Episode Transcript
Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.
Use Ctrl + F to search
0:00
Today's episode is sponsored
0:02
by Trading 212. The
0:04
platform bringing commission-free investing
0:06
to everyone. National debt figures
0:08
are staggering, running to trillions of
0:11
pounds in the UK and tens
0:13
of trillions of dollars in the
0:15
US. Headlines were one of unsustainable
0:17
paths and ticking time bombs under
0:19
our economies. But is government debt
0:21
really out of control? I want
0:24
to know how we got buried
0:26
under this mountain of debt and
0:28
what the real risks are. And
0:30
in today's dumb question of the
0:32
week, we ask, is government debt
0:34
just like household debt only much
0:37
bigger? All right, let's get into
0:39
it. So this week, Roman, we're
0:41
going to be talking about things
0:43
which involve very big numbers in
0:45
the trillions. Now, I want to
0:47
avoid the trap where we go
0:49
big number equals scary. So I
0:52
think what we should do, if
0:54
we can, is always talk about
0:56
things as percentages of GDP, if
0:58
we can. Yeah, otherwise the numbers
1:00
just look crazy. You should always scale
1:02
it in terms of the size of
1:04
the economy. An economy that's 10 times
1:07
as big can maintain a level of
1:09
debt, which is 10 times larger. So let's
1:11
just get to it straight away then. How
1:14
big is the public debt in
1:16
the UK? So public sector net
1:18
debt and that excludes public sector
1:20
banks. That was estimated at
1:22
about 95.5% of GDP, gross
1:24
domestic product. And that was
1:27
for February 2025. So a little bit
1:29
under 100% of GDP. Should
1:31
we give some context to that?
1:33
Because it has risen sharply
1:35
over the past 25 years.
1:37
If we go back to the turn of the
1:40
Millennium, the year 2000, public debt
1:42
at that point was 28.3% of
1:44
GDP, and now we're at nearly 100.
1:47
And again, if you zoom out here,
1:49
I think it's useful, and go all
1:51
the way back to the 1700s. I
1:53
thought going back to the Millennium was
1:55
fair enough. We were turning the time
1:57
machine way back. But with the UK...
1:59
do that which is great but 2000
2:02
was very much a low point in
2:04
debt to GDP for the UK just
2:06
prior to that well I say just
2:09
about 50 years prior to that just
2:11
after World War II that's when we
2:13
reached our all-time high for debt to
2:16
GDP there it peaked at just over
2:18
250% briefly and after World War I
2:20
it peaked at about just under 200%
2:23
so Clearly, times of crisis, when you
2:25
really have to raise a lot of
2:27
taxes, raise a lot of income and
2:30
spend it, those are the periods in
2:32
time when government really splurges out and
2:34
issues lots of debt and pushes up
2:37
debt to GDP. You promised me the
2:39
1700s. Keep going. Okay, so another peak
2:41
was just after the Napoleonic War. Clearly
2:44
we had to pay for that. Then
2:46
we had the American War of Independence.
2:48
Before that. the seven years war, the
2:50
war of the Austrian succession, and each
2:53
of these had its own little peak
2:55
which built up and built up to
2:57
a crescendo of the Napoleonic Wars when
3:00
debt to GDP reached about 200% again.
3:02
But then if we go further back
3:04
in time, all the way back to
3:07
1,700 debt to GDP was tiny. It
3:09
was only about 25% and the first
3:11
thing that really pushed us up the
3:14
hill was the war of the Spanish
3:16
succession. Seems like there's a lot of
3:18
wars in British history if we're looking
3:21
at the debt to GDP ratio. But
3:23
the reason why we won those wars
3:25
was that we were very good at
3:28
issuing debt, at least that's one argument.
3:30
But we're not fighting a war right
3:32
now, so how has debt gone from
3:35
just under 30% of GDP in the
3:37
year 2000 to almost 100% now? Well
3:39
that's why it hasn't gone to 200%
3:42
probably, but we have had COVID, which
3:44
is kind of like a war against
3:46
a virus, so I'd argue that something
3:49
like a pandemic would also count as
3:51
something which is going to push up
3:53
to GDP. Any kind of big crisis
3:56
we have to spend a lot. We
3:58
did spend a lot through COVID on
4:00
furlough and on healthcare costs. And of
4:02
course before that we had the global
4:05
financial crisis, which really cost a lot
4:07
in terms of bank bailouts and stimulus
4:09
packages. And of course growth, because if
4:12
you're comparing debt to GDP, if GDP
4:14
is weak and debt to GDP is
4:16
going to go up. And it has
4:19
to be said in the past, whenever
4:21
we've actually reduced our debt to GDP,
4:23
So this was following the Napoleonic War
4:26
and following World War II, the way
4:28
that number's fallen is because GDP growth
4:30
has been more rapid than debt growth.
4:33
Yeah, we've grown our way out of
4:35
it to some extent and inflated our
4:37
way out a little bit. Yeah. And
4:40
here I think it's worth being clear
4:42
about the difference between the national debt
4:44
and the deficit, because you hear a
4:47
lot in the media about the deficit,
4:49
and I guess that is the engine
4:51
by which the debt grows. Yeah, so
4:54
this is the distinction between levels and
4:56
flows. The deficit is what makes debt
4:58
grow because you plug the difference between
5:01
tax income and expenditure by issuing debt,
5:03
and then the level of debt grows
5:05
if the deficit is continually large. And
5:07
at the moment, the deficit in the
5:10
UK, which is called public sector net
5:12
borrowing, is around £137 billion this year.
5:14
which is 4.8% of GDP and is
5:17
too high to be sustainable in the
5:19
long run really. Now the Office for
5:21
Budget Responsibility issued a report last week
5:24
alongside the spring statement which showed that
5:26
based on the government's spending plans and
5:28
tax plans and its assumptions around growth
5:31
and things like that, it expects the
5:33
deficit to fall to 2.1% of GDP
5:35
by the end of this parliament in
5:38
2030. So it's fair to say this
5:40
government takes debt to GDP very seriously.
5:42
They haven't splurged on spending and they're
5:45
very keen on getting debt to GDP
5:47
under control. Now if we turn our
5:49
attention to the US, obviously the numbers
5:52
are much bigger there because it's much
5:54
bigger country. they're experiencing a kind of
5:56
similar thing to the UK where deficits
5:59
are very large by historic standards and
6:01
debt has been rising fast. So for
6:03
the United States it depends how you
6:06
measure it but if you look at
6:08
what the CBO recommends which is federal
6:10
debt held by the public as a
6:13
percentage of GDP that's just a shade
6:15
under a hundred percent it's 97 percent.
