Ep. 302: Vania Stavrakeva on Macro News, Investor Flows and Trading Markets

Ep. 302: Vania Stavrakeva on Macro News, Investor Flows and Trading Markets

Released Friday, 4th April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Ep. 302: Vania Stavrakeva on Macro News, Investor Flows and Trading Markets

Ep. 302: Vania Stavrakeva on Macro News, Investor Flows and Trading Markets

Ep. 302: Vania Stavrakeva on Macro News, Investor Flows and Trading Markets

Ep. 302: Vania Stavrakeva on Macro News, Investor Flows and Trading Markets

Friday, 4th April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:02

Welcome to Macrohive Conversations with Balal Hafiz.

0:05

Macrohive uses natural and artificial intelligence to

0:07

educate investors and provide actional of insights

0:09

for all markets from rates to effects

0:12

to equities. For our latest insights, visit

0:14

macrohive.com. Before I start my conversation with

0:16

this episode's guest, I have three requests.

0:19

First, please make sure to subscribe to

0:21

this podcast. Apple Spotify or if you

0:23

listen to podcast, leave some nice feedback

0:26

and let your friends know about the

0:28

show. My second request is that you

0:30

sign up to a free weekly

0:32

newsletter that contains market insights and

0:35

unlocked content. You can sign up

0:37

for that at macrohigh.com. Finally, and

0:39

my third request is that if

0:42

you are a professional or institutional

0:44

investor, do get in touch with

0:46

me. We have a very

0:49

high-octane research and analytics offering

0:51

that includes access to our

0:53

world-class research team, trade ideas,

0:55

AI models, and much, much more.

0:58

You can email me at Balal

1:00

at macrohigh.com, or you can message

1:02

me on Bloomberg for more details.

1:04

Vania is an assistant professor of

1:06

economics at the London Business School and

1:09

has a PhD from Harvard. She has

1:11

extensively studied exchange rate determination in how

1:13

monetary policy, macroeconomic news and beliefs impact

1:16

exchange rate movements. She has also produced

1:18

innovative research on the global network of

1:20

equity holdings and their impact on equity

1:23

fixing them and exchange rate markets. Now

1:25

on to our conversation. Greetings and welcome

1:27

Vania. It's fantastic to have you on the

1:29

podcast show. Thank you so much for having me. It's

1:31

a pleasure to be here. Now before we start

1:33

the meat of our conversation I do like to

1:36

ask my guest something about their background so it'll

1:38

be great to know something about your origin story

1:40

what did you study at university and was inevitable

1:42

you'd end up in academia. So thank you for

1:45

this question. So I grew up in

1:47

Bulgaria I'm originally from Bulgaria and I'm

1:49

the last generation that lived through communism

1:51

and as a result through all the

1:53

crisis following communism, hyperinflation, sovereign debt crisis,

1:55

banking crisis, which is why I was

1:57

interested in interesting economics. So when I

1:59

went into college. wanted to study economics,

2:01

particularly international finance. I also studied math,

2:03

as every diligent Eastern European is advised

2:06

to study, which thankfully I did. And

2:08

then I spent two years at the

2:10

Brookings Institute, followed by my PhD at

2:12

Harvard. Great. Fantastic. And I see that in

2:15

recent years, you've done a lot of work

2:17

on currency market for exchange. Why currencies, rather

2:19

than any of the market? So exchange rates

2:21

was always a passion of mine. Actually,

2:23

my first FX paper was after undergrad

2:25

when I met Ken Rogofet Brookings and

2:27

we wrote a paper on an example

2:30

of exchange rate forecasting. And of course,

2:32

exchange trade is one of the most

2:34

interesting and important prices in international finance,

2:36

right? So, and it's one of the

2:38

least understood prices in financial markets, which

2:40

is I like a challenge, which is

2:42

why I studied it. So indeed, I

2:44

have studied exchange from various angles throughout

2:46

my career, and I have a number

2:48

of papers on it. If you would

2:50

like me, I can just give you

2:53

a brief overview of what are the

2:55

different ways to think about effects

2:57

determination, and I'm going to

2:59

bring my research throughout the

3:01

discussion. Yeah, maybe we could

3:04

frame it. You mentioned Ken

3:06

Rogoff, and he, of course,

3:08

wrote that famous paper in the

3:10

early 80s, like Dick Macy and Ken

3:12

Rogoff, on our inability to forecast currencies,

3:15

trying to not just... show that exchange

3:17

rates are forecasted by out of sample,

3:19

which has been incredibly hard. But also

3:21

in sample, it was shown for many

3:24

years that one count five reconnect between

3:26

exchange rates and pretty much almost any

3:28

variables. So the good news is that

3:31

the in sample reconnect has been shown

3:33

to exist now, and actually my work

3:35

has contributed towards that, particularly with macroeconomic

3:38

surprises, and I can tell you a

3:40

bit more about that. Of course, out

3:42

of sample forecasting remains challenging, and I

3:44

am exploring it in ongoing work of

3:46

mine. Yeah, great. Okay, so let's go back

3:48

to what you were saying earlier about the

3:51

determinants of exchange rates. Yes, there are two

3:53

ways to think about exchange determination determination.

3:55

Essentially one of the standard ways

3:57

is to take what's called the

4:00

nor arbitrage condition in our finance models,

4:02

which we call the Euler equation, right?

4:04

And then you can express any asset

4:07

price, including exchange rates as a function

4:09

of forward-looking variables. So what do I

4:11

mean by this? You can show that

4:13

the exchange rate can be exchanged over

4:16

any two periods, can be expressed as

4:18

the interest rate differential in period T,

4:20

if you're studying the T plus to

4:23

T plus one change, for example, into

4:25

currency risk premium as a PFT. the

4:27

revisions in expectations over the relative nominal

4:29

policy rate paths, revisions and expectations

4:32

over the relative nominal essentially inflation

4:34

rate paths across the two countries,

4:36

and revisions in expectations over the

4:38

current city's period. So in my

4:40

research with Jenny Tang at the

4:42

Boston Fed, we show essentially constructing

4:44

these components of this decomposition to

4:46

do that we actually use survey

4:48

data in order to back out

4:50

the whole expected path of inflation

4:52

expectations, interest rate expectations, and exchange

4:54

rate expectations, and exchange rate expectations.

4:56

We show that the forward-looking components,

4:58

not surprisingly, are the main driver

5:01

of exchange rates. In particular... And on the data,

5:03

where do you get the survey data? So we

5:05

use consensus economics, blue chips data,

5:07

you can effectively use their survey

5:09

data and the approach the methodology

5:11

that we use is essentially you

5:13

take your standard way to construct

5:15

expectations of variables, which would be

5:18

you run some kind of vector

5:20

regressive essentially process. But then instead

5:22

of just stopping there, you are

5:24

disciplining the expectations produced by this

5:26

model using survey data. Right. So

5:28

the idea is that. we know

5:30

that running a simple VAR is

5:32

going to generate massive downward bias

5:34

and very flat expectations two years ahead.

