The Trillion Pound Question: Is Government Debt Out of Control?

The Trillion Pound Question: Is Government Debt Out of Control?

Released Wednesday, 2nd April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
The Trillion Pound Question: Is Government Debt Out of Control?

The Trillion Pound Question: Is Government Debt Out of Control?

The Trillion Pound Question: Is Government Debt Out of Control?

The Trillion Pound Question: Is Government Debt Out of Control?

Wednesday, 2nd April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:00

Today's episode is sponsored

0:02

by Trading 212. The

0:04

platform bringing commission-free investing

0:06

to everyone. National debt figures

0:08

are staggering, running to trillions of

0:11

pounds in the UK and tens

0:13

of trillions of dollars in the

0:15

US. Headlines were one of unsustainable

0:17

paths and ticking time bombs under

0:19

our economies. But is government debt

0:21

really out of control? I want

0:24

to know how we got buried

0:26

under this mountain of debt and

0:28

what the real risks are. And

0:30

in today's dumb question of the

0:32

week, we ask, is government debt

0:34

just like household debt only much

0:37

bigger? All right, let's get into

0:39

it. So this week, Roman, we're

0:41

going to be talking about things

0:43

which involve very big numbers in

0:45

the trillions. Now, I want to

0:47

avoid the trap where we go

0:49

big number equals scary. So I

0:52

think what we should do, if

0:54

we can, is always talk about

0:56

things as percentages of GDP, if

0:58

we can. Yeah, otherwise the numbers

1:00

just look crazy. You should always scale

1:02

it in terms of the size of

1:04

the economy. An economy that's 10 times

1:07

as big can maintain a level of

1:09

debt, which is 10 times larger. So let's

1:11

just get to it straight away then. How

1:14

big is the public debt in

1:16

the UK? So public sector net

1:18

debt and that excludes public sector

1:20

banks. That was estimated at

1:22

about 95.5% of GDP, gross

1:24

domestic product. And that was

1:27

for February 2025. So a little bit

1:29

under 100% of GDP. Should

1:31

we give some context to that?

1:33

Because it has risen sharply

1:35

over the past 25 years.

1:37

If we go back to the turn of the

1:40

Millennium, the year 2000, public debt

1:42

at that point was 28.3% of

1:44

GDP, and now we're at nearly 100.

1:47

And again, if you zoom out here,

1:49

I think it's useful, and go all

1:51

the way back to the 1700s. I

1:53

thought going back to the Millennium was

1:55

fair enough. We were turning the time

1:57

machine way back. But with the UK...

1:59

do that which is great but 2000

2:02

was very much a low point in

2:04

debt to GDP for the UK just

2:06

prior to that well I say just

2:09

about 50 years prior to that just

2:11

after World War II that's when we

2:13

reached our all-time high for debt to

2:16

GDP there it peaked at just over

2:18

250% briefly and after World War I

2:20

it peaked at about just under 200%

2:23

so Clearly, times of crisis, when you

2:25

really have to raise a lot of

2:27

taxes, raise a lot of income and

2:30

spend it, those are the periods in

2:32

time when government really splurges out and

2:34

issues lots of debt and pushes up

2:37

debt to GDP. You promised me the

2:39

1700s. Keep going. Okay, so another peak

2:41

was just after the Napoleonic War. Clearly

2:44

we had to pay for that. Then

2:46

we had the American War of Independence.

2:48

Before that. the seven years war, the

2:50

war of the Austrian succession, and each

2:53

of these had its own little peak

2:55

which built up and built up to

2:57

a crescendo of the Napoleonic Wars when

3:00

debt to GDP reached about 200% again.

3:02

But then if we go further back

3:04

in time, all the way back to

3:07

1,700 debt to GDP was tiny. It

3:09

was only about 25% and the first

3:11

thing that really pushed us up the

3:14

hill was the war of the Spanish

3:16

succession. Seems like there's a lot of

3:18

wars in British history if we're looking

3:21

at the debt to GDP ratio. But

3:23

the reason why we won those wars

3:25

was that we were very good at

3:28

issuing debt, at least that's one argument.

3:30

But we're not fighting a war right

3:32

now, so how has debt gone from

3:35

just under 30% of GDP in the

3:37

year 2000 to almost 100% now? Well

3:39

that's why it hasn't gone to 200%

3:42

probably, but we have had COVID, which

3:44

is kind of like a war against

3:46

a virus, so I'd argue that something

3:49

like a pandemic would also count as

3:51

something which is going to push up

3:53

to GDP. Any kind of big crisis

3:56

we have to spend a lot. We

3:58

did spend a lot through COVID on

4:00

furlough and on healthcare costs. And of

4:02

course before that we had the global

4:05

financial crisis, which really cost a lot

4:07

in terms of bank bailouts and stimulus

4:09

packages. And of course growth, because if

4:12

you're comparing debt to GDP, if GDP

4:14

is weak and debt to GDP is

4:16

going to go up. And it has

4:19

to be said in the past, whenever

4:21

we've actually reduced our debt to GDP,

4:23

So this was following the Napoleonic War

4:26

and following World War II, the way

4:28

that number's fallen is because GDP growth

4:30

has been more rapid than debt growth.

4:33

Yeah, we've grown our way out of

4:35

it to some extent and inflated our

4:37

way out a little bit. Yeah. And

4:40

here I think it's worth being clear

4:42

about the difference between the national debt

4:44

and the deficit, because you hear a

4:47

lot in the media about the deficit,

4:49

and I guess that is the engine

4:51

by which the debt grows. Yeah, so

4:54

this is the distinction between levels and

4:56

flows. The deficit is what makes debt

4:58

grow because you plug the difference between

5:01

tax income and expenditure by issuing debt,

5:03

and then the level of debt grows

5:05

if the deficit is continually large. And

5:07

at the moment, the deficit in the

5:10

UK, which is called public sector net

5:12

borrowing, is around £137 billion this year.

5:14

which is 4.8% of GDP and is

5:17

too high to be sustainable in the

5:19

long run really. Now the Office for

5:21

Budget Responsibility issued a report last week

5:24

alongside the spring statement which showed that

5:26

based on the government's spending plans and

5:28

tax plans and its assumptions around growth

5:31

and things like that, it expects the

5:33

deficit to fall to 2.1% of GDP

5:35

by the end of this parliament in

5:38

2030. So it's fair to say this

5:40

government takes debt to GDP very seriously.