6:17
So a similar ballpark to the UK
6:19
really? Yeah it's not very different at
6:22
all. Now you might see a lot
6:24
of people quote the gross federal debt.
6:26
which is the broadest measure of debt
6:29
and that's much higher that's around 123%
6:31
of GDP in the US. But as
6:33
you say the CBO thinks that's not
6:36
the best measure of debt because it
6:38
includes debt that's held by the government
6:40
itself and that is generally through schemes
6:43
like social security and retirement programs and
6:45
Medicare where they invest in treasuries themselves
6:47
so it's the government kind of owing
6:50
itself money. And I think we should
6:52
probably mention what the CBO is. It's
6:54
the Congressional Budget Office. Now this is
6:57
a non-partisan organisation in the United States.
6:59
It was set up by a congressional
7:01
act in 1974. And the idea is
7:04
that it provides objective non-partisan information to
7:06
support the congressional budget process. Yeah, and
7:08
handily they issued their latest report last
7:11
week, much like the OBR in the
7:13
UK, and they project forward. What's going
7:15
to happen to the US deficit and
7:18
the US debt over the next 30
7:20
years? And crucially, they do that on
7:22
the basis of what is the law
7:24
at the moment. We can talk about
7:27
this in a second. I think that's
7:29
a problematic way of doing it. But
7:31
whenever you look at their projections, it's
7:34
always quite alarming. Sure is. So when
7:36
I looked at it this time, it
7:38
said, by 2055, federal debt held by
7:41
the public will reach 156% of GDP
7:43
and remain on track to increase thereafter.
7:45
If you look at the graph, it's
7:48
a scary graph, it's steep, isn't it?
7:50
Yeah, it starts at 100 today, and
7:52
then it just seems to grow. a
7:55
fairly linear fashion all the way up
7:57
to 2055. And as you'd expect, the
7:59
reason the debt keeps growing throughout the
8:02
period is because deficits are baked in
8:04
across the period based on current law.
8:06
So over the next 30 years, the
8:09
CBO estimates the deficit to be 6.3%
8:11
of GDP, which is more than one
8:13
and a half times the average over
8:16
the last 50 years. And that larger
8:18
deficit... is primarily being driven by an
8:20
increase in interest costs as the US
8:23
has to service its debt, but also
8:25
increased spending on healthcare programs like Medicare,
8:27
social securities, you've got an aging population,
8:30
and actually trend growth which is weaker
8:32
than it's been over the last 50
8:34
years on average. And again, if you
8:36
look at that history of fiscal deficit
8:39
for the United States, currently it's pretty
8:41
large, it's about 6.3%. But it's been
8:43
gradually getting larger since 2000. It's just
8:46
government after government, Republican or Democrat, has
8:48
been gradually increasing how much the government
8:50
spends without taxes paying for it and
8:53
then plugging the difference with debt. Now
8:55
when interest rates were pretty much zero
8:57
since 2007, that wasn't such a big
9:00
problem because the debt servicing cost was
9:02
small. But now that we're starting to
9:04
see interest rates pick up back to
9:07
normal, it's a big problem. For example,
9:09
a lot of people quote the fact
9:11
that the US is spending more on
9:14
debt servicing than it is on defence.
9:16
And that is unusual. If you go
9:18
back before 1990, the fiscal deficit was
9:21
much smaller. It's only when you go
9:23
back to the Second World War that
9:25
you see a really huge fiscal deficit
9:28
when it ballooned out beyond 25%. I
9:30
found that that surprising that the US
9:32
is spending around a trillion dollars a
9:35
year on interest, give or take. and
9:37
the defense budget is something like 850
9:39
billion dollars. Yeah, spending more just servicing
9:42
its debt than it is on tanks
9:44
and fighter jets, some missile systems and
9:46
all that stuff which we associate with
9:48
US federal. spending. But can I just
9:51
say that one of the side effects
9:53
of a fiscal deficit is government bonds?
9:55
And I love government bonds. In my
9:58
world, it's my happy place. Obviously too
10:00
much government debt, not such a happy
10:02
place. So within reason, I think having
10:05
a deficit is okay. And in fact,
10:07
it's probably normal. And it's probably good.
10:09
But when it gets out of control,
10:12
which is the topic of today's podcast,
10:14
that's the real problem. Yeah, Robin, you're
10:16
not a price insensitive buyer, are you?
10:19
You have to look at the market
10:21
and make a judgment call. I do
10:23
look at the yields, yeah, yeah. But
10:26
the thing is, you've got tens of
10:28
trillions of debt in the US. It
10:30
can run a surplus for quite a
10:33
while and they'll still be plenty of
10:35
treas for you to buy as they
10:37
roll them over. That's right, that's right.
10:40
I mean, they've got to issue new
10:42
stuff because it does mature, but there
10:44
is a kind of servicing bonds. But
10:47
it's fair to say a lot of
10:49
people like bonds. And they are a
10:51
mainstay of balance sheets across the world.
10:53
But who holds all this debt? So
10:56
the outstanding debt, US Treasuries, at the
10:58
moment is about $36 trillion. And two-thirds
11:00
of that is held by US citizens.
11:03
Now that's not really a problem because
11:05
if you're a US citizen, presumably you
11:07
don't want to scup your own government
11:10
by selling their debt. You don't want
11:12
to destabilise your own country. And when
11:14
you say US citizens, you're including institutions
11:17
like pension funds and insurers and all
11:19
of that stuff in there as well.
11:21
Exactly. Institutions probably hold more than retail
11:24
investors. I'm not sure what that split
11:26
is for the US. But what's perhaps
11:28
more worrying are the non-US holders of
11:31
that debt, which makes up one-third of
11:33
the holdings. Now people have referred to
11:35
this as the kindness of strangers. And
11:38
of course, you can't rely on that
11:40
kindness. particularly if you are not being
11:42
very kind to them. For example, Japan
11:45
holds about just over a trillion dollars
11:47
of that debt, China holds... 761 billion,
11:49
UK 740 billion, Luxembourg weirdly, 410 billion,
11:52
given it's essentially a tiny country, but
11:54
of course that's often financial institutions buying
11:56
US debt. Yeah, tracing the debt is
11:59
never an easy task, is it? Otherwise
12:01
it looks like the Cayman Islands is
12:03
one of the biggest holders of US
12:05
debt. Yeah, they hold 404 billion. Which
12:08
on a per capita basis is insane.
