fact more important for a
37:01
manager than just high sales numbers.
37:04
Still, a thirty percent increase in
37:06
revenue simply by killing off the
37:08
Peter principle, that would seem to
37:10
be a no brainer. So
37:12
does this mean that modern firms simply
37:14
aren't aware of the age
37:16
old Peter principle?
37:18
Most firms are aware of the
37:20
Peter Principle problem, and it's
37:22
a problem that they purposely choose
37:25
to live with. Some evidence
37:27
we have indicating that in
37:29
situations when the firm
37:32
is trying to select a new manager who is going
37:34
to be in charge of a very large team.
37:36
So that's situation which manager quality
37:39
matters a lot. In
37:41
those situations, firms put less
37:43
weight on a worker sales numbers.
37:46
Probably because they know they're gonna end up
37:48
with a bad manager.
37:50
So she was arguing that firms know
37:52
they will get worse managers by simply
37:54
promoting people who've been good at their previous jobs
37:57
rather than people who might actually be good
37:59
managers. And yet for
38:01
the most part, they continue to
38:03
do it even though it hurts their profits.
38:06
Why would they do that?
38:08
Economists are always telling us that companies
38:11
are by definition profit
38:13
maximizing machines. Knowingly
38:16
promoting a bad manager does not
38:18
sound very profit maximizing So
38:21
are companies just making a mistake?
38:23
Affirm having a Peter principal
38:26
problem doesn't necessarily mean that
38:28
the firm doesn't understand what it's doing
38:30
or it's making a mistake.
38:34
So what is going on? After
38:37
the break, Kelly Xu gives us some answers.
38:39
You
38:39
don't wanna brag about your pay on your resume.
38:42
I'm Steven Dubner. This is Freakonomics
38:44
Radio. We'll be right back
38:49
It's time to reboot your credit card with
38:51
Apple card. Apple card is a different
38:53
kind of credit card. It gives you up to three
38:55
percent unlimited cash back on
38:57
everything you buy. It's real cash
38:59
that never expires or loses value.
39:01
And you can use it on anything. Grab a morning
39:04
coffee, pick up a tab, or pay back a
39:06
friend. Apply now in the wallet app on
39:08
iPhone and start using it right away.
39:10
Apple Card issued by Goldman Sachs Bank USA,
39:12
Salt Lake City branch, subject to credit
39:14
approval. Daily Cash is available via Apple
39:17
Cash Card issued by Green Dot Bank member
39:19
FDIC, as a statement credit, terms
39:21
Freakonomics
39:21
radio
39:24
is sponsored by JustWorks. If you are
39:26
small business leader looking for easier way
39:28
to onboard and manage remote employees
39:30
than you need to learn about JustWorks. JustWorks
39:33
makes it easier for you to start, run,
39:35
and grow a business. Justworks
39:37
gives you the peace of mind in knowing the payroll
39:39
will run smoothly. Your team has
39:42
access to high quality benefits and
39:44
your business is getting the support it
39:46
needs. JustWorks makes it simple
39:48
to hire and manage remote employees across
39:50
all fifty states. JustWorks help
39:53
to comply with state payroll tax
39:55
requirements, keep up with state labor
39:57
laws, and access health insurance plans
39:59
in any state. You have access
40:01
to a cloud based platform that enables
40:03
managers and employees alike to
40:05
quickly and securely access benefits,
40:08
payroll, and other HR functionality from
40:10
anywhere anytime. Plus, there
40:12
are no hidden costs. Take
40:14
a look at Justworks' transparent pricing
40:17
by visiting justworks dot com
40:19
slash pricing. Before
40:26
the break, the Yale Finance Professor
40:29
Kelly Xu was telling us about a study
40:31
she and her colleagues published about the Peter
40:33
principle. That's the idea that a good
40:35
employee will be promoted to
40:37
bigger and bigger jobs until
40:39
they get to a job, they're not gonna have,
40:41
and then they tend to stay there. But
40:44
for years, the Peter Principle was just
40:46
a fury. Kelly Xu wanted to see if it's
40:49
real. Using data on
40:51
thousands of promotions, she did
40:53
find that when top performing sales people
40:55
were promoted into management, the
40:57
sales performance on the teams they managed
41:00
declined. In other words, just because
41:02
somebody's good at their job, doesn't mean
41:04
they'll be good at managing people doing
41:06
that same job. Shu also
41:08
found evidence that firms know
41:10
that the best salespeople make bad
41:13
managers and they choose to promote
41:15
them
41:15
anyway. So what is
41:17
happening? What we believe is happening
41:19
is the firm is doing its best to
41:22
motivate workers, and they face
41:24
a trade off. Okay. This is
41:26
where it gets really interesting. Promoting
41:28
based upon past performance is
41:31
very motivating to workers.