5:42

They haven't splurged on spending and they're

5:45

very keen on getting debt to GDP

5:47

under control. Now if we turn our

5:49

attention to the US, obviously the numbers

5:52

are much bigger there because it's much

5:54

bigger country. they're experiencing a kind of

5:56

similar thing to the UK where deficits

5:59

are very large by historic standards and

6:01

debt has been rising fast. So for

6:03

the United States it depends how you

6:06

measure it but if you look at

6:08

what the CBO recommends which is federal

6:10

debt held by the public as a

6:13

percentage of GDP that's just a shade

6:15

under a hundred percent it's 97 percent.

6:17

So a similar ballpark to the UK

6:19

really? Yeah it's not very different at

6:22

all. Now you might see a lot

6:24

of people quote the gross federal debt.

6:26

which is the broadest measure of debt

6:29

and that's much higher that's around 123%

6:31

of GDP in the US. But as

6:33

you say the CBO thinks that's not

6:36

the best measure of debt because it

6:38

includes debt that's held by the government

6:40

itself and that is generally through schemes

6:43

like social security and retirement programs and

6:45

Medicare where they invest in treasuries themselves

6:47

so it's the government kind of owing

6:50

itself money. And I think we should

6:52

probably mention what the CBO is. It's

6:54

the Congressional Budget Office. Now this is

6:57

a non-partisan organisation in the United States.

6:59

It was set up by a congressional

7:01

act in 1974. And the idea is

7:04

that it provides objective non-partisan information to

7:06

support the congressional budget process. Yeah, and

7:08

handily they issued their latest report last

7:11

week, much like the OBR in the

7:13

UK, and they project forward. What's going

7:15

to happen to the US deficit and

7:18

the US debt over the next 30

7:20

years? And crucially, they do that on

7:22

the basis of what is the law

7:24

at the moment. We can talk about

7:27

this in a second. I think that's

7:29

a problematic way of doing it. But

7:31

whenever you look at their projections, it's

7:34

always quite alarming. Sure is. So when

7:36

I looked at it this time, it

7:38

said, by 2055, federal debt held by

7:41

the public will reach 156% of GDP

7:43

and remain on track to increase thereafter.

7:45

If you look at the graph, it's

7:48

a scary graph, it's steep, isn't it?

7:50

Yeah, it starts at 100 today, and

7:52

then it just seems to grow. a

7:55

fairly linear fashion all the way up

7:57

to 2055. And as you'd expect, the

7:59

reason the debt keeps growing throughout the

8:02

period is because deficits are baked in

8:04

across the period based on current law.

8:06

So over the next 30 years, the

8:09

CBO estimates the deficit to be 6.3%

8:11

of GDP, which is more than one

8:13

and a half times the average over

8:16

the last 50 years. And that larger

8:18

deficit... is primarily being driven by an

8:20

increase in interest costs as the US

8:23

has to service its debt, but also

8:25

increased spending on healthcare programs like Medicare,

8:27

social securities, you've got an aging population,

8:30

and actually trend growth which is weaker

8:32

than it's been over the last 50

8:34

years on average. And again, if you

8:36

look at that history of fiscal deficit

8:39

for the United States, currently it's pretty

8:41

large, it's about 6.3%. But it's been

8:43

gradually getting larger since 2000. It's just

8:46

government after government, Republican or Democrat, has

8:48

been gradually increasing how much the government

8:50

spends without taxes paying for it and

8:53

then plugging the difference with debt. Now

8:55

when interest rates were pretty much zero

8:57

since 2007, that wasn't such a big

9:00

problem because the debt servicing cost was

9:02

small. But now that we're starting to

9:04

see interest rates pick up back to

9:07

normal, it's a big problem. For example,

9:09

a lot of people quote the fact

9:11

that the US is spending more on

9:14

debt servicing than it is on defence.

9:16

And that is unusual. If you go

9:18

back before 1990, the fiscal deficit was

9:21

much smaller. It's only when you go

9:23

back to the Second World War that

9:25

you see a really huge fiscal deficit

9:28

when it ballooned out beyond 25%. I

9:30

found that that surprising that the US

9:32

is spending around a trillion dollars a

9:35

year on interest, give or take. and

9:37

the defense budget is something like 850

9:39

billion dollars. Yeah, spending more just servicing

9:42

its debt than it is on tanks

9:44

and fighter jets, some missile systems and

9:46

all that stuff which we associate with

9:48

US federal. spending. But can I just

9:51

say that one of the side effects

9:53

of a fiscal deficit is government bonds?

9:55

And I love government bonds. In my

9:58

world, it's my happy place. Obviously too

10:00

much government debt, not such a happy

10:02

place. So within reason, I think having

10:05

a deficit is okay. And in fact,

10:07

it's probably normal. And it's probably good.

10:09

But when it gets out of control,

10:12

which is the topic of today's podcast,

10:14

that's the real problem. Yeah, Robin, you're

10:16

not a price insensitive buyer, are you?

10:19

You have to look at the market

10:21

and make a judgment call. I do

10:23

look at the yields, yeah, yeah. But

10:26

the thing is, you've got tens of

10:28

trillions of debt in the US. It

10:30

can run a surplus for quite a

10:33

while and they'll still be plenty of

10:35

treas for you to buy as they

10:37

roll them over. That's right, that's right.

10:40

I mean, they've got to issue new

10:42

stuff because it does mature, but there

10:44

is a kind of servicing bonds. But

10:47

it's fair to say a lot of

10:49

people like bonds. And they are a

10:51

mainstay of balance sheets across the world.

10:53

But who holds all this debt? So

10:56

the outstanding debt, US Treasuries, at the

10:58

moment is about $36 trillion. And two-thirds

11:00

of that is held by US citizens.

11:03

Now that's not really a problem because

11:05

if you're a US citizen, presumably you

11:07

don't want to scup your own government

11:10

by selling their debt. You don't want

11:12

to destabilise your own country. And when

11:14

you say US citizens, you're including institutions

11:17

like pension funds and insurers and all

11:19

of that stuff in there as well.