12:10
and Belgium our favourite country 378 billion.
12:12
Some of that's China actually rooted through
12:15
Belgium. But another big holder of US
12:17
federal debt is of course the Federal
12:19
Reserve. Its various quantitative easing schemes over
12:22
the last 20 years have in effect
12:24
meant buying treasuries and boosting the size
12:26
of the central bank balance sheet. But
12:29
here we get to an interesting question
12:31
of... Is that really debt? Or is
12:33
it a kind of accounting trick on
12:36
the national balance sheets where you've printed
12:38
money to buy your own debt? It
12:40
is odd, isn't it? And you get
12:43
into all sorts of circular arguments about
12:45
whether it's real debt or not, whether
12:47
it's effectively been retired. Legally it hasn't
12:50
been retired. Yeah. And they are winding
12:52
it down. Now, quantitative tightening is important
12:54
because you can see that if you
12:57
measure the US Treasury securities securities securities
12:59
securities, the holdings by the Fed. for
13:01
treasuries. That peaked at 5.8 trillion and
13:04
that was in roughly the summer the
13:06
spring of 2022 and it's been falling
13:08
fairly sharply since. So currently it's about
13:10
4.2 trillion. So it's diminishing but the
13:13
rate of decrease has recently slowed because
13:15
the feds slowed down its QT programme
13:17
for treasuries at least. And a similar
13:20
thing seems to be playing out in
13:22
the UK where in fact the Bank
13:24
of England is actually selling. some of
13:27
its guilt holdings on the open market,
13:29
somewhat controversially, and is charging the UK
13:31
treasury money every year now because it's
13:34
selling at a loss. This is all
13:36
a weird accounting trick as you say
13:38
but it does mean that the government
13:41
and I guess the taxpayer by extension
13:43
has to find a bit of extra
13:45
money every year at the moment. UK
13:48
government yeah whereas in the US they
13:50
don't actually sell them they just wait
13:52
for them to mature and roll off
13:55
as they call it. But if you
13:57
accept that this is all a bit
13:59
of a weird fiction in a way
14:02
you can look at a measure like
14:04
public sector net debt excluding the bank
14:06
of England. which is obviously lower than
14:09
the actual day. It's more like 90%
14:11
rather than the 95 point something percent
14:13
we talked about earlier. But interestingly, the
14:16
OBR forecasts that by the end of
14:18
the Parliament, those things will have both
14:20
converged at around 95% of GDP as
14:22
the Bank of England ends its term
14:25
funding scheme and asset purchase facility, which
14:27
is what you'd expect, right? Yes, a
14:29
normalisation to the pre-crisis state of affairs.
14:32
Now clearly what you want to avoid
14:34
as a government is having to spend
14:36
a huge amount servicing your debt because
14:39
that's money that you can't spend on
14:41
all the other things that a government
14:43
needs to run the country. So if
14:46
we look at the UK for example
14:48
the total spending is just under 1.3
14:50
trillion pounds a year of which 105
14:53
billion was the debt interest. Yeah so
14:55
about 4.3% of GDP was spent on
14:57
debt interest. in 2223, which is a
15:00
post-war high. Now, the OBI expects that
15:02
to decline a little bit in the
15:04
coming years, but not hugely. It's going
15:07
to be around 4% maybe a little
15:09
bit lower by the end of the
15:11
Parliament. And I guess crucially, we are
15:14
spending a lot more on debt interest
15:16
than we used to. So in the
15:18
10 years before the pandemic, the cost
15:21
of servicing the national debt was around
15:23
2% of GDP on average. So, you
15:25
know, we're more than twice that at
15:28
the moment. So until quite recently the
15:30
UK issued a lot of inflation link
15:32
debt. Now the way those work is
15:34
that they increase their principal value increases
15:37
as does their coupon in line with
15:39
our And when RPI inflation zoomed up
15:41
above 10% that pushed up the principal
15:44
values of those notes, of that debt.
15:46
Now that's not something that reverses. It
15:48
carries on being expensive until those bonds
15:51
mature. So that was a real problem
15:53
for the UK. A lot of historical
15:55
inflation make debt, which is more expensive
15:58
to service. And relative to other countries,
16:00
we issued a lot more of this
16:02
stuff because our life insurers love it.
16:05
For the rest of the debt, which
16:07
is nominal, that wasn't an issue, it
16:09
wasn't about inflation increasing. Really the problem
16:12
there is that there's just more debt
16:14
outstanding and because yields are higher, as
16:16
that debt's rolled over, the government's having
16:19
to pay more to service those bonds.
16:21
So all in all, a pretty much
16:23
perfect storm for the UK government. So
16:26
the picture overall, I think you could
16:28
summarize in the UK and to an
16:30
extent in the US, is that debt
16:33
has been rising extremely fast, extremely fast.
16:35
since the financial crisis. Deficits are persistent
16:37
and governments don't seem to be able
16:39
to close them. And yields have gone
16:42
up. And markets are a little bit
16:44
nervous, I guess you could say, now
16:46
they're looking at this step. I'm saying,
16:49
is it sustainable? So I guess when
16:51
we come back from the break, the
16:53
question will be, is the doubt of
16:56
control and is it dangerous? Trading 212
16:58
stocks and shares ISA is the cheapest
17:00
way to invest, with zero commission and
17:03
the lowest FX fees I could find
17:05
on the market. Looking to keep things
17:07
simple, you can easily automate your investing
17:10
with pies that allow you to rebalance
17:12
your portfolio at the click of a
17:14
button. Customers with Invest accounts can also
17:17
benefit from the Trading 212 card, which
17:19
has no FX fees, true interbank rates
17:21
and offers 0.5% cash back on all
17:24
transactions up to 20 pounds per month.
17:26
Many happy returns listeners can claim free
17:28
fractional shares worth up to a hundred
17:31
pounds. Just create and verify a trading
17:33
2-1-2 invest or stock-sicer account, make a
17:35
minimum deposit of a pound, and use
17:38
the promo code, Roman, R-A-M-I-N, within 10
17:40
days of signing up or use the
17:42
link in the show notes. When investing
17:45
your capital is at risk and you
17:47
may get back less than invested. Past
17:49
performance doesn't guarantee future results. Pies and
17:51
Auto Invest is an execution only service,
17:54
not investment advice or portfolio portfolio management.
