Episode Transcript
Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.
Use Ctrl + F to search
0:00
Work management platforms.
0:02
Ugh, endless onboarding,
0:04
IT bottlenecks, admin
0:06
requests. But what if
0:08
things were different? Monday.com
0:11
is different. No lengthy onboarding.
0:13
Beautiful reports in minutes. Custom
0:15
workflows, you can build on
0:18
your own. Easy to use
0:20
prompt free AI. Huh. Turns
0:22
out you can love a
0:25
work management platform. Monday.com, the
0:27
first work platform you'll love
0:29
to use. Welcome to the
0:31
New Books Network. Welcome to
0:34
the New Books Network. I'm your
0:36
host, Megan Cochran. Today I
0:38
welcome Don Moore and Max
0:41
Baserman to discuss their book,
0:43
Decision Leadership, empowering others
0:45
to make better choices. This is the
0:48
second book that they have co-authored
0:50
together. The first was in 2013,
0:52
called Judgment in Managerial Decision Making.
0:54
Don Moore is a professor at the
0:56
Haas School of Business at UC
0:58
Berkeley, where he is the Lorraine
1:00
Tyson Mitchell Chair in Leadership and
1:03
Communication. His research centers on leadership,
1:05
negotiation, overconfidence, that's my favorite thing,
1:07
and decision making. Max Bezerman is
1:09
a professor of business administration at
1:11
the Harvard Business School, as well
1:14
as an author and researcher and
1:16
researcher and researcher. His work focuses
1:18
on negotiation, behavioral economics, and ethics.
1:21
Before we get into the book, I want
1:23
to note for listeners that the
1:25
decision leadership book was originally
1:27
published in 2022 and released as
1:29
a hardcover, and it's being re-released
1:31
in April as a paperback. So
1:33
we could quibble a little bit about
1:35
the definition of new, but to me this
1:38
is an important and in some ways even
1:40
urgent topic, and the book has not been
1:42
discussed yet on the new book's network. So
1:44
I'm going to call it. new to us.
1:47
What I found particularly engaging
1:49
and important about the book is
1:51
that it shifts the criteria for
1:53
good decision, for good leadership, from
1:56
just making good decisions to helping
1:58
others make good decisions. Could you,
2:00
let's start with there, can
2:02
you explain why this is
2:05
so important and what does
2:07
it mean to make a
2:09
good decision? Wow, thanks, thanks
2:11
for inviting us on and
2:13
it is a delight to
2:16
be with you and to
2:18
talk about this book that
2:20
we had so much fun
2:22
writing and that conveys so
2:24
many messages that we feel
2:26
deeply about. It's important because
2:29
what makes leaders effective is
2:31
their ability to empower those
2:33
around them to act effectively,
2:35
choose wisely, and behave consistent
2:37
with their own values in
2:40
order to achieve success the
2:42
way that they define it.
2:44
Our book encourages people at
2:46
all levels of hierarchy and
2:48
in every walk of life
2:51
to think about the ways
2:53
in which they exert influence
2:55
on those around them, the
2:57
ways in which they can
2:59
structure the situation, making it
3:01
easy for others to choose
3:04
wisely and to be more
3:06
effective in their choices and
3:08
behaviors. I would say if
3:10
we, you know, go back
3:12
many decades and we thought
3:15
about it. typical organization. We
3:17
thought of an organization that
3:19
was had people physically doing
3:21
things. That's rarely the case.
3:23
Now most leaders are guiding
3:25
a large number of people
3:28
who are making lots of
3:30
decisions every day and we
3:32
see our leaders as having
3:34
responsibility for a decision factory
3:36
and we think that just
3:39
so much they can do
3:41
so much they can do.
3:43
to help people make wise
3:45
decisions. So let's go into
3:47
that a little bit. So
3:49
as a culture, and I'm
3:52
broadly talking here about Western
3:54
business culture, and I have
3:56
the original sin of an
3:58
NBA myself, so I put
4:00
myself in this in this
4:03
group too, we tend to
4:05
gravitate towards care as man.
4:07
persuasive and inspiring leaders. You
4:09
argue instead here for leaders
4:11
who build systems and processes,
4:14
and you particularly use this
4:16
term decision architecture, that guides
4:18
decisions more naturally and holistically.
4:20
Can you describe what you
4:22
mean by that approach? Sure.
4:24
We contrast that approach with
4:27
the more traditional view of
4:29
charismatic and persuasive leadership, as
4:31
you mentioned, Megan, where a
4:33
leader's job is to change
4:35
hearts and minds. That sounds
4:38
like hard work and evidence
4:40
suggests it is limited in
4:42
its transformative ability. By contrast,
4:44
changing people's behavior by structuring
4:46
their decisions, making defaults sensible,
4:48
and nudging people toward making
4:51
decisions that are in their
4:53
interest, and in the interest
4:55
of the system or the
4:57
people around them. that can
4:59
more powerfully influence behavior by
5:02
changing the situation rather than
5:04
trying to change the minds
5:06
of the people who are
5:08
making those decisions. So it
5:10
winds up a lighter touch
5:12
form of leadership in which
5:15
leaders are thinking about the
5:17
systems in which other people
5:19
operate, designing the default, designing...