11:21

Exactly. Institutions probably hold more than retail

11:24

investors. I'm not sure what that split

11:26

is for the US. But what's perhaps

11:28

more worrying are the non-US holders of

11:31

that debt, which makes up one-third of

11:33

the holdings. Now people have referred to

11:35

this as the kindness of strangers. And

11:38

of course, you can't rely on that

11:40

kindness. particularly if you are not being

11:42

very kind to them. For example, Japan

11:45

holds about just over a trillion dollars

11:47

of that debt, China holds... 761 billion,

11:49

UK 740 billion, Luxembourg weirdly, 410 billion,

11:52

given it's essentially a tiny country, but

11:54

of course that's often financial institutions buying

11:56

US debt. Yeah, tracing the debt is

11:59

never an easy task, is it? Otherwise

12:01

it looks like the Cayman Islands is

12:03

one of the biggest holders of US

12:05

debt. Yeah, they hold 404 billion. Which

12:08

on a per capita basis is insane.

12:10

and Belgium our favourite country 378 billion.

12:12

Some of that's China actually rooted through

12:15

Belgium. But another big holder of US

12:17

federal debt is of course the Federal

12:19

Reserve. Its various quantitative easing schemes over

12:22

the last 20 years have in effect

12:24

meant buying treasuries and boosting the size

12:26

of the central bank balance sheet. But

12:29

here we get to an interesting question

12:31

of... Is that really debt? Or is

12:33

it a kind of accounting trick on

12:36

the national balance sheets where you've printed

12:38

money to buy your own debt? It

12:40

is odd, isn't it? And you get

12:43

into all sorts of circular arguments about

12:45

whether it's real debt or not, whether

12:47

it's effectively been retired. Legally it hasn't

12:50

been retired. Yeah. And they are winding

12:52

it down. Now, quantitative tightening is important

12:54

because you can see that if you

12:57

measure the US Treasury securities securities securities

12:59

securities, the holdings by the Fed. for

13:01

treasuries. That peaked at 5.8 trillion and

13:04

that was in roughly the summer the

13:06

spring of 2022 and it's been falling

13:08

fairly sharply since. So currently it's about

13:10

4.2 trillion. So it's diminishing but the

13:13

rate of decrease has recently slowed because

13:15

the feds slowed down its QT programme

13:17

for treasuries at least. And a similar

13:20

thing seems to be playing out in

13:22

the UK where in fact the Bank

13:24

of England is actually selling. some of

13:27

its guilt holdings on the open market,

13:29

somewhat controversially, and is charging the UK

13:31

treasury money every year now because it's

13:34

selling at a loss. This is all

13:36

a weird accounting trick as you say

13:38

but it does mean that the government

13:41

and I guess the taxpayer by extension

13:43

has to find a bit of extra

13:45

money every year at the moment. UK

13:48

government yeah whereas in the US they

13:50

don't actually sell them they just wait

13:52

for them to mature and roll off

13:55

as they call it. But if you

13:57

accept that this is all a bit

13:59

of a weird fiction in a way

14:02

you can look at a measure like

14:04

public sector net debt excluding the bank

14:06

of England. which is obviously lower than

14:09

the actual day. It's more like 90%

14:11

rather than the 95 point something percent

14:13

we talked about earlier. But interestingly, the

14:16

OBR forecasts that by the end of

14:18

the Parliament, those things will have both

14:20

converged at around 95% of GDP as

14:22

the Bank of England ends its term

14:25

funding scheme and asset purchase facility, which

14:27

is what you'd expect, right? Yes, a

14:29

normalisation to the pre-crisis state of affairs.

14:32

Now clearly what you want to avoid

14:34

as a government is having to spend

14:36

a huge amount servicing your debt because

14:39

that's money that you can't spend on

14:41

all the other things that a government

14:43

needs to run the country. So if

14:46

we look at the UK for example

14:48

the total spending is just under 1.3

14:50

trillion pounds a year of which 105

14:53

billion was the debt interest. Yeah so

14:55

about 4.3% of GDP was spent on

14:57

debt interest. in 2223, which is a

15:00

post-war high. Now, the OBI expects that

15:02

to decline a little bit in the

15:04

coming years, but not hugely. It's going

15:07

to be around 4% maybe a little

15:09

bit lower by the end of the

15:11

Parliament. And I guess crucially, we are

15:14

spending a lot more on debt interest

15:16

than we used to. So in the

15:18

10 years before the pandemic, the cost

15:21

of servicing the national debt was around

15:23

2% of GDP on average. So, you

15:25

know, we're more than twice that at

15:28

the moment. So until quite recently the

15:30

UK issued a lot of inflation link

15:32

debt. Now the way those work is

15:34

that they increase their principal value increases

15:37

as does their coupon in line with

15:39

our And when RPI inflation zoomed up

15:41

above 10% that pushed up the principal

15:44

values of those notes, of that debt.

15:46

Now that's not something that reverses. It

15:48

carries on being expensive until those bonds

15:51

mature. So that was a real problem

15:53

for the UK. A lot of historical

15:55

inflation make debt, which is more expensive

15:58

to service. And relative to other countries,

16:00

we issued a lot more of this

16:02

stuff because our life insurers love it.

16:05

For the rest of the debt, which

16:07

is nominal, that wasn't an issue, it

16:09

wasn't about inflation increasing. Really the problem

16:12

there is that there's just more debt

16:14

outstanding and because yields are higher, as

16:16

that debt's rolled over, the government's having

16:19

to pay more to service those bonds.

16:21

So all in all, a pretty much

16:23

perfect storm for the UK government. So

16:26

the picture overall, I think you could

16:28

summarize in the UK and to an

16:30

extent in the US, is that debt

16:33

has been rising extremely fast, extremely fast.

16:35

since the financial crisis. Deficits are persistent

16:37

and governments don't seem to be able

16:39

to close them. And yields have gone

16:42

up. And markets are a little bit

16:44

nervous, I guess you could say, now

16:46

they're looking at this step. I'm saying,

16:49

is it sustainable? So I guess when

16:51

we come back from the break, the

16:53

question will be, is the doubt of

16:56

control and is it dangerous? Trading 212

16:58

stocks and shares ISA is the cheapest

17:00

way to invest, with zero commission and

17:03

the lowest FX fees I could find

17:05

on the market. Looking to keep things

17:07

simple, you can easily automate your investing

17:10

with pies that allow you to rebalance

17:12

your portfolio at the click of a

17:14

button. Customers with Invest accounts can also

17:17

benefit from the Trading 212 card, which

17:19

has no FX fees, true interbank rates

17:21

and offers 0.5% cash back on all

17:24

transactions up to 20 pounds per month.