17:56
Automatic investing refers to executing schedule deposits.
17:58
You're responsible for all investment and rebalancing
18:01
decisions. Free shares can be fractional. 2.2
18:03
cards are issued by Paynetics which provide
18:05
all payment services. Trading 2.2 provides customer
18:08
support and user interface. Terms and fees
18:10
apply. All right, Roman, so we've got
18:12
this debt pile. It's roughly the size
18:15
of the economy and growing. How dangerous
18:17
is it? I think debts a little
18:19
bit like chocolate in the sense that
18:22
as long as you don't have too
18:24
much, it's kind of okay. In small
18:26
quantities, it's absolutely fine and it makes
18:29
things better. But the problem really comes
18:31
when it really starts to create a
18:33
lopsided economy where debt servicing becomes a
18:36
really big factor. So for example, if
18:38
you're spending a lot on debt servicing
18:40
costs, you're not going to spend it
18:43
on public services, on infrastructure, and that
18:45
can be a problem for future growth
18:47
for future growth. And in order to
18:50
get rid of it, you may have
18:52
to increase taxes. And of course, nobody
18:54
likes that. So it's very politically unpopular.
18:57
And usually you might expect it to
18:59
lead to the change of government, because
19:01
nobody's going to vote for a government
19:03
which has hugely hyped up taxes. And
19:06
of course all those things have growth
19:08
impacts, don't they? So I guess if
19:10
you've got rising debt, it often comes
19:13
with higher yields, and that increases borrowing
19:15
costs across the economy, not just for
19:17
the government. It means businesses. are going
19:20
to be charged more to borrow and
19:22
invest, which should slow growth or else.
19:24
being equal. I guess you could say
19:27
it's also potentially crowding out business investment
19:29
because the government is on the markets
19:31
competing for capital with more debt issuance
19:34
against corporate bonds. So corporate bonds look
19:36
less attractive. Yeah I think all of
19:38
that's true. And of course if you've
19:41
got less margins for companies, lower margins,
19:43
that means less profit growth and it's
19:45
going to be bad for the equity
19:48
market. So all in all, not a
19:50
great thing. And I think one thing
19:52
which I worry about more with high
19:55
debt is that we've talked about how
19:57
debt often jumps up when you have
19:59
a crisis, a war, a pandemic, a
20:02
financial crisis, whatever it is. Those things
20:04
seem to happen fairly regularly and I
20:06
often think there's not much you can
20:08
do about some of those things. So
20:11
we'll probably get another crisis at some
20:13
point. Does it give us less room
20:15
to act in the next crisis? Yeah,
20:18
for example after World War I in
20:20
the UK. the debt hadn't fully got
20:22
back to normal. In fact, it was
20:25
nowhere near back to normal before the
20:27
next one. And going back even further,
20:29
we were talking about the 1700s and
20:32
1800s. Well, there was just war after
20:34
war. And after each one, the debt
20:36
built up, and it never really got
20:39
a chance to fall. So I think
20:41
you're right. I think that now we've
20:43
got less capacity for a future crisis,
20:46
whether it's a pandemic or whether it's
20:48
another war. It's interesting, isn't it, reading
20:50
through these reports from the OBR and
20:53
the UK and the CBO in the
20:55
US. They make all these projections going
20:57
forward, you know, 30, 40 years. And
21:00
everything follows a neat orderly course where
21:02
the deficits are kind of the same
21:04
as they are now into the future.
21:07
And yeah, it makes the debt look
21:09
really bad. But to me, I was
21:11
saying, oh, that's kind of a best
21:14
case, right? The world seems to throw
21:16
problems at us, which means that we
21:18
then have to suddenly spend another 20%
21:20
of GDP, bailing everything out. But I
21:23
think we're lucky that we can do
21:25
that because in the past, whenever we've
21:27
needed to, we've been able to. And
21:30
that's why I think it's really important
21:32
that the UK is a credible borrower.
21:34
If we were some country which really
21:37
didn't care about debt to GDP, then
21:39
when these crises do occur, at least
21:41
the people who give us the money
21:44
can be fairly confident that they will
21:46
get paid back. Whereas if you're Argentina,
21:48
that's a much harder case to make.
21:51
I mean, we'd never defaulted on our
21:53
debt, have we, in the UK? Well,
21:55
there was some close shaves and technical
21:58
ones, but... Not really, not for a
22:00
long time. Don't scare the horses from
22:02
it. We've never defaulted. I loved it
22:05
in the UK. No, the Middle Ages,
22:07
we were serial defaulters. But look, that
22:09
was a long time ago. But it's
22:12
good to know that we would have
22:14
the capacity to increase our debt to
22:16
GDP to 200% as we did in
22:19
previous wars. And that would give us
22:21
three trillion pounds to spend to defend
22:23
ourselves. Do we though? Why did Liz
22:25
truss come a croper so quickly if
22:28
we've got that capacity? No, seriously though.
22:30
Is it because we weren't in a
22:32
crisis? I think that was the issue,
22:35
and it was a period of high
22:37
inflation, and it just seemed economically literate
22:39
what she did. I guess the thing
22:42
is, if a crisis comes along, like
22:44
COVID, and the world's panicking, and markets
22:46
are panicking, markets, I guess, are rushing
22:49
out of risky assets like stocks, and
22:51
whatever, and piling into perceived safe assets
22:53
like guilt. So it may be constrains
22:56
yields at the time you're trying to
22:58
borrow a lot more. As if you
23:00
try and do the outside of a
23:03
crisis, you don't have that same benefit
23:05
of flows. Yeah, when the economy was
23:07
effectively healing and it was a period
23:10
of high inflation, and if you issue
23:12
lots of debt and have unfunded tax
23:14
cuts at the same time, well, that's
23:17
just kind of crazy. The problem would
23:19
be if we have a crisis which
23:21
is UK specific. There's no global rush
23:24
into safe assets. It's just, uh-oh, we're
23:26
trying to issue a lot of dare
23:28
at the same time as our yields
23:31
are rising. Yeah, that wouldn't be so
23:33
good. But could we get one of
23:35
these crises of confidence from the market?