5:21
the options from which people
5:23
choose rather than preaching to
5:26
them or telling them what
5:28
to do? All of what
5:30
God just said I would
5:32
say is what we encourage
5:34
doing it based on evidence
5:36
that's supported by research. I
5:39
think that the the the
5:41
structure of leadership that we're
5:43
outlining we think has a
5:45
much stronger empirical base than
5:47
many others. And I want
5:50
to come back... a little
5:52
bit later to this idea
5:54
of the power of the
5:56
situation. So I want to
5:58
put that a little bit
6:01
on ice for one minute
6:03
and we'll come back. I
6:05
love that there was a
6:07
chapter, a whole chapter called
6:09
guts versus brains and I'd
6:11
love it if you could
6:14
give us a little bit
6:16
of what you mean by
6:18
that. Sure, in that chapter
6:20
we are critical of theories
6:22
of leadership that posit some
6:25
sort of inherent ability that
6:27
some people are born with
6:29
that gives them leadership good
6:31
leadership instincts and the ability
6:33
to rely on their intuitions
6:35
to guide them to make
6:38
the right call in every
6:40
instance. We think it's dangerous
6:42
that people as they rise
6:44
in a hierarchy are inclined
6:46
to attribute to their own
6:49
brilliance and good intuitions, their
6:51
successes. I got here because
6:53
I'm so wonderful and my
6:55
gut always leads me in
6:57
the right direction. Nope. All
6:59
of us in leadership positions
7:02
ought to acknowledge the role
7:04
of happenstance and good fortune
7:06
in helping us get where
7:08
we are and be on
7:10
guard against our own propensity
7:13
to let our successes contribute
7:15
to our overconfident. reliance on
7:17
our own intuitive judgments. Instead,
7:19
as we rise in the
7:21
hierarchy, it becomes more and
7:23
more important for us to
7:26
open our minds to criticism,
7:28
open our hearts to hearing
7:30
the perspectives of those who
7:32
disagree with us, and considering
7:34
the possibility that we aren't
7:37
doing it right, that we
7:39
deserve to be corrected, and
7:41
that we deserve input from
7:43
others. So what that means
7:45
is that instead of relying...
7:48
on our gut intuitions that
7:50
instead we're thinking rigorously about
7:52
our decisions, relying as Max
7:54
said on the best evidence
7:56
available, when we don't have
7:58
that evidence already conducting experiments
8:01
or gathering evidence that helps
8:03
us make better evidence-based decisions,
8:05
and trying to get the
8:07
best of what our brains,
8:09
sometimes in dialogue with our
8:12
hearts, can tell us about
8:14
what we ought to do.
8:16
In that factor that you
8:18
mentioned, Megan, goes against the
8:20
grain of multiple best-selling books
8:22
where the authors want to
8:25
tell managers, you have great
8:27
intuition, trust it. And we
8:29
argue, we hope persuasively, that
8:31
the advice to trust your
8:33
gut is not very well
8:36
supported. And when we say
8:38
that, it's not that... Megan,
8:40
when I tell you your
8:42
intuition is limited, we're not
8:44
telling you that your inferior
8:46
in comparison to some external
8:49
benchmark. What we're saying is
8:51
that if we can help
8:53
you think systematically, on average,
8:55
you will make far, far
8:57
better decisions than if you
9:00
go with your intuitive response
9:02
to the situation. And unfortunately,
9:04
the authors who want to...
9:06
We believe falsely convey that
9:08
you can trust your God.
9:11
Have a large number of
9:13
managers out there who are
9:15
very happy to hear that
9:17
message. And what we need
9:19
to convey to them is,
9:21
again, we're not telling you
9:24
a bad intuition. We're just
9:26
telling you that your intuition
9:28
isn't as good as your
9:30
systematic thinking capabilities. Yes. All
9:32
of our intuition is imperfect
9:35
and having a sense of
9:37
where it's likely to lead
9:39
you astray is very helpful
9:41
for overriding those biased impulses
9:43
and doing better. should say,
9:45
I used to work, you
9:48
had examples I loved in
9:50
this section of the book.
9:52
There were some examples of
9:54
Jack Welch, which I was
9:56
giggling about, and then also
9:59
some examples for Netflix. I
10:01
happened to work at Netflix,
10:03
and we used to place
10:05
bets, not necessarily cash bets,
10:07
but sort of big cash
10:09
bets, on how we thought
10:12
the experiments would turn out.
10:14
And there was an interesting
10:16
part of this that dovetails
10:18
with the stories that you
10:20
tell in the book, which
10:23
is that part of that
10:25
process was for us to
10:27
get more confident, meaning know
10:29
when we were, when we,
10:31
our instincts were right and
10:33
also know when our instincts
10:36
were wrong, but also what
10:38
it did was make us
10:40
feel more in touch with
10:42
the risks of those experiments.
10:44
And so that wasn't the
10:47
example that you chose from
10:49
Netflix, but I thought it...
10:51
It's sort of fit in
10:53
with what you're saying, which
10:55
is it's not that you're
10:58
training yourself to trust your
11:00
gut every time. It's that
11:02
you're learning about when you
11:04
were right and when you
11:06
were wrong. And the fact
11:08
that there's uncertainty out there.
11:11
Correct. And it just isn't
11:13
reasonable for you to get
11:15
all of your predictions right
11:17
in understanding that we're making
11:19
decisions under uncertainty. I think
11:22
it's critical to... developing more
11:24
systematic ways to make more
11:26
good decisions over time. Yeah,
11:28
we had a little trope,
11:30
which I don't know if
11:32
they still do, but it
11:35
was like, if you're if
11:37
you're always right, then your
11:39
tests aren't good. You're just
11:41
testing the wrong thing. Uh-huh.
11:43
I'm a big fan of
11:46
keeping track and keeping score,
11:48
inviting people to be specific
11:50
about their predictions and forecasts
11:52
of how experiments will come
11:54
out. how products will perform
11:56
on the market, what the
11:59
economy is going to do
12:01
in the future, how employees
12:03
will perform once hired, and
12:05
writing down these predictions and
12:07
checking back later. to see
12:10
how the outcomes compare with
12:12
people's forecasts and that leaders
12:14
can help the people who
12:16
work with them better calibrate
12:18
their confidence judgments by helping
12:20
keep track and keep score.
12:23
So let's talk about one
12:25
of the other things that
12:27
you brought up in the
12:29
book, which is for the
12:31
leader of an organization to
12:34
be the investigator in chief.