17:26

Many happy returns listeners can claim free

17:28

fractional shares worth up to a hundred

17:31

pounds. Just create and verify a trading

17:33

2-1-2 invest or stock-sicer account, make a

17:35

minimum deposit of a pound, and use

17:38

the promo code, Roman, R-A-M-I-N, within 10

17:40

days of signing up or use the

17:42

link in the show notes. When investing

17:45

your capital is at risk and you

17:47

may get back less than invested. Past

17:49

performance doesn't guarantee future results. Pies and

17:51

Auto Invest is an execution only service,

17:54

not investment advice or portfolio portfolio management.

17:56

Automatic investing refers to executing schedule deposits.

17:58

You're responsible for all investment and rebalancing

18:01

decisions. Free shares can be fractional. 2.2

18:03

cards are issued by Paynetics which provide

18:05

all payment services. Trading 2.2 provides customer

18:08

support and user interface. Terms and fees

18:10

apply. All right, Roman, so we've got

18:12

this debt pile. It's roughly the size

18:15

of the economy and growing. How dangerous

18:17

is it? I think debts a little

18:19

bit like chocolate in the sense that

18:22

as long as you don't have too

18:24

much, it's kind of okay. In small

18:26

quantities, it's absolutely fine and it makes

18:29

things better. But the problem really comes

18:31

when it really starts to create a

18:33

lopsided economy where debt servicing becomes a

18:36

really big factor. So for example, if

18:38

you're spending a lot on debt servicing

18:40

costs, you're not going to spend it

18:43

on public services, on infrastructure, and that

18:45

can be a problem for future growth

18:47

for future growth. And in order to

18:50

get rid of it, you may have

18:52

to increase taxes. And of course, nobody

18:54

likes that. So it's very politically unpopular.

18:57

And usually you might expect it to

18:59

lead to the change of government, because

19:01

nobody's going to vote for a government

19:03

which has hugely hyped up taxes. And

19:06

of course all those things have growth

19:08

impacts, don't they? So I guess if

19:10

you've got rising debt, it often comes

19:13

with higher yields, and that increases borrowing

19:15

costs across the economy, not just for

19:17

the government. It means businesses. are going

19:20

to be charged more to borrow and

19:22

invest, which should slow growth or else.

19:24

being equal. I guess you could say

19:27

it's also potentially crowding out business investment

19:29

because the government is on the markets

19:31

competing for capital with more debt issuance

19:34

against corporate bonds. So corporate bonds look

19:36

less attractive. Yeah I think all of

19:38

that's true. And of course if you've

19:41

got less margins for companies, lower margins,

19:43

that means less profit growth and it's

19:45

going to be bad for the equity

19:48

market. So all in all, not a

19:50

great thing. And I think one thing

19:52

which I worry about more with high

19:55

debt is that we've talked about how

19:57

debt often jumps up when you have

19:59

a crisis, a war, a pandemic, a

20:02

financial crisis, whatever it is. Those things

20:04

seem to happen fairly regularly and I

20:06

often think there's not much you can

20:08

do about some of those things. So

20:11

we'll probably get another crisis at some

20:13

point. Does it give us less room

20:15

to act in the next crisis? Yeah,

20:18

for example after World War I in

20:20

the UK. the debt hadn't fully got

20:22

back to normal. In fact, it was

20:25

nowhere near back to normal before the

20:27

next one. And going back even further,

20:29

we were talking about the 1700s and

20:32

1800s. Well, there was just war after

20:34

war. And after each one, the debt

20:36

built up, and it never really got

20:39

a chance to fall. So I think

20:41

you're right. I think that now we've

20:43

got less capacity for a future crisis,

20:46

whether it's a pandemic or whether it's

20:48

another war. It's interesting, isn't it, reading

20:50

through these reports from the OBR and

20:53

the UK and the CBO in the

20:55

US. They make all these projections going

20:57

forward, you know, 30, 40 years. And

21:00

everything follows a neat orderly course where

21:02

the deficits are kind of the same

21:04

as they are now into the future.

21:07

And yeah, it makes the debt look

21:09

really bad. But to me, I was

21:11

saying, oh, that's kind of a best

21:14

case, right? The world seems to throw

21:16

problems at us, which means that we

21:18

then have to suddenly spend another 20%

21:20

of GDP, bailing everything out. But I

21:23

think we're lucky that we can do

21:25

that because in the past, whenever we've

21:27

needed to, we've been able to. And

21:30

that's why I think it's really important

21:32

that the UK is a credible borrower.

21:34

If we were some country which really

21:37

didn't care about debt to GDP, then

21:39

when these crises do occur, at least

21:41

the people who give us the money

21:44

can be fairly confident that they will

21:46

get paid back. Whereas if you're Argentina,

21:48

that's a much harder case to make.

21:51

I mean, we'd never defaulted on our

21:53

debt, have we, in the UK? Well,

21:55

there was some close shaves and technical

21:58

ones, but... Not really, not for a

22:00

long time. Don't scare the horses from

22:02

it. We've never defaulted. I loved it

22:05

in the UK. No, the Middle Ages,

22:07

we were serial defaulters. But look, that

22:09

was a long time ago. But it's

22:12

good to know that we would have

22:14

the capacity to increase our debt to

22:16

GDP to 200% as we did in

22:19

previous wars. And that would give us

22:21

three trillion pounds to spend to defend

22:23

ourselves. Do we though? Why did Liz

22:25

truss come a croper so quickly if

22:28

we've got that capacity? No, seriously though.

22:30

Is it because we weren't in a

22:32

crisis? I think that was the issue,

22:35

and it was a period of high

22:37

inflation, and it just seemed economically literate

22:39

what she did. I guess the thing

22:42

is, if a crisis comes along, like

22:44

COVID, and the world's panicking, and markets

22:46

are panicking, markets, I guess, are rushing

22:49

out of risky assets like stocks, and

22:51

whatever, and piling into perceived safe assets

22:53

like guilt. So it may be constrains

22:56

yields at the time you're trying to

22:58

borrow a lot more. As if you

23:00

try and do the outside of a

23:03

crisis, you don't have that same benefit

23:05

of flows. Yeah, when the economy was

23:07

effectively healing and it was a period

23:10

of high inflation, and if you issue

23:12

lots of debt and have unfunded tax

23:14

cuts at the same time, well, that's

23:17

just kind of crazy. The problem would

23:19

be if we have a crisis which

23:21

is UK specific. There's no global rush

23:24

into safe assets. It's just, uh-oh, we're

23:26

trying to issue a lot of dare

23:28

at the same time as our yields

23:31

are rising. Yeah, that wouldn't be so

23:33

good. But could we get one of

23:35

these crises of confidence from the market?