5:36

So for example, if you're familiar with

5:39

the Campbellshire decompositions, which is a similar

5:41

decomposition for stocks, for those researchers that

5:43

back in the day that would use

5:45

a simple VAR to get the expectations

5:47

going forward, they realized that's garbage, right?

5:49

So the literature moved away from this

5:51

kind of simple VAR-based approach, and one

5:53

of the ways to remedy this problem

5:55

is to discipline the expectations using survey

5:57

data, which has been done in the...

6:00

fixed income space, for example, to decompose,

6:02

yields into expectation, her policy and term

6:04

premium, we were the first to do

6:06

it for effects. So we have a

6:08

series of- And just for our audience,

6:10

when you say VAR, you mean a

6:12

vector auto-regression functions as an econometric, you

6:14

know, equation, rather than value risk. You

6:16

usually run a VAR, but most people

6:19

are going to end there, right? So

6:21

what we say is you're going to

6:23

get a massively biased forecast forecast by

6:25

running a simple VAR. unless you use

6:27

some econometric techniques to address the small

6:29

sample bias. But in even better ways

6:31

to say, well, actually, if we believe

6:34

that the survey data captures fairly well

6:36

the expectations of the market, there is

6:38

pricing, currently asset prices, right? So whatever

6:40

expectations they have. factors in and the

6:42

trading decisions, etc. And that's what we

6:44

do. So we amend the VAR approach

6:47

so that the VAR-based expectations are fairly

6:49

close to the survey-based expectations. So that's

6:51

kind of the methodology of the procedure.

6:54

So using that procedure, you see that

6:56

it is the currency risk premium, right?

6:58

That's kind of the main driver. So

7:00

then when I told you that now

7:03

we have a reconnect between macro variables,

7:05

you might wonder, okay, usually currency is

7:07

perceived to be driven by stuff like

7:10

risk aversion. We have shown, you know,

7:12

to a large degree, connection these days

7:14

between exchange rates and this kind

7:17

of more financial variables, if

7:19

we wish, that measure. Market

7:21

sentiment risk aversion, you know,

7:23

liquidity issues in financial markets,

7:25

etc. CAP deviation is doing an

7:28

other important variable. Now, what we

7:30

show in our world that, yes,

7:32

it is the case that this

7:34

forward-looking currency is a premier component

7:37

is the same macro news. that

7:39

are linked to inflation surprises and

7:41

what I mean by surprises is

7:43

realization of inflation CPI inflation minus

7:45

let's say expectations prior to the

7:47

release of the CPI. So macro surprises

7:49

you're saying drive risk premier as much as

7:52

big as these are the factors? Yes that's

7:54

how you can think about it right so so

7:56

why is it the case the model that tends

7:58

to explain not just if but we've applied

8:00

it also to stock markets in

8:03

some of our work is risk

8:05

aversion is very tightly linked to

8:07

macro fundamental so your risk on

8:09

period can be explained actually the

8:11

global financial cycle in your risk

8:13

on period actually in my in

8:15

my some of my latest work

8:17

we show that can be linked

8:19

to US-centered macro news in particular

8:21

right both contemporaneous and like macro

8:23

news not just contemporaneous. In recent

8:25

years, there has always been a

8:27

factor that drives risk. That's a

8:29

very good question. So sensitivity to

8:31

macro news clearly has been always

8:34

there, right? I mean, you turn

8:36

on Bloomberg and they discuss whatever

8:38

macro release there is on that

8:40

date, but the sensitivity varies over

8:42

time. So some of our research

8:44

actually points in the direction of

8:46

when we would expect macro news

8:48

to matter. So we find that

8:50

macro news matter more during periods

8:52

of kind uncertainty. Right. So that's

8:54

when markets are learning more through

8:56

what we call public signals or

8:58

common signals, right? So you essentially

9:00

pretty much putting a larger weight

9:02

on macro signals. So high uncertainty

9:05

recessions disappear. It's where macro news

9:07

tend to matter more. Now we

9:09

also find. In our world, that

9:11

it's lag macaronous riding contemporaneous. So

9:13

that's truly the novel contribution of

9:15

a lot of my research is

9:17

to focus on lag riding contemporaneous.

9:19

So that's something that was missed

9:21

in the literature for a long

9:23

time. For example, we find that

9:25

lag macaronous account in sample, that's

9:27

not a half sample, for about

9:29

50 to 60% of the fluctuations

9:31

of exchange rates at monthly and

9:33

quarterly frequency, is because actually this

9:36

lag pardon and contemporaneous news. So

9:38

the reason why often... both academic

9:40

research, but often also financial practitioners

9:42

focus on contemporaneous, is because they

9:44

say, oh, like information is priced

9:46

in. But that's not necessarily the

9:48

right way to think about it,

9:50

because at every single point of

9:52

time, markets are learning about the

9:54

state of the economy. So let

9:56

me give you a concrete example.

9:58

So imagine you have CPI reduced.

10:00

and then you find that the

10:02

inflation number was higher than the

10:04

consensus, right? We have a positive

10:07

surprise. In order for you to

10:09

interpret... What the impact of this positive

10:11

surprise will be on any asset price

10:13

doesn't have to be affects, it has

10:15

to be stocks, you know, fixed income.

10:17

You need to take it in context

10:20

to what was the latest GDP release,

10:22

right? And was the latest GDP surprise

10:24

on non-farm payroll. So why am I

10:26

saying that? Well, for example, if we

10:28

live in a world where we have

10:31

a positive CPI surprise today, but then

10:33

in the last quarter we had a

10:35

negative GDP surprise, markets extrapolating based on

10:37

this information regime. Right. So you're using

10:39

today's releasing context to previous releases to

10:41

figure out is the variance of supply

10:44

shocks bigger than demand shocks, right? Is

10:46

the shop persistent or not? So we're

10:48

constantly learning, right? So in economics, formally

10:50

you're going to write a patient updating

10:52

model to do that, but the model

10:55

is so complex that clearly no financial

10:57

market participant is kind of solving any

10:59

model, but they're doing it in the

11:01

back of their head, right? They're trying

11:03

to figure out, okay. What does this

11:05

surprise mean in the context of kind

11:08

of the latest news or the history

11:10

of news? So the moment you start

11:12

learning about what we call second or

11:14

the moment, not just the mean of

11:16

supply and demand, right, but also the

11:19

variance, you know, persistence, then the lax

11:21

matter, right? Because you're putting a weight

11:23

on the lack surprises. In a sense,

11:25

that's what kind of the model generates,

11:27

and that is one of the justifications

11:29

why LACS is so important. Now, the

11:32

question arises, can you make money out

11:34

of it, right? So the answer is

11:36

that to the extent that the interpretation

11:38

effectively changing the interpretation of the LAC

11:40

surprises, if you wish, because you decide

11:43

that now we are in a supply

11:45

right in demand region, right? Now. In

11:47

order for you to make money out

11:49

of it, granted that the interpretation changes

11:51

due to the new information that arrives

11:54

today, right, is the interaction of the

11:56

two, you need essentially markets not to

11:58

be good at optimally updating their beliefs,

12:00

right? So they need to be rational

12:02

in some way, which clearly it is

12:04

the case. No one can solve this

12:07

complicated basis. actually it's hard for us

12:09

to solve it. We need to use

12:11

some tricks to do it in our

12:13

research. So granted that markets are not

12:15

kind of doing the optimal Bayesian updating,

12:18

yes, you can exploit that in order

12:20

to effectively develop forecasting models based on

12:22

this landmark on use, which I have

12:24

started doing. So there is some hope

12:26

then in terms of finding proper strategy.