12:36
What does that mean? look
12:38
to actively search for information
12:40
in places where it might
12:42
turn up. contrary evidence or
12:45
uncomfortable evidence that suggests that
12:47
all is not well or
12:49
that the organization might need
12:51
to rethink its approach. We
12:53
note the temptation for so
12:55
many leaders to turn a
12:58
blind eye to bad news
13:00
and unpleasant facts and that
13:02
ethical leadership demands a willingness
13:04
to investigate those trouble spots.
13:06
and understand the actual consequences
13:09
that their decisions are having.
13:11
So a couple bad kids
13:13
ago, I wrote a book
13:15
called Predictable Surprises with Michael
13:17
Watkins. And part of the
13:19
notion there is a lot
13:22
of the biggest disasters we
13:24
could think of. Leaders had
13:26
lots of hints available, but
13:28
they failed to investigate. And
13:30
there were people around them
13:33
who had the information that
13:35
could have changed. the destiny
13:37
of their company or society
13:39
in the case of 9-11.
13:41
And when leaders fail to
13:43
investigate, they put their organization
13:46
and society at risk. We
13:48
saw an example of that,
13:50
a particularly egregious example in
13:52
the case of the Israeli
13:54
Palestinian recent attacks there where
13:57
there was data there and
13:59
it wasn't investigated and that's
14:01
been coming out. recently, so
14:03
very timely application of that.
14:05
And certainly we play that
14:07
history and do better than
14:10
what happened. Exactly. I found
14:12
the chapter about calibrating confidence
14:14
to be particularly applicable. So
14:16
talk about little about the
14:18
risks of being under or
14:21
overconfident and how you can
14:23
sort of calibrate to find
14:25
the right balance there. So
14:27
I'm going to turn it
14:29
over to have done to
14:32
answer. I like the Dons,
14:34
the author of a book
14:36
called Perfectly Confident, and this
14:38
is truly is, I guess,
14:40
lots of expertise, but this
14:42
is his most, most deep
14:45
expertise is on the topic
14:47
of how to be well
14:49
calibrated. So I'm going to
14:51
just advertise for Don, shut
14:53
up. Thanks for seeing me
14:56
up, Max. Overconfidence and underconfidence
14:58
are both errors. With possibly
15:00
asymmetric consequences, overconfidence leads to
15:02
errors of commission, where we're
15:04
too bullish or optimistic about
15:06
our chances, and we enter
15:09
competitions that we will lose,
15:11
we invest in projects that
15:13
will fail, we say dumb
15:15
things that Other people do
15:17
not find this as funny
15:20
or worthwhile as we think
15:22
they are. It's turny time.
15:24
And with Van Dool's Dog
15:26
of the Day, you can
15:28
get a daily profit boost
15:30
storing the college conference championships
15:33
to bet on any underdog.
15:35
So get ready to celebrate
15:37
some upsets. No one saw
15:39
that coming. Except for me,
15:41
baby! 21 plus in President
15:44
Select States. Opt and required.
15:46
Minimum plus $100 required. Bonus
15:48
issued its non-buddrawable profit boost
15:50
tokens. Restrict and supply, including
15:52
token expiration and max-wager amount.
15:55
See terms of sportsbook.fandel.com. Gambling
15:57
problem? Call 1-800 gambler. Make
16:00
your next move with American
16:02
Express Business Platinum. Earn five
16:04
times membership rewards points on
16:07
flights and prepaid hotels hooked
16:09
on Amex Travel.com and with
16:11
a welcome offer of 150,000
16:13
points after you spend $20,000
16:16
on purchases on the card
16:18
within your first three months
16:20
of membership your business can
16:22
soar to new heights. Terms
16:25
apply. Learn more at American
16:27
Express.com/business dash Platinum. Amex Business
16:29
Platinum. Built for business by
16:31
American Express. And those are
16:34
often more salient. It's easy
16:36
to point to high profile
16:38
errors that overconfident leaders have
16:40
made, leading their organizations to
16:42
disaster everything from ill-conceived product
16:45
launches and acquisitions to poorly
16:47
designed products and tone deaf
16:49
initiatives. On the flip side,
16:51
underconfidence is also a mistake.
16:54
Underconfidence is more likely to
16:56
lead to errors of omission
16:58
where you decline opportunities that
17:00
would have led to success.
17:03
The imposter syndrome is relevant
17:05
here, circumstances in which we
17:07
think we're not good enough,
17:09
and so we decline opportunities
17:12
that would work out or
17:14
where we would have been
17:16
successful. And both are errors,
17:18
both overconfidence and underconfidence and
17:21
In my book, I enthusiastically
17:23
endorse the strategy of aiming
17:25
to be well calibrated. Believe
17:27
the truth. And then that
17:29
raises the thorny and complicated
17:32
question of, well, what's the
17:34
truth when we're talking about
17:36
a forecast of an uncertain
17:38
future? And I argue emphatically
17:41
for thinking wisely about probabilities
17:43
and expected value that It
17:45
can be perfectly rational and
17:47
well calibrated to take a
17:50
big risk. on a low
17:52
probability but high payoff project,
17:54
where you recognize there's only
17:56
a tiny chance that this
17:59
is actually going to work.
18:01
But if it does, it
18:03
would be amazing. That can
18:05
still be perfectly sensible. And
18:08
there are such risks in
18:10
life. On the other hand,
18:12
being realistic about the upsides
18:14
and downsides of the risks
18:16
that we're taking, when the
18:19
downside includes tragedies that put
18:21
people's lives at risk or...
18:23
put society at risk, then
18:25
more caution is warranted and
18:28
thinking carefully about even low
18:30
probability risks is absolutely necessary.
18:32
I want to come back
18:34
to this idea of a
18:37
decision-making architecture and you bring
18:39
in many different aspects of
18:41
decision science and behavioral economics,
18:43
which I thought were amazing
18:46
and very good, it was
18:48
sort of a very good
18:50
way of getting getting grounded
18:52
in some of those concepts.