23:37
the so-called bond vigilantes rising up just
23:40
because they feel that the debt is
23:42
on an unsustainable path. I think it's
23:44
unlikely for the UK and I think
23:47
it's unlikely for the US as well
23:49
unless there are some obviously crazy signals
23:51
coming from the government or just signs
23:54
that the government doesn't care. They don't
23:56
care about debt to GDP because they
23:58
assume that people will just carry on
24:01
buying their debt regardless of whatever they
24:03
do. I think that's the situation in
24:05
the US right now. I don't think
24:08
either party really cares about debt to
24:10
GDP. You see talk of slashing federal
24:12
spending, you know, Elon Musk's doge has
24:15
been tasked with going around finding cuts.
24:17
He doesn't seem to be finding anything
24:19
significant. At the same time they're talking
24:22
about massive tax cuts. So the interesting
24:24
thing actually is this CBO report is
24:26
predicated on the basis that the laws
24:29
stay the same. Now, that's interesting, like
24:31
what to stay the same mean, because
24:33
what you've got baked in in the
24:36
US tax system is things that expire.
24:38
So Trump instituted massive tax cuts in
24:40
2017 in this first term, which are
24:43
due to expire in the next few
24:45
years. And the CBO projections assume that
24:47
they will expire and not be renewed,
24:49
yet obviously Trump wants to renew them.
24:52
He doesn't want to raise taxes from
24:54
where they are now, and he wants
24:56
to bring in further tax cuts. So
24:59
the CBO projections to me... I like
25:01
downside projections to the debt. I agree
25:03
and I think if the Trump administration
25:06
does carry on with its extension of
25:08
those tax cuts and does produce more
25:10
of them, well it'll be really interesting
25:13
to see what the CBO forecast looks
25:15
like then, unless of course they shut
25:17
down the CBO, which would be one
25:20
really neat solution to that problem. Probably
25:22
doesn't help you with rising yields though
25:24
if you shut down the statistics. Flying
25:27
Blind is not something investors welcome, but
25:29
if you think about it. the US
25:31
is running chunky deficits of six or
25:34
seven percent of GDP. If those go
25:36
higher again because of further tax cuts
25:38
and all the other problems you've got
25:41
with the aging population and lower trend
25:43
growth. Surely there comes a point where
25:45
the market goes, hang on, you can't
25:48
do this. If the deficit got to
25:50
10% and above on a consistent basis,
25:52
the debt just goes exponential. Yeah, there
25:54
is a certain point at which you
25:57
cross the debt Rubicon and essentially things
25:59
get completely out of control. I think
26:01
the US is far from that. I
26:04
think there are enough people who are
26:06
sensible in Congress who... push back on
26:08
it and probably stop it happening. But
26:11
look, ultimately, if markets were worried about
26:13
debt sustainability, seriously worried in the United
26:15
States, then yields with spike and there'd
26:18
be a huge crisis. I guess that
26:20
takes us to a question of what
26:22
are the possible paths from here to
26:25
deal with the problem if it is
26:27
a problem. So I had a thing
26:29
and came up with five possible paths,
26:32
which I want to run by E.
26:34
Roman. The one you hinted out there,
26:36
I've called The Shock, which is that
26:39
a market scare forces drastic action to
26:41
solve the deficit. Like, taxes go up
26:43
and spending gets slashed immediately just because
26:46
yield to blowing out and markets force
26:48
government's hand. That's the most extreme of
26:50
these situations, I say. The second one,
26:53
which is less dramatic, I've just called
26:55
the grind upwards. So this is slow
26:57
growth. High debt is persisting, taxes maybe
27:00
go up a little bit, spending gets
27:02
squeezed a little bit, the economy struggles,
27:04
but it's not catastrophic, and I would
27:06
call this kind of a Japanification of
27:09
the economy, we just muddle through. You
27:11
kind of see that happening over the
27:13
last decade in the United States. They
27:16
have been muddling through, the deficits been
27:18
consistently large, and debt to GDP has
27:20
been gradually rising. So that has been
27:23
the grind upwards. And this isn't to
27:25
say it's consequence free. Some people would
27:27
say you're harming future generations, right, by
27:30
spending beyond your means now as a
27:32
government, but maybe let's put a pin
27:34
in that and come back to it.
27:37
The third possible path I've called austerity
27:39
returns, so this is where we do
27:41
get... sharp spending cuts, Elon Musk finds
27:44
old apartments to take out in the
27:46
US, he slashes Medicare, he slashes Social
27:48
Security, and the debt is reduced in
27:51
the medium term, but the government bears
27:53
quite a lot of political pain and
27:55
I guess growth suffers at the same
27:58
time. Oh yeah, that wouldn't be without
28:00
consequences, political as well, because remember all
28:02
of these changes come with their own
28:05
pushback from the electorate. To me this
28:07
is an unlikely. path because I think
28:09
the political pain is too great. As
28:11
much as Republicans might want to cut
28:14
social spending, I think a lot of
28:16
their base rely on social security and
28:18
Medicare. Yeah, if the spending cuts are
28:21
too sharp, then remember that government spending
28:23
actually does stimulate the economy. So if
28:25
it's too severe, that could itself cause
28:28
problems. And we're already seeing this in
28:30
red states where, for example, a large
28:32
proportion of the government spending has been
28:35
cut. in particular areas which are very
28:37
painful and that hasn't gone down well
28:39
locally. Yeah there's a political cost and
28:42
I also think there's just an economic
28:44
question of can you actually bring debt
28:46
under control through austerity measures if they're
28:49
too harsh the effect on growth might
28:51
be too big and it's like a
28:53
self-defeating policy. Anyway let's move on to
28:56
the fourth possible path forward which I've
28:58
called inflate away and this is the
29:00
idea that the government has this huge
29:03
debt and it thinks huh Maybe if
29:05
I let inflation just run a little
29:07
hot for the next 10 to 20
29:10
years, the real value of that debt
29:12
will fall as a percentage of GDP.
29:14
I think the problem with that one
29:17
is that the government can't really control
29:19
inflation. They can have certain policies which
29:21
make inflation higher, but making it a
29:23
little bit higher and not a lot
29:26
higher is actually very difficult. Just look
29:28
at the Fed's problems getting inflation under
29:30
control. Plus they'd have to talk to
29:33
the Fed. in order to let that
29:35
happen. You can change the mandate right?