12:28

Yes, I started exploiting that. Is the

12:31

work course of this rate differentials, so

12:33

carry trades, is that the engine one

12:35

would look at, you know, because then

12:37

you're looking to uncovering interest like parity,

12:39

you carry trades? Differentials definitely play a

12:42

role and usually people Think about interest

12:44

rate differential from the fixed income market,

12:46

right? In the sense that you have

12:48

that, for example, the interest rate in

12:50

the US increases relative to Europe, and

12:52

then people doing the carry trade, they

12:55

borrow in Europe, you know, now the

12:57

care trade becomes more profitable, you borrow

12:59

in Europe, you know, now the care

13:01

trade becomes more profitable, you borrow in

13:03

Europe, you borrow in Europe, invest in

13:06

the US, you put market pressure in

13:08

the door from the fixed income market.

13:10

arbitrage conditions, where is this going to

13:12

show up? It's going to show up

13:14

as a link between the current city's

13:17

premium and interest rate differential, which of

13:19

course has been shown to exist, right?

13:21

So you need to find the same

13:23

relationship between exchange rates and interest rate

13:25

differential. But the more intuitive way to

13:27

think about this for me, the carry

13:30

trade in particular is by thinking about

13:32

dispositioning models, right, and how market pressure

13:34

due to changing the positioning with respect

13:36

to doors coming from the fixed income

13:38

market is putting an upper passion on

13:41

the door, for example. Okay, so in

13:43

terms of that position then, let's delve

13:45

a bit more deeply into that. So

13:47

the second part of my research agenda

13:49

focuses on effectively how do we think

13:51

about holdings and positioning if you wish

13:54

in financial markets is drivers of asset

13:56

prices. There I developed a completely double

13:58

decomposition, which actually first it was I

14:00

developed it with the goal of studying

14:02

effects, but it just so happens that

14:05

it works beautifully for equities as well.

14:07

So now I have a lot of

14:09

research on equities as well, but they

14:11

did there is. Actually, let me start

14:13

a little bit with a brief description

14:16

on, you have to explain how it

14:18

works well, which is in order to

14:20

be able to explain how it works

14:22

for effects. And there is also a

14:24

mapping to fixed income as well. But

14:26

the idea there is you take your

14:29

what we call market theory and condition

14:31

nominal supply has to economical holdings, right,

14:33

or nominal demand. So in a market-based

14:35

economy, this has to hold. If you

14:37

observe the universe of holdings of a

14:40

particular stock, let's take in this case,

14:42

Apple, or given ice and for Apple,

14:44

then. If you have the universe of

14:46

holding swap, this has to add up

14:48

to nominal supply. What is nominal supply?

14:50

It's the price of apples times the

14:53

shares issued. Right. Now the shares issued

14:55

at IC and level is pretty much

14:57

driven by buybacks and it doesn't explain

14:59

much of the variance if you wish

15:01

of the price itself. It's not a

15:04

very volatile variable. So the nominal supply

15:06

is just the change in the price

15:08

of apples. which is kind of what

15:10

we're trying to explain. So that's what

15:12

you have on the left hand side.

15:14

What do you have on the right

15:17

hand side? Well, we have the change

15:19

in holdings which are summed up across

15:21

every single investor that buys Apple. So

15:23

this would be from hedge funds to

15:25

pension funds to mutual funds, etc. Right.

15:28

Now you can decompose this change of

15:30

holdings. can be broken down into components

15:32

with very intuitive interpretation that then later

15:34

can lead you into the direction of

15:36

thinking about causality and how do we

15:39

develop investment strategies etc. So what are

15:41

those components? The price of Apple can

15:43

be moving. because of rebalancing, right? Portfolio

15:45

way changes. So this was one of

15:47

the components of the change in holdings.

15:49

The second component is the growth rate

15:52

of assets in the management. So imagine

15:54

a given fund now increases their assets

15:56

in the management on average, their long

15:58

Apple, and then of course this is

16:00

going to also put upward pressure for

16:03

Apple, the most mechanical thing being index

16:05

funds, right? Money is fleeing into index

16:07

funds, which is putting an upper pressure

16:09

on Apple. The growth rate of assets

16:11

in the management can be further broken

16:13

down into the net of the net

16:16

of returns component. So essentially you make

16:18

profits on your portfolio that get to

16:20

invest. including in Apple, right, or final

16:22

inflows and outflows into the fund. So

16:24

those are the two components that indeed

16:27

have very intuitive interpretation. And there is

16:29

a four subcomponent of holdings, which is

16:31

exchange evaluation effects. That's why the exchange

16:33

rate is going to enter the story.

16:35

And it captures that you have used

16:37

the or funds, let's say, buying Brazilian

16:40

stocks, and they need to exchange the

16:42

currency in between putting upward pressure potential

16:44

on the currency. Now. If you have

16:46

all the holdings, you can construct those

16:48

components and then you can test various

16:51

theories and kind of discuss what are

16:53

the drivers of equities etc. So the

16:55

revelation that I had in my research

16:57

is actually even if we focus only

16:59

on mutual funds where we have the

17:02

best data, right? We also have very

17:04

good data coming from the U.S. using

17:06

let's say SEC 13F also on not

17:08

just mutual funds but hedge funds to

17:10

essentially everyone that holds equity. It's a

17:12

bit trickier. to use that data to

17:15

decompositions because you don't necessarily see the

17:17

final in close and the net of

17:19

your returns, which you see in the

17:21

mutual funds. So there are the regulatory

17:23

forms and also companies like Morningstar. And

17:26

the mutual funds you just get from

17:28

some database that provides these sorts of

17:30

things. It's Morningstar. So it's morning star.