18:55
I'd love to go through
18:57
a few of them and
18:59
just talk about how you,
19:01
you know, what is the
19:03
element and then how do
19:06
you, how they can be
19:08
used. So I'd love to
19:10
start with nudges. I think
19:12
people roughly know what a
19:15
nudge is. I mean, if
19:17
you live in New York
19:19
City, everybody knows that a
19:21
nudge is, but if you,
19:24
you know, most people know
19:26
what it is, but what
19:28
does it mean in this
19:30
is in science and behavioral
19:33
economics, and how can the
19:35
leaders use these to create
19:37
that architecture that you're talking
19:39
about? You want to take
19:42
this field? that used to
19:44
be part of psychology and
19:46
seemed to move into the
19:48
world of behavioral economics, where
19:50
we did a phenomenal job
19:53
of understanding the systematic and
19:55
predictable biases that humans make.
19:57
This is particularly important, very
19:59
relevant in our book. And
20:02
it's important that not just
20:04
that people make mistakes, but
20:06
that they're predictable and systematic,
20:08
which means we can predict
20:11
them, we can coach people
20:13
to do better, we can anticipate
20:15
them. And a long time, Dick
20:17
Taylor and Cass Sunstein, who laid
20:20
a book called Nudge, which
20:22
is an important kind of
20:24
next generation book in terms
20:27
of saying, if we know
20:29
how people make systematic and
20:32
predictable errors. We can design
20:34
the environment to increase select
20:37
because they will make both
20:39
better decisions, more ethical decisions,
20:41
decisions that are better for
20:44
the overall environment. So we
20:46
have just lots of examples
20:48
in terms of changing the
20:51
default. So one of their
20:53
classic examples has to do
20:55
with the fact that prior
20:58
to their work, lots of
21:00
people who were offered very
21:02
attractive matching plans on their
21:05
retirement program at work simply
21:07
didn't sign up. And Phelan Sain
21:09
asked us, well, if you're a
21:11
really good organization and you want
21:13
to help your employees, instead of
21:16
making them sign up, why don't
21:18
you just put them in the system
21:20
and allow them to sign
21:22
out? And we find that
21:24
we can get dramatic improvements
21:27
in retirement savings rates. by
21:29
changing what the default looks
21:31
like. So the field kind
21:33
of shifted from simply identifying
21:36
what are the cognitive
21:39
patterns that are interesting
21:41
to describe to saying how
21:43
do we change behavior by
21:46
using this. social science of
21:48
how we make decisions to
21:50
design environments that we can
21:52
predict people are likely to
21:54
make, again, better, more ethical
21:56
and more societyally beneficial decisions.
21:58
And it's kind of a major
22:00
contribution to the literature, but
22:02
also I would say the
22:04
key bridge between going from
22:06
this descriptive research to a
22:08
prescriptive perspective on how to
22:11
make the world better. And
22:13
not long after they wrote
22:15
a book, a group in
22:17
London connected to the British
22:19
government called behavioral insights team,
22:21
sometimes called the Nudge Unit,
22:23
really became masters at putting
22:25
this into practice where they
22:27
would run literally hundreds of
22:29
experiments on how to make
22:31
government work more effectively. And
22:34
part of this movement, which
22:36
may come out of the
22:38
earlier decision literature, is that
22:40
most proponents of the Nudge
22:42
framework. believed in empirical testing.
22:44
That is, we might make
22:46
some inference about how to
22:48
do this, but given that
22:50
we're moving into the field,
22:52
we're moving into a unique
22:55
setting, instead of rolling this
22:57
out on 100 million Americans,
22:59
maybe we can first test
23:01
it on 10,000 and see
23:03
what happens. So this notion
23:05
of using behavioral science, designing
23:07
interventions to make better decisions,
23:09
and testing, became all very
23:11
important in core parts of
23:13
the nudge world. Another concept,
23:16
and we just came up
23:18
a little bit earlier, I
23:20
wanted to come back to
23:22
it, is what you call
23:24
the power of the situation.
23:26
And part of that is
23:28
the debate about whether situations
23:30
or dispositions are more deterministic
23:32
in how people are going
23:34
to behave. So talk a
23:36
little bit about what that
23:39
means and then what you
23:41
learn. Yeah, our consideration of
23:43
this issue reflects a long-standing
23:45
discussion in psychology. between the
23:47
social psychologists and the personality
23:49
psychologists, just to simplify the
23:51
camps here, on what best
23:53
human behavior. Is it that
23:55
there are some people who
23:57
are outgoing and talkative and
24:00
some people who are shy
24:02
introverts and that explains who
24:04
speaks up or who initiates
24:06
conversation with others or are
24:08
there social situations in which
24:10
everybody regardless of how extroverted
24:12
tends to keep to themselves?
24:14
an elevator with strangers, or
24:16
other social situations when everybody,
24:18
no matter how shy and
24:21
introverted, will chat with people
24:23
who they've just met, parties.
24:25
And if you want to
24:27
try to account for the
24:29
variance in behavior, the... You
24:31
can argue about whether the
24:33
glasses have fuller glasses have
24:35
empty if you want to
24:37
give personality a fair shot
24:39
and try to predict how
24:42
people will behave based on
24:44
how they answer personality surveys.
24:46
Max and I come down
24:48
more on the situational side
24:50
of this discussion being persuaded
24:52
by the evidence on the
24:54
power of situations to change
24:56
behavior. That accounts for a
24:58
whole lot of the variants
25:00
that we observe. Personality is
25:02
a real thing. People differ
25:05
and it does influence behavior,
25:07
but more often we observe
25:09
situations as powerful influences and
25:11
when personality matters it's more
25:13
often in interaction with the
25:15
situation. What that means for
25:17
nudging people toward good decisions
25:19
and executing effective decision leadership
25:21
is that as the leader
25:23
you often have an enormous
25:26
amount of power to change
25:28
the situation. One example that
25:30
we use in the book,
25:32
connecting to Max's earlier question
25:34
to your question about Nudges,
25:36
or Max's answer to your
25:38
question about Nudges, is the
25:40
work of Jesse Wisdom at
25:42
Google, where they. tried to
25:44
use simple insights from situational
25:47
effects on behavior to influence,
25:49
say, the way Googleers ate
25:51
in the cafeteria, putting the
25:53
desserts at the back in
25:55
opaque containers, not removing them,
25:57
but just making them less
25:59
tempting and obvious. Google was
26:01
paying for people's food and
26:03
paying for their health care.