23:37

the so-called bond vigilantes rising up just

23:40

because they feel that the debt is

23:42

on an unsustainable path. I think it's

23:44

unlikely for the UK and I think

23:47

it's unlikely for the US as well

23:49

unless there are some obviously crazy signals

23:51

coming from the government or just signs

23:54

that the government doesn't care. They don't

23:56

care about debt to GDP because they

23:58

assume that people will just carry on

24:01

buying their debt regardless of whatever they

24:03

do. I think that's the situation in

24:05

the US right now. I don't think

24:08

either party really cares about debt to

24:10

GDP. You see talk of slashing federal

24:12

spending, you know, Elon Musk's doge has

24:15

been tasked with going around finding cuts.

24:17

He doesn't seem to be finding anything

24:19

significant. At the same time they're talking

24:22

about massive tax cuts. So the interesting

24:24

thing actually is this CBO report is

24:26

predicated on the basis that the laws

24:29

stay the same. Now, that's interesting, like

24:31

what to stay the same mean, because

24:33

what you've got baked in in the

24:36

US tax system is things that expire.

24:38

So Trump instituted massive tax cuts in

24:40

2017 in this first term, which are

24:43

due to expire in the next few

24:45

years. And the CBO projections assume that

24:47

they will expire and not be renewed,

24:49

yet obviously Trump wants to renew them.

24:52

He doesn't want to raise taxes from

24:54

where they are now, and he wants

24:56

to bring in further tax cuts. So

24:59

the CBO projections to me... I like

25:01

downside projections to the debt. I agree

25:03

and I think if the Trump administration

25:06

does carry on with its extension of

25:08

those tax cuts and does produce more

25:10

of them, well it'll be really interesting

25:13

to see what the CBO forecast looks

25:15

like then, unless of course they shut

25:17

down the CBO, which would be one

25:20

really neat solution to that problem. Probably

25:22

doesn't help you with rising yields though

25:24

if you shut down the statistics. Flying

25:27

Blind is not something investors welcome, but

25:29

if you think about it. the US

25:31

is running chunky deficits of six or

25:34

seven percent of GDP. If those go

25:36

higher again because of further tax cuts

25:38

and all the other problems you've got

25:41

with the aging population and lower trend

25:43

growth. Surely there comes a point where

25:45

the market goes, hang on, you can't

25:48

do this. If the deficit got to

25:50

10% and above on a consistent basis,

25:52

the debt just goes exponential. Yeah, there

25:54

is a certain point at which you

25:57

cross the debt Rubicon and essentially things

25:59

get completely out of control. I think

26:01

the US is far from that. I

26:04

think there are enough people who are

26:06

sensible in Congress who... push back on

26:08

it and probably stop it happening. But

26:11

look, ultimately, if markets were worried about

26:13

debt sustainability, seriously worried in the United

26:15

States, then yields with spike and there'd

26:18

be a huge crisis. I guess that

26:20

takes us to a question of what

26:22

are the possible paths from here to

26:25

deal with the problem if it is

26:27

a problem. So I had a thing

26:29

and came up with five possible paths,

26:32

which I want to run by E.

26:34

Roman. The one you hinted out there,

26:36

I've called The Shock, which is that

26:39

a market scare forces drastic action to

26:41

solve the deficit. Like, taxes go up

26:43

and spending gets slashed immediately just because

26:46

yield to blowing out and markets force

26:48

government's hand. That's the most extreme of

26:50

these situations, I say. The second one,

26:53

which is less dramatic, I've just called

26:55

the grind upwards. So this is slow

26:57

growth. High debt is persisting, taxes maybe

27:00

go up a little bit, spending gets

27:02

squeezed a little bit, the economy struggles,

27:04

but it's not catastrophic, and I would

27:06

call this kind of a Japanification of

27:09

the economy, we just muddle through. You

27:11

kind of see that happening over the

27:13

last decade in the United States. They

27:16

have been muddling through, the deficits been

27:18

consistently large, and debt to GDP has

27:20

been gradually rising. So that has been

27:23

the grind upwards. And this isn't to

27:25

say it's consequence free. Some people would

27:27

say you're harming future generations, right, by

27:30

spending beyond your means now as a

27:32

government, but maybe let's put a pin

27:34

in that and come back to it.

27:37

The third possible path I've called austerity

27:39

returns, so this is where we do

27:41

get... sharp spending cuts, Elon Musk finds

27:44

old apartments to take out in the

27:46

US, he slashes Medicare, he slashes Social

27:48

Security, and the debt is reduced in

27:51

the medium term, but the government bears

27:53

quite a lot of political pain and

27:55

I guess growth suffers at the same

27:58

time. Oh yeah, that wouldn't be without

28:00

consequences, political as well, because remember all

28:02

of these changes come with their own

28:05

pushback from the electorate. To me this

28:07

is an unlikely. path because I think

28:09

the political pain is too great. As

28:11

much as Republicans might want to cut

28:14

social spending, I think a lot of

28:16

their base rely on social security and

28:18

Medicare. Yeah, if the spending cuts are

28:21

too sharp, then remember that government spending

28:23

actually does stimulate the economy. So if

28:25

it's too severe, that could itself cause

28:28

problems. And we're already seeing this in

28:30

red states where, for example, a large

28:32

proportion of the government spending has been

28:35

cut. in particular areas which are very

28:37

painful and that hasn't gone down well

28:39

locally. Yeah there's a political cost and

28:42

I also think there's just an economic

28:44

question of can you actually bring debt

28:46

under control through austerity measures if they're

28:49

too harsh the effect on growth might

28:51

be too big and it's like a

28:53

self-defeating policy. Anyway let's move on to

28:56

the fourth possible path forward which I've

28:58

called inflate away and this is the

29:00

idea that the government has this huge

29:03

debt and it thinks huh Maybe if

29:05

I let inflation just run a little

29:07

hot for the next 10 to 20

29:10

years, the real value of that debt

29:12

will fall as a percentage of GDP.

29:14

I think the problem with that one

29:17

is that the government can't really control

29:19

inflation. They can have certain policies which

29:21

make inflation higher, but making it a

29:23

little bit higher and not a lot

29:26

higher is actually very difficult. Just look

29:28

at the Fed's problems getting inflation under

29:30

control. Plus they'd have to talk to

29:33

the Fed. in order to let that

29:35

happen. You can change the mandate right?