17:32

So we use Morningstar direct, which reports

17:34

essentially the variables that you need in

17:36

order to construct the following, right? So

17:39

you have a. limited coverage. For the

17:41

US, we have 15% of the coverage,

17:43

right? So what they mean by coverage,

17:45

cauldings relative to the market cup of

17:47

a particular icing. If you go to

17:50

other countries, we have 33 countries and

17:52

20,000 stops, right, icing. So it is

17:54

a global model. You have even more

17:56

limited coverage for China. We have 0.01%

17:58

often. So the idea here is that,

18:00

well, even with this limited coverage and

18:03

even. if we observe only mutual funds

18:05

and again here we focus only on

18:07

a sample starting 2008 which is the

18:09

period when mutual funds growing importance right

18:11

so you're not going to get as

18:14

much of a good fit if you

18:16

kind of do it in the 90s

18:18

of course when mutual does it. management

18:20

industry wasn't so prominent in the equity

18:22

space. So starting in 2008, the observations

18:25

I had is like, well, wait a

18:27

second, we might have limited coverage, but

18:29

if the mutual funds are representative of

18:31

the behavior of the investors we don't

18:33

observe, then you can take their holdings

18:35

and scale them up as if you

18:38

have a representative sample. So what do

18:40

I mean by this? So the good

18:42

news is that we observed the pension

18:44

funds and insurance behavior to mutual funds

18:46

to accommodate. pension funds investment, right? So

18:49

you kind of have also those big

18:51

players indirectly in that data, if you

18:53

wish. And the case, you're going to

18:55

split your funds by type. What do

18:57

you mean by type? So let's take

18:59

large caps, US stocks, active funds, certain

19:02

frequency of rebalancing. So you can have

19:04

a granular bucket, especially for the large

19:06

stocks. When you go to small stocks,

19:08

you don't have that many funds. So

19:10

you can't go that granular. But for

19:13

Apple, you can go really granular. And

19:15

then what you do is say, well,

19:17

let's take each component, let's say the

19:19

portfolio weight changes, right? We can always

19:21

break down for every single funds holding

19:24

the Apple, the portfolio way change of

19:26

fund I with respect to Apple. I

19:28

can decompose it as an average within

19:30

this narrowly defined bucket of funds and

19:32

residual, right? You can always do that

19:34

simple decomposition. Now, this average that I

19:37

can construct based on the sample that

19:39

I observe, as long as it's... fairly

19:41

closely aligned with the population average for

19:43

the funds that belong in that bucket,

19:45

then effectively I can scale up this

19:48

average as if I... observe the universe

19:50

of holding. So does the idea here?

19:52

It turns out that they use incredibly

19:54

balancing, which is very volatile, right? So

19:56

if you look at our plots, you

19:58

see a cloud of dots for the

20:01

portfolio wage change. And the reason why

20:03

it's the average that matters so much

20:05

is because the way to think about

20:07

it, is because the way to think

20:09

about it, is this is the information

20:12

that is contemporaneously priced in by the

20:14

whole market, right? So we all observed

20:16

the end of quarter report, and we're

20:18

going on. forecasting the price of Apple

20:20

going forward. But that information is not

20:22

part of the information set of everyone

20:25

trading today, so it's not going to

20:27

move the prices up all today, right?

20:29

That's why contemporaneously it's going to be

20:31

this portfolio wage change. Now you do

20:33

that for the flows and the net-offier

20:36

returns of components, you carry it up.

20:38

And now it turns out that across

20:40

33 stock markets and 20,000 ices, contemporaneously

20:42

you can count for about 90% of

20:44

the variation of this 20,000 stock prices

20:47

at monthly frequency. 9-0. Okay. Yes, it's

20:49

striking. I've tried to kill it. It's

20:51

actually now when I present this evidence,

20:53

I have to go and show China

20:55

and a stock with a 0.01% coverage

20:57

and show when it doesn't work, right?

21:00

Because no one, I mean, I actually

21:02

want, I can't show you some plots,

21:04

but I don't think we'll have the

21:06

time, but the fit is truly striking,

21:08

especially for the big ice, the fit

21:11

is perfect, right? And again, the idea

21:13

is this, these guys, these guys, these

21:15

guys are representative, the representative, right. Presumably

21:17

the morning star data or this all

21:19

this flow data comes with a lag

21:21

in like is the point in time

21:24

data you're looking at or are you

21:26

looking at contemporaneous decomposition and the way

21:28

I have used it in in order

21:30

to develop investment strategies based on that

21:32

right because the contemporaneous relationship is not

21:35

what you're going to use in order

21:37

to kind of develop investment strategies is

21:39

to essentially exploit the heterogeneity in objectives

21:41

among the different players in the markets.

21:43

What do I mean by this right

21:45

you have some a set of funds

21:48

that are going to be contrary and

21:50

some are going to be momentum. You

21:52

have the index funds versus active. So

21:54

by playing the heterogeneity in objectives, you

21:56

can exploit lacked information in these components.

21:59

And I have developed strategies with a

22:01

sharp ratio of 20% return market neutral

22:03

based on this. That is not going

22:05

to be made publicly available. But it

22:07

is possible to use the sub components.

22:10

And again, to give an example that

22:12

probably most of your viewers are going

22:14

to be familiar with coming from the

22:16

fixed income space, right? So how do

22:18

people explore? the heterogeneity in objectives and

22:20

preferences there. Clearly, when the central banks

22:23

are doing Q&QT, you know, investors are

22:25

front running, for example, the purchase of

22:27

the actual. long-term ground bonds. You're exploiting

22:29

the presence of pension funds that have,

22:31

you know, liability-driven investment and they're going

22:34

to hedge. So this has been exploited

22:36

massively in the fixed income space. This

22:38

is equivalent in the equity space, right?

22:40

Because you do have a lot of

22:42

heterogeneous, you have guys that are doing

22:44

fundamental assets, you have guys that are

22:47

momentum reversal, etc. And that's how you

22:49

can exploit. That's truly positioning from the

22:51

equity space, right, if you wish. And

22:53

then the papers, for those of you

22:55

that might be interested in kind of

22:58

stylized facts coming from this decomposition, because

23:00

then you can take the decomposition and

23:02

ask the question, okay, which one of

23:04

the components drive asset prices, right? So

23:06

if you take IS and level asset

23:08

prices, indeed, we find that it's the

23:11

portfolio way changes that are the main

23:13

driver of essentially individual level asset prices.

23:15

But when you go to the stock

23:17

market level. the S&P versus, you know,

23:19

European indices etc, across 33 stock markets,

23:22

the picture changes dramatically. So what happens

23:24

is all of a sudden for S&P,

23:26

right, or for the US stock market,

23:28

the main driver is no longer the

23:30

portfolio wage changes. It's actually the net

23:33

if he returns and the final inflows,

23:35

the final inflows account. for a small

23:37

fraction of the variation is the net-of-reterners

23:39

that drive most of the duration, but

23:41

they're always significant. So the world that

23:43

we live in for the US stock

23:46

market is you are in a risk-com

23:48

period, money of fleeing fixing funds, going

23:50

into equity markets, which gets amplified by

23:52

the profits generated by equity funds that

23:54

invest in the S&P, right? So this

23:57

is the main driver of- So this

23:59

is the growth of the AOM side

24:01

of things, is driving the- The index.

24:03

The growth of the AOM, but the

24:05

original shock, the exerting shock, comes from

24:07

the final influence into the funds because

24:10

the neatory deterrence is just... function of

24:12

prices itself, right? So it has an

24:14

amplification effect, if you wish, where the

24:16

original source of variation in that model

24:18

is going to be from the final

24:21

inflows into the funds and whatever the

24:23

active guys are doing with the portfolio

24:25

weight changes, right? They can be creating

24:27

one fundamental use, etc. The rest, you

24:29

can map to prices and you can

24:32

kind of solve it out once you

24:34

write the structural model. So, but then

24:36

when you go to Brazil, Turkey... Even

24:38

some other advanced economies, the portfolio changes

24:40

remain an important driver, right? The netafel

24:42

returns disamplification effect is still present. The

24:45

final inflow is always significant, which is

24:47

good because that's where the exosional variation

24:49

comes from. But then the portfolio changes

24:51

is too important. So. Then because we

24:53

have the micro to macro decomposition, so

24:56

that's kind of the first paper to

24:58

truly go across countries and do the

25:00

micro to macro, going from Iceland level

25:02

to stock market, even in, you know,

25:04

in the academic financial literature, we can

25:06

truly decompose why the picture changes, right?