26:05
So had a strong incentive
26:07
to help Googleers eat more
26:10
healthfully. And small changes in
26:12
cafeteria and menu design helped
26:14
them support the healthy choices
26:16
of their employees. You talk
26:18
a little bit about, well,
26:20
I'm actually, I'm going to
26:22
go back on myself. So,
26:24
um, You've used a bunch
26:26
of examples about how people
26:28
have used these, but I
26:31
would love for you to
26:33
talk a little bit more
26:35
about a leader influencing like
26:37
their managerial staff to make
26:39
decisions. Can you talk a
26:41
little bit more about some
26:43
of those examples that are
26:45
maybe not obvious for people
26:47
who are actually like in
26:49
a corporate, we're really talking
26:52
about sort of corporate or
26:54
organizational environments. What are some
26:56
of those levers that a
26:58
leader has to use the
27:00
nudges and the power of
27:02
the situation to create that
27:04
framework that you discuss? Yeah,
27:06
so let me go back
27:08
to the behavioral insights team
27:10
in the UK. So basically
27:12
they were appointed for a
27:15
very limited period of time
27:17
by David Cameron in the
27:19
UK government and they were
27:21
charged with producing that you
27:23
can on the government's investment
27:25
in creating the unit. So
27:27
the first place that they
27:29
started was collecting more taxes.
27:31
So if people pay their
27:33
taxes more, people can see
27:36
a relatively clear benefit and
27:38
they got far more than
27:40
a tenfold return on the
27:42
initial. investment. And then all
27:44
of a sudden, lots of
27:46
different government agencies were interested
27:48
in getting their constituents to
27:50
get back to work faster,
27:52
to show up for their
27:54
health care exam, and we
27:57
can go on and on
27:59
and on. And what David
28:01
Halper and the leader of
28:03
the behavioral institute seemed ill
28:05
along with a very talented
28:07
staff was create a different
28:09
norm among leaders within the
28:11
British government. So instead of
28:13
trying, all of a sudden
28:15
instead of trying to sell
28:17
them on will you let
28:20
us run an experiment, they
28:22
had large numbers of people
28:24
coming to them saying we
28:26
need your help to figure
28:28
out how to run an
28:30
experiment. So they changed the
28:32
culture about the idea of
28:34
using psychology, behavior, economics and
28:36
nudges to think systematically about
28:38
what are the changes that
28:41
we can make, that can
28:43
make government more effective. In
28:45
the process, it became phenomenally
28:47
successful. You might recall David
28:49
Cameron was a big fan
28:51
of privatizing. aspects of government
28:53
and one of the things
28:55
that was privatized was the
28:57
behavioral insights team. So they
28:59
went off of making a
29:02
consulting firm one-third owned by
29:04
the British government and basically
29:06
spread their word across the
29:08
world in many ways. Thank
29:10
you. I want to ask
29:12
about another element that I,
29:14
it seems obvious but I
29:16
was impressed by the surprising
29:18
nuance of it and that
29:20
is how leaders can determine
29:22
how to incorporate insights from
29:25
others into their decision-making and
29:27
how they can learn when
29:29
to trust their own judgment.
29:31
When do you incorporate and
29:33
when do you trust? Well,
29:35
I think we tend to
29:37
under-trust the judgment. of others.
29:39
So Don's been part of
29:41
a literature on to what
29:43
degree do we pay attention
29:46
to other people's judgment. So
29:48
if you take a very
29:50
simple context of you estimate
29:52
something and you're told someone
29:54
who has equal talent is
29:56
you, you told their estimate,
29:58
what weight should you put
30:00
on your own judgment? persons,
30:02
what weight should you put
30:04
out of people's judgment? And
30:07
many researchers, including Don, have
30:09
found that we tend to
30:11
overweight our own judgment and
30:13
then underweight the judgment of
30:15
others, and we could perform
30:17
more effectively if we more
30:19
seriously considered their weight. In
30:21
simple version, if you're, if
30:23
the other person knows roughly
30:25
as much as you do,
30:28
averaging the two is going
30:30
to do better than either
30:32
deferring to them, I'm using
30:34
your own judgment. A colleague,
30:36
Duke, Rick Leric, has shown
30:38
basically the wisdom of small
30:40
crowds. So a lot of
30:42
people know the argument of
30:44
the wisdom of crowds, if
30:46
you have a thousand people,
30:48
estimates and surprisingly good, because
30:51
they all have the same
30:53
signal. and the errors are
30:55
both high and low, so
30:57
on average they do pretty
30:59
well, which provides really convincing
31:01
evidence that there's a wisdom
31:03
of small selected crowds. So
31:05
if instead of getting a
31:07
thousand people, you've got five
31:09
smart people within your own
31:12
firm who view the same
31:14
task. If you're making an
31:16
important assessment of what will
31:18
sales be next year or
31:20
what is this claim worth
31:22
in an insurance context, five
31:24
smart people and then averaging
31:26
them is going to do
31:28
remarkably well better than the
31:30
randomly sought person who happens.
31:33
have that task, yet people
31:35
don't use these tolls of
31:37
paying attention to the assessments
31:39
of others as much as
31:41
they should. A few additional
31:43
thoughts on that. I agree
31:45
with everything that Max has
31:47
noted there. Organizations can take
31:49
better advantage of exactly the
31:51
dynamics that Max is talking
31:53
about by aggregating judgments, having
31:56
people. make forecasts or bets,
31:58
and reduce the need for
32:00
meeting to discuss it. I
32:02
think it's pretty common for
32:04
organizations to rely too heavily
32:06
on meetings, where you get
32:08
together to talk about something.