29:37
You could say... or if the inflation
29:40
target is 4% now for the next
29:42
10 years. But just think what that
29:44
would do to US debt, it would
29:47
make a massive difference to the valuation
29:49
of US debt, it would make a
29:51
change to the way companies are run,
29:54
it would be a huge shock if
29:56
you double the inflation target. So I
29:58
just don't buy that as a credible
30:01
way of doing it. And if they
30:03
try to do it secretly again, I'm
30:05
not convinced that the government is competent
30:08
enough to cover that up. Even if
30:10
they could pull it off. It's a
30:12
stealth tax on savers effectively, isn't it?
30:15
It's eroding the real value of savings
30:17
to fund the government by the backdoor.
30:19
An inflation is so politically unpopular. Just
30:22
look at all of the discourse about
30:24
egg prices in the United States. It's
30:26
incredible. The amount of pushback, that's generated.
30:29
And you just amplify that by a
30:31
factor of 10 if they suddenly say,
30:33
oh, we're telling the Fed to double
30:35
its inflation target. Have you seen that
30:38
the Trump administration seems to be going...
30:40
one by one around the European countries
30:42
asking for extra egg imports. And they
30:45
keep getting turned down Denmark's like no,
30:47
no, go away. Belgium says no, get
30:49
your own eggs. This is like the
30:52
kindness of strangers, right, in microcosm, around
30:54
eggs rather than deficit funding. And if
30:56
relations with those countries were good, maybe
30:59
they could have talked them around. But
31:01
this is hardly what I described as
31:03
a charming government. No, and I think
31:06
we've also moved away from a... international
31:08
order based on rules to one where
31:10
it's all made by deals effectively. And
31:13
I don't know what that effect that
31:15
has long term on capital flows, but
31:17
anyway, that's a whole other problem. Let's
31:20
go to the final path forward I've
31:22
identified, which is an optimistic one that
31:24
I've called the growth miracle. And here,
31:27
the idea is the debt comes well
31:29
under control just because productivity booms in
31:31
the coming years. And maybe that's because
31:34
of AI or something else. But the
31:36
idea is that economic growth is so
31:38
hot. that the debt becomes trivial. In
31:40
an ideal world, that's the way you
31:43
grow your way out of debt, is
31:45
to have a pickup and GDP. Now
31:47
can I just say there is another
31:50
sixth path which is a debt default?
31:52
So you do get the government suddenly
31:54
saying look you know how we owed
31:57
you what 36 trillion dollars? Well if
31:59
you're a foreign country we're not going
32:01
to pay you a penny. Now would
32:04
that be a problem? Yeah it would
32:06
be hugely disruptive for markets but under
32:08
this new approach where anything goes who
32:11
knows maybe there will be some kind
32:13
of forcing of governments. to accept a
32:15
write-down on US debt, their treasury holdings.
32:18
All bets are off in that situation,
32:20
I reckon. Who knows what's safe and
32:22
what's not? Well, it was part of
32:25
the Maralago thing, which is that the
32:27
governments would willingly swap their US treasuries,
32:29
coupon-paying treasuries, with a fixed maturity date,
32:32
with century bonds, which has zero coupon,
32:34
which is a default. Yeah. Now that's
32:36
not taken seriously, it's not going to
32:39
be policy, but it is something that's
32:41
being considered being considered. All right, so
32:43
let's nail our colors to the mask
32:46
then. We've got six scenarios. You've added
32:48
one. We've got the shock, the grind
32:50
upwards, austerity returns, inflate away, the growth
32:52
miracle, or default doom. What path do
32:55
you think we're on? I think the
32:57
US is on the grind upwards, because
32:59
clearly the government currently doesn't care about
33:02
deficits. It's unlikely that a Democrat government
33:04
would either. So I'd say, yeah, that
33:06
will probably continue. In the UK, certainly
33:09
at the moment, it seems as if
33:11
we've got kind of austerity returns, where
33:13
we've got a government which is really
33:16
cutting back on spending, certainly the day-to-day
33:18
spending, and does care about debt to
33:20
GDP, so they're trying to get the
33:23
deficit under control as well. But it's
33:25
not great for growth. What concerns me
33:27
is that the UK may move to
33:30
a more populist flavor of government. If
33:32
you look at reform in the polls,
33:34
it's certainly shot up. Who knows what
33:37
they'll do when it comes to managing
33:39
the managing the debt? I think you're
33:41
right about both those things, but that
33:44
in the next 30 years... we are
33:46
going to see either the shock or
33:48
the growth miracle. Eventually, at some point,
33:51
who knows where it is, debt becomes
33:53
a problem, and we either get bailed
33:55
out by AI or we don't. Well,
33:58
you're assuming that it will come to
34:00
some kind of head, but what about
34:02
Japan? Japan is way out there in
34:04
terms of debt to GDP. It's at
34:07
something like 250 percent. But life goes
34:09
on in Japan. Economically, they're okay. Not
34:11
incredibly powerful as an economy now as
34:14
they used to be. The growth hasn't
34:16
been phenomenal. And that's despite the huge
34:18
demographic problems, the fact that other countries
34:21
are taking their export mantle away from
34:23
them, and it hasn't come to a
34:25
head. No, you're right. It hasn't, at
34:28
least not yet. There are some differences
34:30
with Japan though. Like they have a
34:32
very high domestic savings rate compared to
34:35
the US and the UK. And I
34:37
guess you could argue that the bank
34:39
of Japan has somewhat monetized its debt.
34:42
And I think it has a lot
34:44
less debt held by foreign investors. But
34:46
you're right, I guess it shows that
34:49
high debt isn't automatically fatal. But then
34:51
yields are starting to creep up in
34:53
Japan. At this point, by design, they
34:56
want higher interest rates and they want
34:58
a bit of inflation to return. But
35:00
let's hope they can keep that manageable,
35:03
right? You don't want debt to be
35:05
250% of GDP. from negative to positive
35:07
to very very positive. Yeah that would
35:09
be catastrophic for Japan. I mean if
35:12
you were the government now in the
35:14
UK say what could they do? What
35:16
should they do? It seems to me
35:19
there's no easy fixes there's just tradeoffs
35:21
involved. Yeah and as a politician you're
35:23
always thinking about whether you'll get reelected
35:26
which makes you avoid doing the difficult
35:28
things which is to raise taxes and
35:30
to reduce spending. And I think that's
35:33
not going to be something that any
35:35
government is going to do lightly. I
35:37
think a lot of what the current
35:40
government and the previous one were trying
35:42
to do is good, which is to
35:44
boost growth, because ultimately that's what reduces
35:47
debt to GDP. That's the solution. That's
35:49
the way out of the problem. It's
35:51
true. Everyone's preferred option is to boost
35:54
growth, but it's hard to achieve, right?