25:09

How come for the year stock market

25:11

at an Iceland level with 60% portfolio

25:13

wage changes and all of a sudden

25:15

the portfolio which changes even slightly negative.

25:17

asset rebalancing. So what do you mean

25:20

by this? When you go to the

25:22

aggregate stock market, what changes is that

25:24

it matters which stock do you buy

25:26

when you sell Apple, right? So for

25:28

the US, investor state within the dollar

25:30

currency market, right? Within the US stock

25:33

market. So if you buy one US

25:35

stock, they're going to sell another US

25:37

stock. As a result, they prefer the

25:39

way changes. Even their, the main driver,

25:41

Iceland will simply cancel out when we

25:44

aggregate all the different stock. because you're

25:46

not moving across. So the cross-air was

25:48

distancing, is if you wish, a negative,

25:50

right? When you go to Brazil and

25:52

Turkey, what happens? You say, well, just

25:55

talk in Brazil and you buy Turkey.

25:57

So you go across currency borders, right?

25:59

And that is kind of the reason.

26:01

Even at the ice and level of

26:03

the stock market level. Just for the

26:05

point for our audience, because I'm just

26:08

making sure that they. they follow this.

26:10

So what you're saying is with US

26:12

markets, in particular, what you find is

26:14

that the single company level, like the

26:16

apples and so on, is the portfolio

26:19

weight changes that make all the difference.

26:21

But when you aggregate up to the

26:23

S&P level, what matters more is the

26:25

growth in the AUN, the fund flow,

26:27

the net profit move between asset classes,

26:29

like bonds to equities, equities to bonds.

26:32

It's what drives, that's what drives, that's

26:34

what drives, that gets. amplified with essentially

26:36

the profits generated by the funds. But

26:38

then with EM countries like Turkey and

26:40

Brazil it's more across countries than suddenly

26:43

the switch happens rather than within US.

26:45

Indeed the portfolio weight changes remain an

26:47

important driver. Yeah. Now What about effects?

26:49

Right? So effects is very interesting in

26:51

that space, especially when you go outside

26:53

of the US stock market. So when

26:56

you draw a picture and then we

26:58

have this cool network plot section the

27:00

follow-up paper, which is on exchange rates

27:02

and currency centrality, where essentially we show

27:04

that the US clearly is the main

27:07

player in town, more so than fixed

27:09

income. So if you look at equity

27:11

markets, it's US dollar funds that pretty

27:13

much buy global equity markets. Right. So

27:15

even if you take UK. their significantly

27:18

smaller amount of assets in the management

27:20

denominated in euros and pounds invested in

27:22

equities. So the US is kind of

27:24

the center, right? So US funds, US

27:26

dollar funds are buying all global stocks.

27:28

That's where the FX role comes in

27:31

and the pressure into. So the next

27:33

thing we've done, and before I'm moving

27:35

to how do you formally map this

27:37

to exchange rates, even these decompositions, here's

27:39

implications for exchange rates due to this

27:42

exchange evaluation effect, I didn't mention, right.

27:44

So what does the exchange rate component

27:46

do in terms of being a driver

27:48

of equities? And the implications here are

27:50

the same at an IC&N and aggregate

27:52

stock market level. So let me discuss

27:55

them at the aggregate stock market level.

27:57

So we find that for every single

27:59

stock market market besides the door, Japanese

28:01

here. Swiss francis mixed back and then

28:03

every currency packed to the dollar, right?

28:06

What happens is that both the currency

28:08

and the stock market moves in the

28:10

same direction. So what do you mean

28:12

by this? When the Brazilian stock market

28:14

appreciates, it's also that the real is

28:16

going to appreciate, right? But that's not

28:19

the case, of course, for the dollar.

28:21

The usual cycle, what is happening now,

28:23

but the usual global financial cycle, now

28:25

it's a US cycle. The usual global

28:27

financial cycle is that all risky assets

28:30

go up and then the door

28:32

depreciates. So what that means is,

28:34

is if you want to... take

28:36

your more macroeconomic hat is so

28:39

as an investor clearly you're benefiting

28:41

both if you're a US dollar

28:43

investor both from the real appreciating

28:45

and the stock market appreciating local

28:48

currency if you're going to buy

28:50

a Brazilian stock. What does it

28:52

mean from a kind of more

28:54

big picture macro point of view?

28:57

It means that the fact that

28:59

the exchange rate is moving, helping

29:01

equilibrium, real goods is it makes sure

29:03

that the volatility of the Brazilian

29:05

stock market in local currency is

29:08

not as high. So it dampens

29:10

the volatility of the local stock

29:12

market. That's why when we calculate

29:14

these scaled covariances when we do

29:16

these various covariance compositions and study

29:18

what fraction of the S&P price

29:20

movement and the Brazilian stock market

29:22

price movement is due to the

29:24

set components. The exchange rate component

29:26

contributes negatively. It dampens the

29:29

volatility of the local stock market

29:31

in local currency, right? kind of the

29:33

exchange rate component and say something more

29:35

concretely about exchange rates because this is

29:37

about, you know, exchange exchange rate component

29:39

is a basket of currency, right? We

29:41

want to study dollar euro, dollar pound,

29:43

we want to study bilateral currencies. Actually,

29:45

you can do that, right? Because you

29:47

have now a system of equations, I

29:49

have 33 stock markets, and then the

29:52

equivalent exchange rates, let's say against the

29:54

door that correspond to those 33 stock markets.

29:56

So you have a system of equations that you

29:58

can kind of flip it. and so forth, all

30:01

the bilateral exchange trade. So now you have

30:03

a model where every single bilateral exchange

30:05

trade. And the interesting thing is that a lot

30:07

of the things that I tell you, essentially everything

30:09

applies not just to door base, right? So

30:11

actually, particularly we study also the euro base

30:13

as well. We can do it for any

30:15

base. You can express any exchange trade

30:17

as a function of what we call net supply

30:20

components that I explain what they are, and loadings

30:22

based on that which you can

30:24

think of it of them as

30:26

elasticisticities. right? That a function of

30:28

the centrality of different stock markets,

30:30

right? So let me just give you

30:32

a concrete example. So what

30:34

is this net supply measure?