32:10
Just to pick a stylized
32:12
example, the organization has to
32:14
choose path A or path
32:17
B. Which way are we
32:19
going to turn at this
32:21
strategic intersection? so you get
32:23
together to talk about it.
32:25
And too often those discussions
32:27
are dominated by the highest
32:29
paid person in the room
32:31
and there's basically one brain
32:33
in operation and people line
32:35
up behind the boss. You
32:38
have sacrificed the wisdom of
32:40
the crowd by lining everyone
32:42
up behind the boss, and
32:44
turning the crowd into a
32:46
mob, where errors are correlated
32:48
too strongly with the person
32:50
who's ready to assert their
32:52
will, and talk over others.
32:54
Instead, if you elicit independent
32:56
predictions... from a large group
32:58
or maybe a small select
33:01
group as Max suggests, that
33:03
can provide guidance where what
33:05
they're predicting is, okay, well,
33:07
what's going to happen if
33:09
we pick path A? What's
33:11
going to happen if we
33:13
pick path B? Every decision
33:15
depends on a forecast of
33:17
its consequences. And you got
33:19
to pick the right outcome.
33:22
What do we care about
33:24
predicting in path A versus
33:26
path B? But gathering people...
33:28
independent judgments can be very
33:30
helpful. Sometimes that by itself
33:32
will point the way toward
33:34
a clear decision. Sometimes there
33:36
may be issues to be
33:38
worked out by talking about
33:40
those consequences and elaborating on
33:43
the initial guesses that people
33:45
have made. But as a
33:47
rule organizations take too little
33:49
advantage of those sorts of
33:51
prediction markets and rely too
33:53
heavily on meetings for working
33:55
out decisions. I can give
33:57
an interesting example of this.
33:59
So about a decade ago,
34:01
I had the wonderful opportunity
34:03
of working on a consulting
34:06
project with Danny Cunningham, and
34:08
the client was an insurance
34:10
company, and we were doing
34:12
work on helping them make
34:14
better decisions and negotiate claims
34:16
more fairly and more efficiently
34:18
and reducing legal costs. And
34:20
at some point... We were
34:22
invited to a meeting of
34:24
what they called a roundtable,
34:27
and a roundtable was to
34:29
have someone who had a
34:31
large claim, perhaps tens of
34:33
millions of dollars. And before
34:35
they started negotiating over the
34:37
claim, they wanted to make
34:39
sure that they had a
34:41
good assessment of what was
34:43
a fair amount to pay
34:45
on the claim. And we
34:48
thought, well, that's interesting. They're
34:50
going to put people together.
34:52
And we were very much
34:54
thinking... along the lines of
34:56
Don just outlined, well, it's
34:58
quite useful to have, you
35:00
know, a dozen different experts
35:02
independently, it's us to claim.
35:04
And what we immediately saw
35:06
to our horror was that
35:08
the person with the claim
35:11
presented the story in detail
35:13
and then told everybody what
35:15
they thought it was worth
35:17
and then turned around and
35:19
said, what do the rest
35:21
of you think that this
35:23
is worth? Kind of just
35:25
eliminating the whole power. of
35:27
getting advice from others by
35:29
creating that of anchor and
35:32
it wasn't hard to do
35:34
some demonstrations to convince this
35:36
organization that they could make
35:38
some very mild changes in
35:40
what a roundtable look like
35:42
to make it more effective
35:44
following the advice of Don
35:46
Outline for you. Yeah, it's
35:48
really great. This was the
35:50
part of it that I
35:53
found really nuanced and just
35:55
as a side I worked
35:57
in a situation once where
35:59
the... management team that I
36:01
was part of like to
36:03
do what they called getting
36:05
everyone's input. But the way
36:07
that that happened was very
36:09
similar to this where everyone
36:11
went in and everyone was
36:14
trying to guess what the
36:16
decision maker was wanted and
36:18
so then what actually came
36:20
out was not what they
36:22
actually thought, but what they
36:24
thought someone else wanted. And
36:26
so it is very new.
36:28
It's not just about getting
36:30
a bunch of smart people
36:32
in a room. That's really
36:34
not the point. I think
36:37
you make this very clear
36:39
in the book, but I
36:41
love that you are able
36:43
to bring that out here
36:45
in this discussion. It's not
36:47
just a bunch of smart
36:49
people in a room following
36:51
a methodology that allows each
36:53
of their separate opinions and
36:55
biases and insights. to reflect
36:58
individually and then you're putting
37:00
those together afterwards, not guessing.
37:02
And that allows for decision
37:04
leadership. Yes, what's the role
37:06
of the leader there aside
37:08
from setting a structure? What
37:10
do they do that? The
37:12
leader should not be driving
37:14
some political agenda that everybody
37:16
else is trying to guess.
37:19
The leader who wants to
37:21
get good information in order
37:23
to inform wise decisions should
37:25
seek the truth. And if
37:27
they suspect, as they often
37:29
have good reason to suspect,
37:31
that what they say is
37:33
likely to influence others, they
37:35
should want to collect independent
37:37
judgments first. And here we
37:39
might think of the Delphi
37:42
method that the Rand Corporation
37:44
developed, where you first collect
37:46
independent guesses from some group.
37:48
Then maybe you share those
37:50
averages, maybe allow the group
37:52
to update their perspectives, and
37:54
at some point maybe it's
37:56
necessary to get together. If
37:58
you do get together to
38:00
talk, the responsible leader who
38:03
wants to get information out
38:05
of the people who are
38:07
there will start by having
38:09
the... lowest ranked person present
38:11
speak first with the leader
38:13
reserving judgment and holding their
38:15
tongue until everyone else has
38:17
had a chance to weigh
38:19
in such that you don't
38:21
get everyone just complying with
38:24
whatever the leader recommended. Right.