29:37

You could say... or if the inflation

29:40

target is 4% now for the next

29:42

10 years. But just think what that

29:44

would do to US debt, it would

29:47

make a massive difference to the valuation

29:49

of US debt, it would make a

29:51

change to the way companies are run,

29:54

it would be a huge shock if

29:56

you double the inflation target. So I

29:58

just don't buy that as a credible

30:01

way of doing it. And if they

30:03

try to do it secretly again, I'm

30:05

not convinced that the government is competent

30:08

enough to cover that up. Even if

30:10

they could pull it off. It's a

30:12

stealth tax on savers effectively, isn't it?

30:15

It's eroding the real value of savings

30:17

to fund the government by the backdoor.

30:19

An inflation is so politically unpopular. Just

30:22

look at all of the discourse about

30:24

egg prices in the United States. It's

30:26

incredible. The amount of pushback, that's generated.

30:29

And you just amplify that by a

30:31

factor of 10 if they suddenly say,

30:33

oh, we're telling the Fed to double

30:35

its inflation target. Have you seen that

30:38

the Trump administration seems to be going...

30:40

one by one around the European countries

30:42

asking for extra egg imports. And they

30:45

keep getting turned down Denmark's like no,

30:47

no, go away. Belgium says no, get

30:49

your own eggs. This is like the

30:52

kindness of strangers, right, in microcosm, around

30:54

eggs rather than deficit funding. And if

30:56

relations with those countries were good, maybe

30:59

they could have talked them around. But

31:01

this is hardly what I described as

31:03

a charming government. No, and I think

31:06

we've also moved away from a... international

31:08

order based on rules to one where

31:10

it's all made by deals effectively. And

31:13

I don't know what that effect that

31:15

has long term on capital flows, but

31:17

anyway, that's a whole other problem. Let's

31:20

go to the final path forward I've

31:22

identified, which is an optimistic one that

31:24

I've called the growth miracle. And here,

31:27

the idea is the debt comes well

31:29

under control just because productivity booms in

31:31

the coming years. And maybe that's because

31:34

of AI or something else. But the

31:36

idea is that economic growth is so

31:38

hot. that the debt becomes trivial. In

31:40

an ideal world, that's the way you

31:43

grow your way out of debt, is

31:45

to have a pickup and GDP. Now

31:47

can I just say there is another

31:50

sixth path which is a debt default?

31:52

So you do get the government suddenly

31:54

saying look you know how we owed

31:57

you what 36 trillion dollars? Well if

31:59

you're a foreign country we're not going

32:01

to pay you a penny. Now would

32:04

that be a problem? Yeah it would

32:06

be hugely disruptive for markets but under

32:08

this new approach where anything goes who

32:11

knows maybe there will be some kind

32:13

of forcing of governments. to accept a

32:15

write-down on US debt, their treasury holdings.

32:18

All bets are off in that situation,

32:20

I reckon. Who knows what's safe and

32:22

what's not? Well, it was part of

32:25

the Maralago thing, which is that the

32:27

governments would willingly swap their US treasuries,

32:29

coupon-paying treasuries, with a fixed maturity date,

32:32

with century bonds, which has zero coupon,

32:34

which is a default. Yeah. Now that's

32:36

not taken seriously, it's not going to

32:39

be policy, but it is something that's

32:41

being considered being considered. All right, so

32:43

let's nail our colors to the mask

32:46

then. We've got six scenarios. You've added

32:48

one. We've got the shock, the grind

32:50

upwards, austerity returns, inflate away, the growth

32:52

miracle, or default doom. What path do

32:55

you think we're on? I think the

32:57

US is on the grind upwards, because

32:59

clearly the government currently doesn't care about

33:02

deficits. It's unlikely that a Democrat government

33:04

would either. So I'd say, yeah, that

33:06

will probably continue. In the UK, certainly

33:09

at the moment, it seems as if

33:11

we've got kind of austerity returns, where

33:13

we've got a government which is really

33:16

cutting back on spending, certainly the day-to-day

33:18

spending, and does care about debt to

33:20

GDP, so they're trying to get the

33:23

deficit under control as well. But it's

33:25

not great for growth. What concerns me

33:27

is that the UK may move to

33:30

a more populist flavor of government. If

33:32

you look at reform in the polls,

33:34

it's certainly shot up. Who knows what

33:37

they'll do when it comes to managing

33:39

the managing the debt? I think you're

33:41

right about both those things, but that

33:44

in the next 30 years... we are

33:46

going to see either the shock or

33:48

the growth miracle. Eventually, at some point,

33:51

who knows where it is, debt becomes

33:53

a problem, and we either get bailed

33:55

out by AI or we don't. Well,

33:58

you're assuming that it will come to

34:00

some kind of head, but what about

34:02

Japan? Japan is way out there in

34:04

terms of debt to GDP. It's at

34:07

something like 250 percent. But life goes

34:09

on in Japan. Economically, they're okay. Not

34:11

incredibly powerful as an economy now as

34:14

they used to be. The growth hasn't

34:16

been phenomenal. And that's despite the huge

34:18

demographic problems, the fact that other countries

34:21

are taking their export mantle away from

34:23

them, and it hasn't come to a

34:25

head. No, you're right. It hasn't, at

34:28

least not yet. There are some differences

34:30

with Japan though. Like they have a

34:32

very high domestic savings rate compared to

34:35

the US and the UK. And I

34:37

guess you could argue that the bank

34:39

of Japan has somewhat monetized its debt.

34:42

And I think it has a lot

34:44

less debt held by foreign investors. But

34:46

you're right, I guess it shows that

34:49

high debt isn't automatically fatal. But then

34:51

yields are starting to creep up in

34:53

Japan. At this point, by design, they

34:56

want higher interest rates and they want

34:58

a bit of inflation to return. But

35:00

let's hope they can keep that manageable,

35:03

right? You don't want debt to be

35:05

250% of GDP. from negative to positive

35:07

to very very positive. Yeah that would

35:09

be catastrophic for Japan. I mean if

35:12

you were the government now in the

35:14

UK say what could they do? What

35:16

should they do? It seems to me

35:19

there's no easy fixes there's just tradeoffs

35:21

involved. Yeah and as a politician you're

35:23

always thinking about whether you'll get reelected

35:26

which makes you avoid doing the difficult

35:28

things which is to raise taxes and

35:30

to reduce spending. And I think that's

35:33

not going to be something that any

35:35

government is going to do lightly. I

35:37

think a lot of what the current

35:40

government and the previous one were trying

35:42

to do is good, which is to

35:44

boost growth, because ultimately that's what reduces

35:47

debt to GDP. That's the solution. That's

35:49

the way out of the problem. It's

35:51

true. Everyone's preferred option is to boost

35:54

growth, but it's hard to achieve, right?