30:36

The net supply measure is

30:38

simply the valuation of the

30:40

local stock market. So that's

30:42

kind of the nominal supply

30:45

of equities in Brazilian Rio

30:47

or US dollar, etc. Right. So

30:49

there are stock market specific, which

30:51

is just the price of the

30:53

stock market, minus... the demand for

30:56

that stock market but denominated

30:58

in the investor currency right so granted we

31:00

said that US door funds own everything

31:02

that is going to be primarily

31:04

US door investors demand holdings

31:07

denominated in US doors so to

31:09

the extent the nominal supply denominated in

31:11

Brazil they are real minus these holdings

31:13

that are denominated in dollars if there

31:16

is a gap it's the exchange rate

31:18

that needs to move in order to

31:20

equally pay the market So in that

31:22

example, so the net splice, let's

31:24

say from a US perspective investing

31:27

into Brazil, if the Brazilian rail

31:29

strengthens, then does that mean the

31:31

demand has increased into Brazil? So

31:33

let me just give you a specific

31:36

example to make it a bit clear.

31:38

This is a bit complicated, I think,

31:40

to grasp. But effectively imagine that you

31:42

have, you can measure an exhorgener shock,

31:45

exhorgeness demand coming from the US. you

31:47

know coming from the US for Brazilian

31:49

stocks. The market can clear in two

31:51

ways. One is the Brazilian stock market

31:54

appreciates in local currency, right? And the

31:56

second way is the Brazilian rehab appreciates

31:58

because if the Brazilian have appreciates. Now

32:00

of a sudden the dollar, the dollar

32:03

demand can buy fewer Brazilian stocks,

32:05

so the local stock market doesn't

32:07

have to appreciate. So effectively that's

32:09

what this net supply measures is

32:12

capturing, right? So by zoning into

32:14

the demand nominated in US dollars,

32:16

we are extracting how much the

32:18

currency needs to move in order

32:20

to clear. It's kind of the residual

32:23

claimant. It incorporates the fact that

32:25

the local market in response

32:27

to this exogenous demand shock. But

32:29

then if it's... So either the local stocks could

32:32

increase or the local effects could increase?

32:34

So in a world with fixed exchange rates,

32:36

everything is going to be done by the

32:38

local stock market serving, right? And then actually

32:40

this net supply measure has to be zero or

32:43

close to zero, right? In that world, where you

32:45

have loading exchange rates, actually exchange rates can

32:47

do a pretty big chunk of the job

32:49

in a sense. So then now we have

32:51

a world where every single bilateral exchange trade

32:53

is a function of this net supply

32:56

measures kind of scaled by... particular

32:58

entities that we directly observe, which

33:00

come out of the sub components

33:02

of our decompositions. And then in the

33:04

follow-up paper, which is with Helen,

33:06

we document a lot of novel

33:09

facts around why is the US

33:11

dollar effectively, why does the US

33:13

dollar come off so strongly with

33:15

the global financial cycles, but the

33:17

euro does. Right. So there what

33:19

we are doing is tracing. Why does

33:21

the particular exchange rate move in response

33:23

to the global financial cycle, which we

33:25

measure using this US macro news that

33:27

I mentioned in risk aversion shocks, also

33:30

in that paper we show that the

33:32

global financial cycle, which usually is measured

33:34

as the first principal component of risky

33:36

assets, right? So that's kind of what

33:38

people usually used to calculate these risk-on

33:40

measures. That's where they come from. We

33:42

show that actually can have a much

33:44

more kind of exogenous measure of that.

33:46

We pretty much show that this... Financial

33:49

cycle is driven by contemporaneous and lack

33:51

macro news and risk conversion shops that

33:53

originate from the US due to the

33:55

structure of equity markets, right? The US

33:57

funds own everything so that's why they

33:59

are are very sensitive to these US

34:01

shocks, particularly in flows into equity funds

34:04

that get invested not just in the

34:06

US but also globally. That's kind of

34:08

the big issue. And so what follows

34:10

from that then, so what you're saying

34:12

essentially is that you've established this new

34:14

sort of flow factor that helps explain

34:16

the US centrality. So what follows then

34:18

is if Europe suddenly established ended up

34:20

with the big equity market in the

34:23

world and they were the biggest investors

34:25

in the world, then you end up

34:27

with the euro global cycle, which isn't

34:29

really likely to happen. But what you've

34:31

done is you've added some meat or

34:33

theory to this empirical observation of US

34:35

driving everything. Indeed, and then you

34:37

can use, also we have a lot

34:39

of facts where we show that actually

34:42

focusing on just the local net supply

34:44

and the door is enough to account

34:46

for most of the migration, so you

34:48

can significantly reduce the dimensionality of the

34:51

problem, etc. So it has a lot

34:53

of, essentially... And just going back to

34:55

that Brazil example, you know, in terms

34:57

of what takes the pressures of the

34:59

equity market or the currency, doesn't need

35:01

to move. basically all the pressures gone

35:04

into the empty market which is feels

35:06

kind of counterintuitive because you you kind

35:08

of think that okay if the empty

35:10

market's going to go up then FX

35:12

also has to go up but what you're

35:15

almost saying is actually that doesn't

35:17

have to be the case. Yeah so so

35:19

in a sense what's missing here in fixed

35:21

income so we do need to talk about

35:23

fixed income and let me kind of close

35:25

the the story by telling you what needs

35:27

to happen in fixed income to observe what

35:29

we're happening in equity equity markets. So if

35:31

fixed income is a crucial driver driver And

35:33

again, one needs to do additional work to

35:35

truly nail the causal effect and we are

35:37

going in that direction here. But if the

35:40

fixed income is the main driver and something

35:42

else is happening in the fixed income world,

35:44

it doesn't have to be the case indeed

35:46

that the exchange trade appreciates. It could be

35:48

that just the local stock market

35:50

essentially is appreciating in response to

35:52

exogenous demand for Brazilian stops coming

35:54

from the US. Now the fixed income world

35:57

is very interesting because it's the flip side

35:59

of the equity. So what do we mean

36:01

by this? So in the currency centrality

36:03

paper, what we find is that there

36:05

is a very interesting sorting between how

36:08

much this net supply component responds to

36:10

the cycle shocks, right, which translates into

36:12

how much the exchange rate responds to

36:14

the cycle shocks that we capture, correlates

36:16

very strongly with the openness of the

36:19

stock market. So the more open the

36:21

equity market is, and the Brazilian stock

36:23

market is very open, right? So most

36:25

of it is held by U.S. door

36:27

funds of locally issued equities, the more

36:30

the net supply component's responses is the

36:32

result the exchange rate is loading on

36:34

this global financial cycle, right? Now, let's

36:36

think about, and of course, for the

36:38

U.S. it's kind of the reverse. The

36:41

net supply is kind of the shifting

36:43

in the opposite way. The U.S. is

36:45

close to a close to the market.

36:47

90 percent of U. US dollar denominated

36:49

equity funds. So that's kind of the

36:52

closest to a close if you wish

36:54

equity market there is. That's another unique

36:56

property. The size plus the closeness of

36:58

the two very unique properties that are

37:00

needed in order to make the door

37:03

a good hedge for the global financial

37:05

cycle. Actually, that's explicitly made in the

37:07

paper. What about the fixed income market?