38:26
I want to move on
38:28
a little bit to the
38:30
negotiation some of the negotiation
38:32
pieces that are in here
38:34
and I'm going to start
38:36
and just. ask you to
38:38
talk a little bit about
38:40
the myth of the fixed
38:42
pie mindset and how breaking
38:44
away from that can improve
38:47
negotiations. But then, you know,
38:49
if there's other stuff you
38:51
want to bring in, go
38:53
for it. That's just the
38:55
piece I wanted to make
38:57
sure got covered there. Wow.
38:59
And do I get to
39:01
advertise the fact that I
39:03
just published a new book
39:05
on negotiation called Negotiation the
39:08
Game is Change. And so
39:10
I think I'll take that
39:12
question because I may or
39:14
may not have been the
39:16
person who first use the
39:18
term the mythical Fix Five.
39:20
But the basic idea here
39:22
is that in teaching executive
39:24
programs at Northwestern and now
39:26
at Harvard, one of the
39:29
amazing things that happens is
39:31
that you get sort of
39:33
fascinating executives with, you know,
39:35
successful careers who think that
39:37
they are good negotiators and
39:39
you give them a relatively
39:41
straightforward exercise. where one person
39:43
cares more about one issue
39:45
and another person cares more
39:47
about another issue. And rather
39:49
than trade off, they compromise
39:52
on each issue. And the
39:54
reason that they miss the
39:56
opportunity to trade off the
39:58
two issues isn't because they
40:00
don't want to. They've literally
40:02
never thought about the idea.
40:04
of growing the pie through
40:06
trade-offs across time. And so
40:08
one of the things that
40:10
happens to these executives and
40:13
negotiation training at any good
40:15
business school is that they
40:17
learn to bust the mythical
40:19
fixed pie and we provide
40:21
them techniques for finding gains
40:23
from trade. And it's not
40:25
just uncomplicated business decisions. But
40:27
when Marla and I go
40:29
out to dinner, I'm married
40:31
to Marla for approximately forever.
40:34
Oh, when we go out
40:36
to dinner, sometimes we'll compromise.
40:38
And then over dinner, because
40:40
she'll want kind of fancy
40:42
Northern Italian and I'll want
40:44
a pizza and we'll compromise
40:46
on Southern Italian and over
40:48
dinner, we'll talk about what
40:50
movie to watch after dinner
40:52
and she'll want some artsy
40:54
film and I'll want some
40:57
comedy, so we'll settle on
40:59
a drama. But after we're
41:01
all done, we find that
41:03
Marla cared more about the
41:05
movie choice and I cared
41:07
more about the dinner choice.
41:09
And there was a better
41:11
evening involved by busting the
41:13
mythical Fix Five and finding
41:15
those kinds of tradeoffs. So
41:18
for me, this is such
41:20
a critical topic in negotiation
41:22
because there's literally millions of
41:24
dollars on the ground that
41:26
no one's picking up. because
41:28
they're not finding these trades
41:30
and it permeates all of
41:32
our ongoing negotiation relationships and
41:34
it permeates all of our
41:36
personal relationships where we can
41:39
simply do better if we
41:41
try to maximize the collective
41:43
benefit. But in order to
41:45
do that we need to
41:47
understand that that's even possible
41:49
and it is almost any
41:51
time we're negotiating two or
41:53
more ships. So if I'm
41:55
negotiating with the car dealer
41:57
over a specific car, there
42:00
isn't necessarily room for game.
42:02
for trade, but for the
42:04
important negotiations that your listeners
42:06
are involved in, there's typically
42:08
more going on in finding
42:10
those trades becomes critical to
42:12
finding wise agreements. And the
42:14
term mythical really just highlights
42:16
the fact that people are
42:18
walking around with a bad
42:20
assumption about how to create
42:23
value or negotiation. underscore and
42:25
amplify Max's point by stating
42:27
something implicit in what he
42:29
just said, and that is
42:31
that by making wiser trades
42:33
in negotiation, the parties involved
42:35
create value. They make the
42:37
world better off by helping
42:39
each other achieve more of
42:41
what they care about. And
42:44
that is a powerful analogy
42:46
to the message that we're
42:48
trying to deliver in this
42:50
book. They're better. and worse
42:52
ways to support others' decision-making.
42:54
And we're seeking approaches that
42:56
leave people, organizations, and societies
42:58
in aggregate better off by
43:00
helping people achieve those things
43:02
that they care about most
43:05
at lower cost to them
43:07
and the institutions that they're
43:09
a part of. I think
43:11
this is such a powerful
43:13
idea. I really came away
43:15
from this part of the
43:17
book, excited about what you
43:19
were saying. And I would
43:21
like to give a gift
43:23
from my parents, who I
43:25
just imagine everything my parents
43:28
ever say is like old
43:30
Jewish people, you know, like,
43:32
what do they do? But
43:34
my parents once gave me,
43:36
they never give advice. They're
43:38
very good about not putting
43:40
their nose in there. But
43:42
they gave me one piece
43:44
of marriage advice, which is
43:46
just ask, every time, how
43:49
important is this to you?
43:51
That's terrific. Yeah. And so
43:53
when they make a decision,
43:55
they always say, they always
43:57
say, Well, okay, we're going
43:59
to decide about where we're
44:01
going for dinner. And they
44:03
use numbers, scale one to
44:05
ten. This is a five
44:07
for me. This is an
44:10
eight for me. And then
44:12
they... negotiate. Now, of course,
44:14
when they're feeling bad, when
44:16
they're feeling angry, whatever, they're
44:18
like, it's Jen, you know,
44:20
but for the most part,
44:22
they've agreed to use that.