41:33
So it's a very strong incentive system.
41:36
We can also work out this in some ways cheaper
41:39
than offering really strong pay for
41:41
performance. So there are two ways to
41:43
motivate people. We can pay them a whole lot
41:45
more or we can give them an opportunity
41:47
for promotion, which they might
41:49
value a whole lot because that's
41:51
something that they can put on their resume. And
41:53
it increases their status in society.
41:56
You don't wanna brag about your pay on your
41:58
resume. I mean, the minute you say that, it
42:00
makes me think wait. Maybe we should
42:02
make it more acceptable for people to brag about
42:04
their pay because wouldn't that be more efficient
42:06
in the end and encourage
42:08
less promotion of people who are going
42:11
to be bad managers? That's a
42:13
fantastic idea. I don't know of
42:15
research testing that directly. But
42:17
I do know in other
42:18
cultures, there's differences in
42:21
it being more socially acceptable to
42:23
talk about your compensation. I mean,
42:25
I was kind of half joking, but
42:28
it would be interesting if there was some metric
42:30
or badge you get saying,
42:33
I'm really good at what I do. And
42:35
I'm so good that I've been rewarded
42:37
a lot of raises. And plainly,
42:40
I'm very valuable to the firm and I could
42:42
be a manager if I wanted, but
42:45
I'm better than that. That's an
42:47
incredibly hand handed naive way
42:49
of putting it, but Is there any mechanism
42:52
in managerial science for
42:54
that kind of
42:56
delineation between success on
42:58
financial level and success on managerial
43:00
level? There have been some interesting
43:03
attempts in that direction, so I've
43:05
heard of many technology focused
43:07
firms, especially those in Silicon Valley.
43:10
They face this problem that they have
43:12
a pool of very talented and
43:14
skilled engineers and those engineers
43:17
may not be the best managers of engineers.
43:19
Many of those firms offer something
43:21
called a dual career track where
43:24
someone can rise in the ranks of
43:26
being an engineer, basically having a higher
43:28
and higher title. So you can start
43:30
as engineer, then distinguish
43:32
engineer, then lifetime distinguish engineer.
43:36
And that's a way for the
43:38
firm to recognize someone's contributions
43:41
in a public way without moving them
43:43
over to management.
43:47
The Berkeley economist Steve Tedellis
43:49
has also noticed this movement in
43:51
companies like eBay, Google,
43:53
Amazon, Facebook, there's the term
43:55
of IC. There are independent contributor.
43:59
And you will have people who are
44:01
at the level of VP not
44:03
managing a single person. Because they
44:05
are just gods in their realm
44:07
of engineering or coding
44:09
or architecture and so on.
44:12
By distinguishing between ICs
44:15
and the so called management talent,
44:18
the firm is saying, look, we are going to
44:20
promote people in ways
44:22
that reward them for what they're great at.
44:24
You're not a great manager. You're not
44:26
going to get incentivized by becoming
44:29
a manager. Has that model
44:32
trickled out at all of that high-tech
44:34
realm? One area
44:36
where I have seen it is
44:39
in consulting companies where
44:42
you have the kind of deep technical talent,
44:45
think of PhDs, etcetera. That
44:48
will remain and be very heavily rewarded
44:50
for the work they do and they will not
44:53
manage people.
44:56
The fact that Kelly Xu and Steve Tedellis
44:59
can identify handful of cases
45:01
where career success is not tied
45:04
to promotion into management Well,
45:06
those are exceptions that prove
45:08
the rule. As she found
45:10
in her research, the Peter principal is
45:13
alive and well, as absurd as
45:15
that may seem. It is yet
45:17
another confirmation that management science
45:20
as lovely phrase as that may seem
45:22
is not yet very scientific. Most
45:25
firms stick with what they've always done.
45:28
When an employee is good at what they
45:30
do, You turn them into a manager
45:33
to oversee other people who do what they
45:35
used to do, even if they are not
45:37
cut out to be a manager, like
45:40
our friend, Katie
45:41
Johnson, the data scientists
45:44
we met earlier. I didn't see that
45:46
there was another path, whereby I could
45:48
be director level but
45:50
not have direct
45:51
reports. I just didn't ever see that.