35:56
And it requires smart investment and long-term
35:58
policy planning and perhaps short-term pain. It's
36:01
just hard to get that going, or
36:03
it seems to have been. So what
36:05
you end up with is this kind
36:08
of technocratic managerial style of government, where
36:10
you've got fiscal rules, which you're trying
36:12
to micromanage your way through. Sometimes... the
36:15
tail is wagging the dog and you're
36:17
looking at the projections from the OBR
36:19
which are clouded in uncertainty and they
36:21
admit that and you're tweaking spending cuts
36:24
and tax rises based on these very
36:26
uncertain forecasts and I think the government
36:28
in the UK probably is quite constrained
36:31
for maneuver here. Taxes as a share
36:33
of GDP are at a post-war high
36:35
of more than 35% and are scheduled
36:38
to rise to almost 38% in the
36:40
coming years and that's already... four and
36:42
a half percentage points higher than the
36:45
pre-pandemic level taxes as a share of
36:47
GDP. And also, as you hinted at
36:49
earlier, they are making cuts to welfare
36:52
spending and to departmental spending outside of
36:54
protected areas, but still public spending is
36:56
high. It's forecasted to 45% of GDP
36:59
next year, which is much higher than
37:01
it's been in recent decades. It all
37:03
seems quite gloomy and depressing when you
37:06
think about... debt because people always focus
37:08
on you know is it serviceable is
37:10
it out of control and yet I
37:13
think people should focus more on how
37:15
it does create this ability to weather
37:17
these shocks and of course you have
37:20
to deal with the aftermath that's what
37:22
we're doing right now but what it
37:24
meant was that through the pandemic we
37:26
could keep people employed there wasn't such
37:29
a big negative shock on the economy
37:31
where there were loads of layoffs and
37:33
then when these crises occur you can
37:36
deal with it. And like you, I'm
37:38
kind of optimistic about what the future
37:40
holds in terms of getting that tet
37:43
to GDP down again, just as we
37:45
had after the Second World War, it
37:47
fell very dramatically. And after the Napoleonic
37:50
War, what you... of rely on is
37:52
there not to be another crisis in
37:54
quick succession or a whole spative crisis
37:57
in fact? Yeah I think that's right.
37:59
I wouldn't describe the national debt as
38:01
out of control which kind of implies
38:04
there's an imminent crisis coming over the
38:06
horizon. But at the same time of
38:08
the other extreme you see some people
38:11
saying you don't really need to worry
38:13
about the debt, government controls the currency,
38:15
it can print money. Let's just get
38:18
on with things and run the economy
38:20
hot. I don't agree with that either.
38:22
I think the level of debt we
38:25
have and the deficits we have do
38:27
create real tangible problems for the economy
38:29
and the government. And there are constraints
38:32
here, genuine constraints around inflation, around the
38:34
resources available to the real economy, around
38:36
crowding out, and around like political capital
38:38
and what you can actually do to
38:41
fix these things before people just get
38:43
sick of it. And I think the
38:45
OBR acknowledges... that the long-term outlook is
38:48
difficult. So a quote from their latest
38:50
report, it says, the long-term fiscal outlook
38:52
remains very challenging, with pressures from an
38:55
aging population, climate change and rising geopolitical
38:57
tensions, putting the public finances on an
38:59
increasingly unsustainable path. The baseline projection would
39:02
require fiscal tightening of 1.5% of GDP
39:04
per decade over the next 50 years
39:06
to return debt to pre-pandemic levels. Leaving
39:09
policy settings unchanged in the long term
39:11
would see debt rise to over 270%
39:13
of GDP by the mid-20-70s. The strong
39:16
words, I think, from a like official
39:18
watchdog. Fiscal tightening 1.5% of GDP. That
39:20
is pretty surprising. We're not going to
39:23
do that. That's why growth has to
39:25
bail us out. I think the thing
39:27
that gets lost in all this debate
39:30
is that people think about the national
39:32
debt as a kind of accounting number.
39:34
It's very abstract. It's like a reflection
39:37
of our collective priorities and our willingness
39:39
to invest now and delay consumption and
39:41
agree on how we should pay for
39:44
the society that we want to have.
39:46
It's a much harder problem than like
39:48
balancing the books. It's always phrased as
39:50
balancing the books, but that's just like
39:53
the trivial bit of it. And it's
39:55
the sum of the previous crisis we've
39:57
suffered in recent history, which recently hasn't
40:00
been great. We've had the financial crisis
40:02
and then a real crisis with the
40:04
pandemic. What worries me is that if
40:07
politicians come along offering simple solutions and
40:09
saying, yep, bread and circuses, let's just
40:11
spend people carrying on buying our debt,
40:14
it doesn't matter, that's what would really
40:16
cause a problem. But you're still happy
40:18
to buy the debt, aren't you? Oh
40:21
yeah, I love it. Now you've heard
40:23
I'm a fan of buying government debt.
40:25
Well, a lot of our content in
40:28
the past has been about buying gilts
40:30
and we've got lots of tools available
40:32
for people who are interested in buying,
40:35
say, low coupon gilts, which are very
40:37
tax efficient. If you want to learn
40:39
more about that, why not join our
40:42
community? Just go to pensioncraft.com/membership. Okay, today's
40:44
dumb question of the week. Is government
40:46
debt just like household debt? only much
40:49
bigger. No. It is a very very
40:51
frustrating analogy to hear, wheeled out over
40:53
and over again. But then it's really
40:55
tempting, right? Because you have to try
40:58
and make it relevant to people's lives.
41:00
And I'm sure we've fallen into the
41:02
trap inadvertently before where you say credit
41:05
card or mortgage or something when you
41:07
try to talk about sovereign debt. I
41:09
wish I could print money. That would
41:12
be great. Well, yeah, there's so many
41:14
differences, isn't there, how a government structures
41:16
it's borrowing versus a household. Do you
41:19
want to run through some of the
41:21
differences for the differences for us? Okay,
41:23
the obvious one is if you control
41:26
money, you can tax people in your
41:28
own money. And in your own money
41:30
is really important. If they could pay
41:33
taxes in some other form, eggs for
41:35
example, then your currency wouldn't be so
41:37
important. But because you can force people
41:40
to pay taxes in your own currency,
41:42
that immediately creates value for that currency.