37:09

It's actually quite interesting because the two

37:11

main markets that exchange rates are going

37:14

to clear will be the fixed income

37:16

and the equity market. So the real

37:18

good side that's kind of one year

37:20

and above frequency because we have sticky

37:22

prices. So we don't have to worry

37:25

about it that much. So the fixed

37:27

income market is the flip side in

37:29

terms of openness. So what do you

37:31

mean by this? So the US equity

37:33

market is very close, but the US

37:36

fixed income market is super open. Why?

37:38

Because we know that in normal times,

37:40

US long-term government debt appreciates in bad

37:42

times and the door appreciates. So it's

37:44

the best catch there is. So foreigners

37:47

love to hold US government debt and

37:49

actually they flooding to US government debt

37:51

whenever we have, like to safety episodes,

37:53

right? So Japan is also a fairly

37:55

close stock market, right? Not as close

37:58

as the US, but it's one of

38:00

the more closed. stock markets there is.

38:02

But what about Brazil? What about Turkey,

38:04

right? The market economies. So when you

38:06

look at their fixed market, fixed income

38:09

market, they of course have, in most

38:11

cases, bigger fixed income market than equity

38:13

market, right? The equity markets are not

38:15

that developed. But a big fraction of

38:17

this fixed income market is issued not

38:20

a local currency. It's issued in dollars.

38:22

It's issued in euros. Why? Because Pimko

38:24

doesn't want to hold. local currency. They're

38:26

going to buy euro or door. So

38:28

what is issued in local currency from

38:31

the fixed income market? A lot of

38:33

that is actually internally helped by Brazilian

38:35

investors, if you wish. So actually, if

38:37

you just think about the fraction of

38:39

the fixed income market issued in local

38:42

currency, which is what matters for the

38:44

exchange trade, right, at the end of

38:46

the day. Because we want to think

38:48

about Brazilian reality versus doors. Actually, the

38:50

fixed income market in emerging market economies

38:53

is fairly closed. So it's the flip

38:55

side of equity. So what the exchange

38:57

trade is doing is moving in order

38:59

to equilibrate the stock markets and the

39:01

fixed income markets that are relatively more

39:04

open. So it just so happens that

39:06

in the case of Brazil, the equity

39:08

market is very open, and the fixed

39:10

income market counting only fixing commission in

39:12

Brazilian currency is closed. So it is

39:15

accommodating the equity market. In the case

39:17

of the US. the exchange rate is

39:19

clearing the fixed income market, right? And

39:21

that's why usually you have this negative

39:23

comm movement between long-term government debt and

39:26

stocks in the US. So there is,

39:28

everything has to hold in equilibrium, right?

39:30

All the markets need to clear and

39:32

the exchange rate is entering all this

39:34

market. So again, there's way more work

39:37

that needs to be done and we

39:39

need to do in terms of getting

39:41

truly causal instruments in some for demand

39:43

shocks, etc. This is the picture of

39:45

the world that truly kind of explains

39:48

the data and maps well to the

39:50

data. So fixed income markets are interesting,

39:52

but what we are pushing is that

39:54

actually equity markets are in some ways

39:56

even more interesting. particularly when we want

39:59

to study as well Brazil and effectively

40:01

emerging markets and some small advanced economies

40:03

as well. Another thing to keep in

40:05

mind is fixed income markets, often the

40:07

exchange rate risk is hedged, right? Even

40:10

if we think about euro dollar kind

40:12

of transaction, so US dollar funds buying

40:14

euro bonds and the other way around.

40:16

Usually it's euro funds buying, you know,

40:18

US dollar fixing income assets. So if

40:21

you, for example. putting pressure on the

40:23

door coming from euro, right? European investors

40:25

are buying essentially US diagram and bonds,

40:27

but they're not doing it for carry

40:29

purposes, right? They just want to hold

40:32

their underlying return in dollars. Then they're

40:34

going to hedge the exchange rate risk.

40:36

So you're putting a upper patient on

40:38

the door coming from the fixed income

40:40

market, but then in the derivatives market

40:43

you're putting a pressure on the door

40:45

from the opposite direction, right? So it

40:47

ends up being neutral then because it's

40:49

currently hedged more close, right? Well with

40:51

equity markets usually there's no hedging. It's

40:54

currently unhed. Correct. That's why the causality...

40:56

It's my prior and we do have

40:58

some evidence that even if you have

41:00

like really exogenous calls of instruments that

41:02

you construct, right, of demand shocks, which

41:05

is not trivial to do, but you

41:07

know we've done some work and Helen

41:09

has done some work in the bus,

41:11

actually is going to go through equity

41:13

markets and also we do have another

41:16

paper studying the universe of effects derivatives

41:18

transactions in the UK. We're the first

41:20

to clean that massive data set and

41:22

indeed it is the case. That's what

41:24

we find. Fixing fixing. and not equity

41:27

funds, right? And when you go also

41:29

to pension funds, there's massive hedging, right?

41:31

They are truly hedging the effects risk.

41:33

And they are loaded on fixed income.

41:35

So that's why equity markets are more

41:38

interesting, in my opinion, when we study

41:40

effects, because that's where exogenous demand shocks

41:42

are not hedged and are putting the

41:44

pressure on the effects. And then importantly

41:46

you've come up with this global framework

41:49

to look at flows in a clever

41:51

way to see the transmission mechanism from

41:53

equities flows to FX which is very

41:55

clever and then equally on the on

41:57

the risk premium side. The way you've

42:00

looked at macro expectations and surprises by

42:02

looking at lagged versions of those variables

42:04

also shows, at least in sample, that

42:06

it tends to work quite well. So

42:08

this all fantastic work and I think

42:11

all of it as you say can

42:13

be applied for investors if people think

42:15

about it more carefully and and hopefully

42:17

at some point you'll be able to

42:19

reveal some of your your secret source

42:22

to us all. But before we sort

42:24

of round off I do like to

42:26

ask my guest something on just more

42:28

on the non-academic side you know one

42:30

is we do have some young people

42:33

listening to the podcast as well you

42:35

know many of them out at university

42:37

at the moment and many of them

42:39

will graduate this year or have graduated.

42:41

as they enter the post-university world? Or

42:44

maybe they should stay in university and

42:46

do PhDs. That's a challenging question in

42:48

an AI world. In a sense, to

42:50

be honest, what I'm hearing a lot

42:52

is I don't need to hire a

42:55

research system. I don't need to hire

42:57

a junior. So I mean, again, I

42:59

don't want to scare the young of

43:01

yours. I think one way to... differentiate

43:03

themselves and to kind of have a

43:06

successful career because I do believe it's

43:08

going to get more challenging to get

43:10

the nice jobs where you get to

43:12

work with someone more senior where you

43:14

can learn and be trained etc. The

43:17

business model will have to change. So

43:19

They clearly have to become experts on

43:21

how to utilize AI in their work,

43:23

but what I tell my NBA students

43:25

and in management students that are kind

43:28

of the younger group is that for

43:30

you to use AI effectively, you need

43:32

to be already an expert in something,

43:34

right? So in a sense, if you

43:36

go to child GPT and ask a

43:39

question, you know, to the extent that

43:41

the answer can be useful and, you

43:43

know, can add value to your work,

43:45

you need to understand what on earth.