45:52
Looking back, there were
45:54
some clues that Johnson wasn't
45:56
quite manager material. You
45:59
remember, during management training,
46:01
she took that personality test, and
46:03
she told us the areas where she got high scores?
46:06
Critical thinking, attention to
46:08
detail, courage, all these kind of
46:10
internal thinking type characteristics.
46:13
Well, those were not the only
46:15
results of this test. Things
46:18
that I can do that I struggle with
46:20
was compassion, empathy
46:23
relationship building. I saw this
46:25
output and I was like, why didn't anyone
46:27
do this to me before I got this
46:29
job? Because this just screams great
46:31
data scientist, not so great manager.
46:34
But it was too late. She'd
46:36
already been made a manager. And
46:38
as you'll recall, it was not going
46:40
well. I would
46:41
finish my day and my study, walk into
46:43
the living room, put a blanket over my
46:45
head and cry.
46:50
So let's say we're talking a scale
46:52
of zero to ten. Where would
46:54
you put your median
46:56
satisfaction and when you were an
46:58
IC or a maker? When I
47:00
was a maker, I put myself as an eight
47:02
and a half that I actually loved
47:05
what I did. I at absolutely loved it. The
47:07
only reason I would even deduct one point
47:09
five points is because there were some
47:11
frustrations, as I mentioned, about not
47:13
being heard and not being
47:15
autonomous. And
47:15
then where would you put it at zero to ten when you'd
47:18
become a full on manager? I would
47:20
say I'd put myself more at like a
47:22
four or A5A6. Would
47:24
be a great day.
47:25
Okay. That's your personal
47:28
satisfaction. I do see, however,
47:30
on LinkedIn a review
47:33
from your manager. He writes,
47:35
Katie is a rounded and passionate
47:37
data leader with all the qualities
47:40
required to inspire manage
47:42
and lead a team. Plus, she has got
47:44
brilliant IC skills to boot.
47:47
And he notes that you are a real unicorn
47:49
in the data analytics
47:51
field. So that sounds like
47:53
you were the best manager ever.
47:55
Yeah. Is
47:58
there any nicest in it?
47:59
It's Really nice. Did he write that before
48:01
or after you decided to quit? He wrote that after.
48:07
You heard that right. Katie Johnson
48:10
quit that management job.
48:12
She quit being a boss entirely.
48:15
She went back to working as a data
48:17
scientist. At a different firm.
48:20
I don't know if you can ever
48:22
be successful at something you don't like.
48:24
I wanna do something that I love and
48:26
I'm really passionate about it because that's the only
48:29
way. Maybe other people are different, but I
48:31
have to love it. I have to be, like, on a Sunday
48:33
night, I can't wait to stop my work tomorrow and get back
48:35
what I was
48:35
doing. And I was never ever ever
48:37
gonna have that in my management job. So
48:40
before you ever became a manager, as a maker,
48:42
you said you're average satisfaction
48:45
or happiness was around eight and a half. When
48:47
you became a manager, dropped to let's call it
48:49
five six on a great
48:52
day. What is it now?
48:54
I'd say it's a nine and a half night. I'm super
48:56
happy. Are you getting paid less
48:58
now as a data scientist then you
49:00
were as a manager? I'm getting paid
49:02
more. How did that happen? I think there
49:05
are more individual contributors now
49:07
that paid good money. I think that this
49:09
technical specialist group is becoming
49:12
more prominent and more rewarded, and
49:14
people do realize that there are gonna
49:16
be a lot of people who don't want become the
49:18
manager. And how do you motivate
49:19
them?
49:20
I believe you looked at the Peter principal
49:22
paper. Is that right?
49:23
Yeah. I did. The way the Peter principal is
49:25
usually described is, to me, almost comical
49:27
to that people rise to the level of their incompetence,
49:30
which I find is a bit cruel
49:32
sounding because one could also
49:34
say that people rise to their
49:36
ceiling of competence. Right?
49:38
And then maybe they're not as good of that. It's not like
49:40
they suddenly turn into idiots. But
49:43
I am curious just your thoughts on
49:45
the notion of promotion into management
49:47
as a reward for being good at what
49:49
you've been doing all
49:50
along. For me, this is where the
49:53
idea of splitting out those levels
49:55
of seniority. So maybe
49:57
you don't become the manager, but you can become a
49:59
technical expert and you are paid and rewarded
50:01
for that. Is something that helps with
50:03
the incentives. What I would say on that though is often
50:06
we have this dual career track of, okay,
50:08
you can be a manager or you can be a technical
50:10
specialist. But even though you might get
50:13
a quote unquote promotion and be paid more,
50:15
the technical specialists still might be excluded
50:17
from high level conversations. So being
50:19
a manager just has this connotation of
50:22
seniority that a technical specialist
50:24
doesn't necessarily and you still might be
50:26
overlooked in terms of just the respect.