44:24
And I always thought that
44:26
was great advice. So this
44:28
is my gift from my
44:30
parents to you. I like
44:33
that. Thank you. Are they
44:35
looking for jobs as negotiation
44:37
teachers? Thank them from us.
44:39
Yeah. Maybe we'll get them
44:41
to finally listen to one
44:43
of my episodes. Okay, I
44:45
want to move on a
44:47
little bit to ethical decision-making.
44:49
And so can you talk
44:51
a little bit about how
44:54
leaders can create environments that
44:56
promote that ethical behavior? And
44:58
I think maybe even more
45:00
important in some ways, but
45:02
some of the common pitfalls
45:04
that undermine ethical decision-making. One
45:06
common ethical pitfall that we
45:08
highlight in the book is
45:10
a leader who guide there.
45:12
subordinates or their reports by
45:15
saying do whatever it takes
45:17
to achieve some outcome. That
45:19
instruction too often turns a
45:21
blind eye to the ethical
45:23
consequences of what it would
45:25
take to achieve some level
45:27
of profitability, for instance, that
45:29
there are approaches that would
45:31
necessitate cutting ethical corners, that
45:33
the boss may be unwilling
45:35
to endorse and even uncomfortable
45:38
with, but by saying do
45:40
whatever it takes is implicitly
45:42
recommending that others shoulder that
45:44
ethical burden and violate their
45:46
own ethical standards in order
45:48
to fudge the numbers or
45:50
shift the revenues from some
45:52
future quarter into this quarter
45:54
to make the numbers look
45:56
better and we recommend instead.
45:59
that ethical leaders not say
46:01
to do whatever it is.
46:03
and instead empower those with
46:05
whom they're working to give
46:07
voice to their own ethical
46:09
concerns and express doubts about
46:11
the viability of stretch goals
46:13
or unrealistic ambitions when that
46:15
implies breaking the rules or
46:17
violating their own ethical principles
46:20
to do so. If you
46:22
think back to that steroid
46:24
era of either baseball or
46:26
cycling... The press liked to
46:28
focus on who the players
46:30
were or who the riders
46:32
were who used steroids and
46:34
got caught. And I don't
46:36
mean to take them off
46:38
of the hook. They broke
46:40
the rolls. I don't think
46:43
that they should have done
46:45
that. But I think that
46:47
the far more guilty parties
46:49
were the leaders who were
46:51
rewarding people for home runs
46:53
under any circumstances. and were
46:55
not enforcing the rules in
46:57
any way. So, you know,
46:59
the baseball commissioner's office and
47:01
the teams were rewarding people
47:04
for taking steroids, and then
47:06
when eventually the media catches
47:08
up and finds a specific
47:10
instance, the leaders are saying
47:12
bad, bad player, when in
47:14
fact, they had created the
47:16
environment. And that's... where we're
47:18
saying the situation is so
47:20
important. So you can kind
47:22
of see so much of
47:25
human behaviors being guided by
47:27
the situations that leaders create,
47:29
including ethical behavior. Max wrote
47:31
a very important book called
47:33
Noticing, and here this is
47:35
one of the circumstances where
47:37
ethical and responsible leaders will
47:39
notice the consequences for the
47:41
incentives that they set up
47:43
and the consequences of turning
47:46
a blind eye to cheating
47:48
in various forms, whether that's
47:50
taking steroids or massaging the
47:52
accounting numbers. But we're getting
47:54
near the end of our
47:56
time. I want to ask
47:58
you to summarize. our listeners,
48:00
the most important things that
48:02
you want to take them to, want
48:04
them to take away from your book.
48:07
We've said it in various forms
48:09
throughout our conversation, but we
48:11
want people to see themselves
48:13
as decision leaders, helping those
48:15
around them make better decisions.
48:17
Better decisions by their own
48:19
standards of what they care
48:21
about and better decisions according
48:23
to their own ethical compasses.
48:25
And there's more opportunity to
48:28
make positive change than most
48:30
of us realize. And maybe you
48:32
can tell us a little bit
48:34
about what's next for each of you.
48:36
I enjoyed implementing some of the
48:38
book's lessons in my leadership role
48:41
here at the School of Business
48:43
and having stepped back from my
48:45
service in the dean's office. I
48:48
am excited to be returning to
48:50
the classroom and sharing some of
48:52
those lessons to empower my students.
48:55
to be decision leaders. So
48:57
I'm currently spending some time
48:59
doing podcasts on negotiation. The
49:02
game has changed. And I've
49:04
recently finished up a book
49:06
called Inside an academic scandal
49:09
for your listeners who have
49:11
been following some of the
49:14
recent social science problems having
49:16
to do with data fabrication.
49:18
I happen to be an
49:21
author of the... pretty famous
49:23
paper that's known to be fraudulent.
49:26
And I've written a book
49:28
that describes in detail how
49:30
that could come about and
49:32
how we might reform social
49:34
science to improve its integrity
49:37
moving forward. Thank you both.
49:39
And my favorite part of everyone
49:41
is what books do you want
49:43
to recommend to our listeners? Are
49:45
we allowed to be self-serving and to our
49:48
own horns? I was going to pick
49:50
your book, don't I? Well, then, I'll
49:52
tell people that they should read negotiation,
49:54
the game has changed. I've made it
49:56
required reading in my negotiations class that
49:58
I'm teaching right now. fantastic. And
50:00
what's what's What's your What's your
50:02
perfectly confident by I guess
50:05
it's perfectly All right. by Don
50:07
Moore. Sorry, got it. All That
50:09
was that equitable. Every every
50:11
equity Thank you very much. So
50:13
Don Moore and Max Moore it
50:15
has been a huge pleasure been
50:17
a with you today about decision
50:19
leadership, empowering others to make
50:21
better choices. Thank you both
50:23
for joining us on you both for
50:25
joining Thank you. Thank you, books network.
50:27
Thank you.
Podchaser is the ultimate destination for podcast data, search, and discovery. Learn More