41:44
So that relationship between senior age, the
41:47
ability to issue money and the power
41:49
to tax. is inextricably linked. And I
41:51
guess it's critical that government has a
41:54
monopoly on that power to tax. And
41:56
they won't give it up without the
41:58
use of weapons. So that's important to
42:01
remember. But it's a huge difference isn't
42:03
it? So you and I we rely
42:05
on our salaries or our business income
42:07
or our investment income whereas the government
42:10
can to a large extent control its
42:12
own income and has this massively diversified
42:14
revenue stream. And I guess the point
42:17
on currency could be expanded even further
42:19
to say that for a lot of
42:21
countries... including the US, the US, including
42:24
the UK, the government owes debt in
42:26
its own currency. Yeah, unless you're in
42:28
the Eurozone, for example, where that kind
42:31
of breaks down. Or in an emerging
42:33
market where they've borrowed in dollars, say.
42:35
Yeah, hard currency debt. I mean, I
42:38
guess the implication here is that can
42:40
a government that owes debt in its
42:42
own currency actually default legally? Like the
42:45
US or the UK could print pounds
42:47
or dollars to pay back creditors. Obviously
42:49
there's consequences to that, but they can
42:52
do it. And this is an argument
42:54
why countries which can print money are
42:56
said to have a very low credit
42:59
risk. Within reason, they can print money
43:01
to service the debt. So that's always
43:03
reassuring. You always want to lend to
43:06
someone who's got their own printing press.
43:08
They print too much. They might be
43:10
paying you back in very devalued dollars,
43:12
but still, you're going to get some
43:15
dollars somehow. This is it. Within reason,
43:17
everything would be fine. They can't go
43:19
involuntarily bankrupt like a person can, is
43:22
what we're saying. Yeah, ultimately it's always
43:24
a matter of choice for a government,
43:26
you know, do we default on our
43:29
external debt? A repudiation of debt is
43:31
not something that a same government would
43:33
take lightly, because it'll have generational costs,
43:36
because yields will spike and stay high
43:38
for a long period of time. Bond
43:40
investors wouldn't forget that. And you say
43:43
it's a choice, and I think we
43:45
should remember here that we're talking about...
43:47
developed market economies that are borrowing in
43:50
their own currency. Like it's not a
43:52
choice if Argentina defaults on its dollar
43:54
bonds. It might genuinely not be able
43:57
to get its hands on enough dollars
43:59
to... people back. And it's a privilege
44:01
to be able to borrow in your
44:03
own currency. And you probably don't
44:06
want to risk that by annoying
44:08
markets too much. But there
44:10
are other differences, aren't there, between
44:12
a household and a government when
44:14
it comes to borrowing. One of
44:17
those being around how long we live.
44:19
Yeah, for us, it's all a matter
44:21
of a lifetime, which is at most
44:23
about 100 years. For a country, it's
44:25
effectively eternal. So they don't really have to
44:27
worry about paying things off over the
44:30
next century. Yeah, the government never
44:32
really aims to get to the
44:34
position where it has no debt,
44:36
whereas a person probably doesn't want
44:38
to die with like massive outstanding
44:41
debts. Or maybe you do. I don't
44:43
know. Another difference is that if I
44:45
decide to take out a loan, it's
44:47
not going to massively affect the UK
44:49
or another country. Whereas if the US
44:52
decides to massively increase its debt, that
44:54
would have global implications. Yeah, it's just
44:56
the scale of everything, isn't it? Me and
44:58
new borrowing does not impact our neighbour,
45:00
whereas government borrowing and spending
45:03
decisions affect the whole economy.
45:05
Government debt, its level, its structure,
45:07
its growth rate, that affects everything
45:09
from interest rates to inflation, to
45:11
investment to the exchange rate. It's
45:13
not something that acts in isolation
45:16
like me going and getting a
45:18
mortgage. And I think the reasons behind
45:20
government borrowing are different from
45:22
reasons for household borrowing. If I
45:24
borrow it, it's because I haven't got enough ready
45:26
cash. If the government borrows, it
45:29
could be because they're trying to
45:31
do something counter-cyclical. If there has been
45:33
a slowdown in growth, they may be trying
45:35
to stimulate the economy by borrowing. I think
45:38
that's a really good point. The rational course
45:40
of action is completely different. Opposite, you
45:42
might say. Like, if I as an
45:44
individual lose my job... It's sane and proper
45:46
to cut my spending, to cut my
45:49
cloth accordingly. Whereas if you think about the
45:51
government, if the economy tanks and lots
45:53
of people are losing their jobs, what
45:55
you want the government to do is
45:57
to boost spending and to stimulate demand.
46:00
This is what Keynesian economic says
46:02
at least. The government is acting
46:04
counter-cyclically, like you say. It's completely
46:06
the opposite to an individual. And
46:08
as a final point, whenever people
46:10
talk about having no debt, as
46:12
if that were a good thing,
46:14
remember that things like treasuries, UK
46:16
guilt actually form the lubricant for
46:18
the entire financial system, which really
46:20
wouldn't be able to run as
46:23
it exists now, without that very
46:25
safe debt. So just remember that
46:27
one of the side effects of
46:29
having a deficit and having an
46:31
outstanding debt is a good thing,
46:33
which is it makes the financial
46:35
system work. I mean it kind
46:37
of works, doesn't it? Close enough.
46:39
We're muddling through. Thank you for
46:42
joining us for many happy returns.
46:44
Keep sending us your questions, no
46:46
matter how dumb, at MHR at
46:48
pensioncraft.com. And do remember to check
46:50
out pensioncraft.com for all the information
46:52
about our membership courses and investment
46:54
coaching options. Many happy returns is
46:56
a pension craft production. Co-hosted and
46:58
executive produced by Romyn Akisa and
47:00
Michael Pew. This podcast is for
47:03
informational and entertainment purposes and is
47:05
not financial advice. We do not
47:07
provide recommendations or endorse any decision
47:09
to buy, sell or hold any
47:11
security. We cannot be held responsible
47:13
for any actions listeners may take,
47:15
and investors are encouraged to seek
47:17
independent financial advice.
Podchaser is the ultimate destination for podcast data, search, and discovery. Learn More