50:29
And I think that is motivating more than just hey,
50:31
here's a promotion, here's a new job title. I think
50:33
people want that autonomy and that having
50:35
a seat at the
50:35
table, people caring what you think,
50:38
it has to come with that. I
50:42
would think that many people who are
50:44
promoted from some sort of maker
50:46
to some sort of manager that it would be
50:48
hard to step
50:49
back. If for no other reason, then it seems like
50:52
a loss of status. Yes? It definitely
50:54
feels like a loss of status. I guess, for
50:56
me, I'm lucky that I don't
50:58
care what people think as much as other
51:00
people or at
51:01
all.
51:02
I'm sure that was identified in your personality
51:04
test as well. Yeah, complete rogue
51:06
doesn't care what others think. People
51:08
judge you, which I find interesting because
51:10
I didn't know anyone who likes their job as much
51:13
as I do. So for people to
51:15
look upon me and feel sorry for me in
51:17
a sense that I have chosen to go
51:20
backwards in terms of career hierarchy
51:23
it's kind of telling in terms of what we value
51:25
out for career.
51:26
And you can tell them that if you hadn't done this,
51:29
you wouldn't be on radio.
51:30
Well, it's not play. I got what I
51:32
wanted. Was
51:34
this the plan all along? Yeah. It's an
51:36
update long game. Thanks
51:42
to Katie Johnson for sharing her Boston
51:44
and backstory and to Kelly
51:46
Xu, Steve Tedellis, Nick Blum,
51:48
and all their collaborators for trying to make this
51:51
thing we call management science a
51:53
bit more
51:54
scientific. Coming up next time
51:56
on radio. Insurance
51:58
markets offer an incredibly sexy
52:01
prospect of providing
52:03
a measure of certainty in a
52:05
dangerous and uncertain world. Seriously,
52:09
insurance, sexy? Apparently,
52:12
yes. That's next time on the
52:14
show. Until then, take care of
52:16
yourself. And if you can, someone
52:18
else too. Freakonomics
52:23
radio is produced by Stitcher and Renbud
52:25
Radio. This episode is produced
52:27
by Ryan Kelly and mixed by Greg
52:29
Ripon. We had help from Jeremy Johnston
52:31
and Jared Holt. Our staff also
52:34
includes Zach Lipinski, Morgan Levy,
52:36
Catherine Cure, Elena Coleman, Rebecca
52:38
Lee Douglas, Julie Canford, Eleanor
52:40
Osborn, Jasmine Klinger, Daria Kleenert,
52:43
Ematorel, Lyric Boudic, and Elsa
52:45
Hernandez. The executive team of the
52:47
Freakonomics Radio Network is Neil Carruth,
52:49
Gabriel Roth, and me, Stephen Dubner,
52:52
our theme song is mister Fortune by
52:54
the hitchhikers, all the other music was composed
52:56
by Luis Guerra. As always,
52:59
thanks for listening. Do
53:09
you ever want to tell
53:11
your dean, thanks so
53:13
much for giving me all this managerial
53:16
responsibility, but I don't want it.
53:18
I don't want my reward
53:20
for being a good scholar to be that I have to
53:22
do a bunch of management. I
53:25
haven't thought about that. The
53:33
Freakonomics Radio Network, the
53:35
hidden side of everything. Stitcher.
53:46
This show is brought to you by better help.
53:48
Getting to know yourself can be a lifelong process,
53:51
especially since you're always growing and changing.
53:53
Therapy is all about deepening that self awareness
53:56
because sometimes you don't know what you
53:58
really want until you talk things through.
54:00
Better help connects you with a licensed therapist
54:02
online. Who can take you on that journey
54:04
of self discovery from wherever you are.
54:07
Visit better help dot com slash stitcher
54:09
today to get ten percent off your first month.
54:11
That's better
54:12
help. HELP dot com
54:14
slash stitcher. As
54:17
if the Macrispy couldn't get any better,
54:19
bacon and ranch just entered the
54:21
chat. The bacon ranch
54:23
with crispy, available and participating
54:26
indonald's for a limited time.
Podchaser is the ultimate destination for podcast data, search, and discovery. Learn More