35:56

And it requires smart investment and long-term

35:58

policy planning and perhaps short-term pain. It's

36:01

just hard to get that going, or

36:03

it seems to have been. So what

36:05

you end up with is this kind

36:08

of technocratic managerial style of government, where

36:10

you've got fiscal rules, which you're trying

36:12

to micromanage your way through. Sometimes... the

36:15

tail is wagging the dog and you're

36:17

looking at the projections from the OBR

36:19

which are clouded in uncertainty and they

36:21

admit that and you're tweaking spending cuts

36:24

and tax rises based on these very

36:26

uncertain forecasts and I think the government

36:28

in the UK probably is quite constrained

36:31

for maneuver here. Taxes as a share

36:33

of GDP are at a post-war high

36:35

of more than 35% and are scheduled

36:38

to rise to almost 38% in the

36:40

coming years and that's already... four and

36:42

a half percentage points higher than the

36:45

pre-pandemic level taxes as a share of

36:47

GDP. And also, as you hinted at

36:49

earlier, they are making cuts to welfare

36:52

spending and to departmental spending outside of

36:54

protected areas, but still public spending is

36:56

high. It's forecasted to 45% of GDP

36:59

next year, which is much higher than

37:01

it's been in recent decades. It all

37:03

seems quite gloomy and depressing when you

37:06

think about... debt because people always focus

37:08

on you know is it serviceable is

37:10

it out of control and yet I

37:13

think people should focus more on how

37:15

it does create this ability to weather

37:17

these shocks and of course you have

37:20

to deal with the aftermath that's what

37:22

we're doing right now but what it

37:24

meant was that through the pandemic we

37:26

could keep people employed there wasn't such

37:29

a big negative shock on the economy

37:31

where there were loads of layoffs and

37:33

then when these crises occur you can

37:36

deal with it. And like you, I'm

37:38

kind of optimistic about what the future

37:40

holds in terms of getting that tet

37:43

to GDP down again, just as we

37:45

had after the Second World War, it

37:47

fell very dramatically. And after the Napoleonic

37:50

War, what you... of rely on is

37:52

there not to be another crisis in

37:54

quick succession or a whole spative crisis

37:57

in fact? Yeah I think that's right.

37:59

I wouldn't describe the national debt as

38:01

out of control which kind of implies

38:04

there's an imminent crisis coming over the

38:06

horizon. But at the same time of

38:08

the other extreme you see some people

38:11

saying you don't really need to worry

38:13

about the debt, government controls the currency,

38:15

it can print money. Let's just get

38:18

on with things and run the economy

38:20

hot. I don't agree with that either.

38:22

I think the level of debt we

38:25

have and the deficits we have do

38:27

create real tangible problems for the economy

38:29

and the government. And there are constraints

38:32

here, genuine constraints around inflation, around the

38:34

resources available to the real economy, around

38:36

crowding out, and around like political capital

38:38

and what you can actually do to

38:41

fix these things before people just get

38:43

sick of it. And I think the

38:45

OBR acknowledges... that the long-term outlook is

38:48

difficult. So a quote from their latest

38:50

report, it says, the long-term fiscal outlook

38:52

remains very challenging, with pressures from an

38:55

aging population, climate change and rising geopolitical

38:57

tensions, putting the public finances on an

38:59

increasingly unsustainable path. The baseline projection would

39:02

require fiscal tightening of 1.5% of GDP

39:04

per decade over the next 50 years

39:06

to return debt to pre-pandemic levels. Leaving

39:09

policy settings unchanged in the long term

39:11

would see debt rise to over 270%

39:13

of GDP by the mid-20-70s. The strong

39:16

words, I think, from a like official

39:18

watchdog. Fiscal tightening 1.5% of GDP. That

39:20

is pretty surprising. We're not going to

39:23

do that. That's why growth has to

39:25

bail us out. I think the thing

39:27

that gets lost in all this debate

39:30

is that people think about the national

39:32

debt as a kind of accounting number.

39:34

It's very abstract. It's like a reflection

39:37

of our collective priorities and our willingness

39:39

to invest now and delay consumption and

39:41

agree on how we should pay for

39:44

the society that we want to have.

39:46

It's a much harder problem than like

39:48

balancing the books. It's always phrased as

39:50

balancing the books, but that's just like

39:53

the trivial bit of it. And it's

39:55

the sum of the previous crisis we've

39:57

suffered in recent history, which recently hasn't

40:00

been great. We've had the financial crisis

40:02

and then a real crisis with the

40:04

pandemic. What worries me is that if

40:07

politicians come along offering simple solutions and

40:09

saying, yep, bread and circuses, let's just

40:11

spend people carrying on buying our debt,

40:14

it doesn't matter, that's what would really

40:16

cause a problem. But you're still happy

40:18

to buy the debt, aren't you? Oh

40:21

yeah, I love it. Now you've heard

40:23

I'm a fan of buying government debt.

40:25

Well, a lot of our content in

40:28

the past has been about buying gilts

40:30

and we've got lots of tools available

40:32

for people who are interested in buying,

40:35

say, low coupon gilts, which are very

40:37

tax efficient. If you want to learn

40:39

more about that, why not join our

40:42

community? Just go to pensioncraft.com/membership. Okay, today's

40:44

dumb question of the week. Is government

40:46

debt just like household debt? only much

40:49

bigger. No. It is a very very

40:51

frustrating analogy to hear, wheeled out over

40:53

and over again. But then it's really

40:55

tempting, right? Because you have to try

40:58

and make it relevant to people's lives.

41:00

And I'm sure we've fallen into the

41:02

trap inadvertently before where you say credit

41:05

card or mortgage or something when you

41:07

try to talk about sovereign debt. I

41:09

wish I could print money. That would

41:12

be great. Well, yeah, there's so many

41:14

differences, isn't there, how a government structures

41:16

it's borrowing versus a household. Do you

41:19

want to run through some of the

41:21

differences for the differences for us? Okay,

41:23

the obvious one is if you control

41:26

money, you can tax people in your

41:28

own money. And in your own money

41:30

is really important. If they could pay

41:33

taxes in some other form, eggs for

41:35

example, then your currency wouldn't be so

41:37

important. But because you can force people

41:40

to pay taxes in your own currency,

41:42

that immediately creates value for that currency.