43:47

actually chirgypity talking about, right? The more

43:50

interesting discussions with chaggypity are the higher

43:52

level discussions. So in a sense, clearly,

43:54

you know, your your viewers are kind

43:56

of the more driven and already, you

43:58

know, they don't need to be motivated

44:01

in this way. But the way I

44:03

would advise them is to learn from

44:05

academia, which is again the word I

44:07

come from, how they can take, exploit

44:09

the knowledge in academia and bring it

44:12

into finance in particular, right, in that

44:14

dimension. I think that in academia there

44:16

is 20 to 30% of the work

44:18

that's very exciting. Not everything is very

44:20

exciting. I'm not going to lie, right?

44:23

academia has its problems and there's a

44:25

lot of inertia but there is 20

44:27

to 30% of the research that I

44:29

would say is very exciting. The most

44:31

exciting research is big data but big

44:34

data what I mean by big data

44:36

in finance and economics is essentially taking

44:38

a theoretical model like what I did

44:40

here is simple accounting identity that is

44:42

coming out of theoretical models but then

44:45

going truly to an Iceland level right,

44:47

a granular level and aggregating from the

44:49

bottom up. What tends to work best

44:51

is aggregating from the bottom up. So

44:53

reading that kind of research, and there

44:56

is a lot of exciting stuff happening

44:58

now, right? So people are using not

45:00

just this holdings data, but you know,

45:02

some people have more, for example, the

45:04

universe of holdings in the fixed income

45:07

space, which is much much harder, because

45:09

clearly need the central banks, you need

45:11

all the market makers because of 40C

45:13

transactions, you can go only so far

45:15

with mutual funds. So that's a very

45:18

excited area of kind of research. The

45:20

propagation of news, right now the AI

45:22

technology allows us to any kind of

45:24

index using annum, right? So the propagation

45:26

of news and here not narrowly restricted

45:29

to macro surprises, which is let's say

45:31

CPI realization minus expectations, but some very

45:33

interesting research by some of my colleagues

45:35

actually in the fixed incomes place is

45:38

let's see how let's say fixed income

45:40

is prices are responding to updates in

45:42

the Congressional Budget Office estimates of the...

45:44

cost to the budget of whatever congressional

45:46

proposal there is. So we can now,

45:49

with the ability to scrape data easily,

45:51

and what I mean is now... even

45:53

young viewers can take advantage of that.

45:55

Like back in the day, I had

45:57

to hire a research assistant to write

46:00

the Python scraping code for me to

46:02

use it, right? Instead of me spending,

46:04

you know, months writing that code. Now

46:06

I can do that with charge you

46:08

between half a day, right? Which is

46:11

what I mean that people don't end

46:13

up hiring research assistance as a result.

46:15

But also that opens the possibility to

46:17

your viewers to go and experiment, right?

46:19

Even if they're not experts on on

46:22

Python coding. I would advise them to

46:24

invest in learning the theory. In particular

46:26

in finance, what's the frontier's intermediation-based asset

46:28

pricing theories? And, you know, they're going

46:30

to find what are the relevant sources

46:33

there, etc. So there's a lot of

46:35

exciting developments there, but if you know

46:37

the theory, then with charge APT that

46:39

is going to help you implement that

46:41

theory in Python, you have much more

46:44

power than someone that has just done

46:46

encoding. and they don't understand how to

46:48

think about financial markets. So they should

46:50

invest in understanding the frontier thinking about

46:52

what drives asset pricing. I think that's

46:55

the most valuable thing. The coding skills,

46:57

yes, you need to still clearly have

46:59

coding experience. Otherwise, even with Judge UPT,

47:01

you know, you can't use it in

47:03

a useful way. But you don't need

47:06

to have fusion computer scientists, right, to

47:08

be able to do incredibly meaningful big

47:10

data. kind of analysis in terms of

47:12

and it's going to be about big

47:14

data right yeah so now the way

47:17

the way I think about it anything

47:19

that is in a textual format can

47:21

be scraped so any if you think

47:23

about discretionary trading so we know that

47:25

inequity already it's about 30% is systematic,

47:28

right? Fixed income is less than that.

47:30

So inequity, the systematic to fundamental based

47:32

kind of, you go download the balance

47:34

sheet and read it, is kind of

47:36

what I think about fundamental based research.

47:39

Systematic is going to keep growing because

47:41

whatever the fundamental analysts are doing, you

47:43

can now automate a lot of that

47:45

analysis. So systematic is going to keep

47:47

growing and important. So being able to.

47:50

do big data, being able to think

47:52

about what is the right model, how

47:54

do you implement it, that is going

47:56

to be crucial going forward. Actually, my

47:58

mee forecast, who knows what I'm right

48:01

or not, but in 10 to 15

48:03

years, especially in the equity space, it's

48:05

going to be mostly systematic plus index

48:07

funds. Of course, ETFs and ETFs can

48:09

be on systematic as well as strategies.

48:12

But even with systematic, there will be

48:14

an overlay always of discretionary, right? How

48:16

much way do I put across systematic

48:18

strategies based on the signal? I think

48:20

that's where we're headed. So not knowing

48:23

big data, not knowing proper theory and

48:25

how to exploit it, because with big

48:27

data you can also introduce a lot

48:29

of noise if you don't know what

48:31

you're doing, right? So it is important

48:34

to start with the theory, the frontier

48:36

theory, and then bring the data. And

48:38

yeah, no, that's great advice. And then

48:40

finally, I just wanted to ask you,

48:42

what's the best way for people to

48:45

reach out to you or follow your

48:47

work, see your work? So my website

48:49

has essentially a lot of the papers

48:51

that we discussed and also there I

48:53

have my CV that is listing my

48:56

Gmail as well. Okay great. I'll include

48:58

a link to that on the show

49:00

notes as well. I'll link it in

49:02

and I'm easy to find. Great. No,

49:04

that's excellent. Yes, with that, you know,

49:07

thanks a lot for this fantastic discussion

49:09

and good luck with all the work

49:11

and especially good luck to the work

49:13

that you're doing on applying it to

49:15

investment strategies directly. You know, I'm quite

49:18

intrigued to see how that goes. So

49:20

yeah, once again, thanks a lot for

49:22

all of this discussion. Thank you so

49:24

much for having me. It's a pleasure.

49:26

Thanks for listening to the episode. Please

49:29

subscribe to the podcast show in Apple,

49:31

Spotify, or have you listened to podcast.

49:33

Leave a five-star rating, a nice comment,

49:35

and let other people know about the

49:37

show. We'll be very, very grateful. Finally,

49:40

sign up for a free newsletter at

49:42

macawive.com. We'll be back soon, so tune

49:44

in then.

Rate

Join Podchaser to...

  • Rate podcasts and episodes
  • Follow podcasts and creators
  • Create podcast and episode lists
  • & much more

Episode Tags

Do you host or manage this podcast?
Claim and edit this page to your liking.
,

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features