41:44

So that relationship between senior age, the

41:47

ability to issue money and the power

41:49

to tax. is inextricably linked. And I

41:51

guess it's critical that government has a

41:54

monopoly on that power to tax. And

41:56

they won't give it up without the

41:58

use of weapons. So that's important to

42:01

remember. But it's a huge difference isn't

42:03

it? So you and I we rely

42:05

on our salaries or our business income

42:07

or our investment income whereas the government

42:10

can to a large extent control its

42:12

own income and has this massively diversified

42:14

revenue stream. And I guess the point

42:17

on currency could be expanded even further

42:19

to say that for a lot of

42:21

countries... including the US, the US, including

42:24

the UK, the government owes debt in

42:26

its own currency. Yeah, unless you're in

42:28

the Eurozone, for example, where that kind

42:31

of breaks down. Or in an emerging

42:33

market where they've borrowed in dollars, say.

42:35

Yeah, hard currency debt. I mean, I

42:38

guess the implication here is that can

42:40

a government that owes debt in its

42:42

own currency actually default legally? Like the

42:45

US or the UK could print pounds

42:47

or dollars to pay back creditors. Obviously

42:49

there's consequences to that, but they can

42:52

do it. And this is an argument

42:54

why countries which can print money are

42:56

said to have a very low credit

42:59

risk. Within reason, they can print money

43:01

to service the debt. So that's always

43:03

reassuring. You always want to lend to

43:06

someone who's got their own printing press.

43:08

They print too much. They might be

43:10

paying you back in very devalued dollars,

43:12

but still, you're going to get some

43:15

dollars somehow. This is it. Within reason,

43:17

everything would be fine. They can't go

43:19

involuntarily bankrupt like a person can, is

43:22

what we're saying. Yeah, ultimately it's always

43:24

a matter of choice for a government,

43:26

you know, do we default on our

43:29

external debt? A repudiation of debt is

43:31

not something that a same government would

43:33

take lightly, because it'll have generational costs,

43:36

because yields will spike and stay high

43:38

for a long period of time. Bond

43:40

investors wouldn't forget that. And you say

43:43

it's a choice, and I think we

43:45

should remember here that we're talking about...

43:47

developed market economies that are borrowing in

43:50

their own currency. Like it's not a

43:52

choice if Argentina defaults on its dollar

43:54

bonds. It might genuinely not be able

43:57

to get its hands on enough dollars

43:59

to... people back. And it's a privilege

44:01

to be able to borrow in your

44:03

own currency. And you probably don't

44:06

want to risk that by annoying

44:08

markets too much. But there

44:10

are other differences, aren't there, between

44:12

a household and a government when

44:14

it comes to borrowing. One of

44:17

those being around how long we live.

44:19

Yeah, for us, it's all a matter

44:21

of a lifetime, which is at most

44:23

about 100 years. For a country, it's

44:25

effectively eternal. So they don't really have to

44:27

worry about paying things off over the

44:30

next century. Yeah, the government never

44:32

really aims to get to the

44:34

position where it has no debt,

44:36

whereas a person probably doesn't want

44:38

to die with like massive outstanding

44:41

debts. Or maybe you do. I don't

44:43

know. Another difference is that if I

44:45

decide to take out a loan, it's

44:47

not going to massively affect the UK

44:49

or another country. Whereas if the US

44:52

decides to massively increase its debt, that

44:54

would have global implications. Yeah, it's just

44:56

the scale of everything, isn't it? Me and

44:58

new borrowing does not impact our neighbour,

45:00

whereas government borrowing and spending

45:03

decisions affect the whole economy.

45:05

Government debt, its level, its structure,

45:07

its growth rate, that affects everything

45:09

from interest rates to inflation, to

45:11

investment to the exchange rate. It's

45:13

not something that acts in isolation

45:16

like me going and getting a

45:18

mortgage. And I think the reasons behind

45:20

government borrowing are different from

45:22

reasons for household borrowing. If I

45:24

borrow it, it's because I haven't got enough ready

45:26

cash. If the government borrows, it

45:29

could be because they're trying to

45:31

do something counter-cyclical. If there has been

45:33

a slowdown in growth, they may be trying

45:35

to stimulate the economy by borrowing. I think

45:38

that's a really good point. The rational course

45:40

of action is completely different. Opposite, you

45:42

might say. Like, if I as an

45:44

individual lose my job... It's sane and proper

45:46

to cut my spending, to cut my

45:49

cloth accordingly. Whereas if you think about the

45:51

government, if the economy tanks and lots

45:53

of people are losing their jobs, what

45:55

you want the government to do is

45:57

to boost spending and to stimulate demand.

46:00

This is what Keynesian economic says

46:02

at least. The government is acting

46:04

counter-cyclically, like you say. It's completely

46:06

the opposite to an individual. And

46:08

as a final point, whenever people

46:10

talk about having no debt, as

46:12

if that were a good thing,

46:14

remember that things like treasuries, UK

46:16

guilt actually form the lubricant for

46:18

the entire financial system, which really

46:20

wouldn't be able to run as

46:23

it exists now, without that very

46:25

safe debt. So just remember that

46:27

one of the side effects of

46:29

having a deficit and having an

46:31

outstanding debt is a good thing,

46:33

which is it makes the financial

46:35

system work. I mean it kind

46:37

of works, doesn't it? Close enough.

46:39

We're muddling through. Thank you for

46:42

joining us for many happy returns.

46:44

Keep sending us your questions, no

46:46

matter how dumb, at MHR at

46:48

pensioncraft.com. And do remember to check

46:50

out pensioncraft.com for all the information

46:52

about our membership courses and investment

46:54

coaching options. Many happy returns is

46:56

a pension craft production. Co-hosted and

46:58

executive produced by Romyn Akisa and

47:00

Michael Pew. This podcast is for

47:03

informational and entertainment purposes and is

47:05

not financial advice. We do not

47:07

provide recommendations or endorse any decision

47:09

to buy, sell or hold any

47:11

security. We cannot be held responsible

47:13

for any actions listeners may take,

47:15

and investors are encouraged to seek

47:17

independent financial advice.

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features