Episode Transcript
Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.
Use Ctrl + F to search
0:00
The rising inequality and
0:02
growing political instability that we
0:04
see today are the direct
0:06
result of decades of bad
0:08
economic theory. The last five
0:10
decades of trickle-down
0:13
economics haven't worked. But
0:15
what's the alternative? Middle-out economics
0:17
is the answer. Because the
0:19
middle class is the source
0:21
of growth, not its consequence.
0:23
That's right. This
0:29
is Pitchfork Economics
0:31
with Nick Hanauer,
0:33
a podcast about
0:35
how to build
0:37
the economy from the
0:40
middle out. Welcome to
0:42
the show. On today's
0:44
podcast, Nick, we're going
0:47
to be talking to
0:49
a white male economist
0:52
from Harvard, which... I
0:54
really get gets into the
0:57
core topic of the conversation
0:59
today. Yeah, absolutely. We
1:01
are going to talk to
1:03
a white male economist from
1:06
Harvard. But our guest today
1:08
is a swell guy named
1:10
David. Despite all that, you're
1:13
telling me. David Deming, who
1:15
joins his day because he
1:17
wrote an article recently in
1:20
Atlantic where he insists that
1:22
Big Econ, much like corporate
1:24
monopolies, have become two. too
1:27
concentrated, too centralized stifling innovation,
1:29
and it's become a profession
1:31
that rather than challenging
1:34
the status quo
1:36
reinforces it. And we
1:38
couldn't agree more. Well, we
1:40
know this. We could ask
1:43
Ashley and Freddie about this,
1:45
our producers. We make an
1:47
effort. to try to have a
1:49
diverse list of guests on this
1:52
show and it's yeah it's not
1:54
easy much easier if this was
1:56
a physics or chemistry or any
1:59
other or medical podcast you know,
2:01
medical research podcast, then it is
2:04
with an economics podcast. That's right.
2:06
Because the profession is the least
2:08
diverse, if you consider it a
2:11
science, it's the least diverse of
2:13
the sciences and across the board
2:15
in every aspect. And as David
2:18
points out in his piece in
2:20
the Atlantic, which I think is
2:22
titled Break Up Big Econ. It's
2:25
concentrated, the leaders of the field
2:27
are concentrated around a handful of
2:29
elite universities. Harvard, where he is being
2:32
one of them. Yeah. And you know, I think
2:34
there have definitely been some downsides of
2:36
that. But with that, let's talk
2:38
to David, and we'll find out more.
2:43
My name is David Deming. I am
2:45
the Isabel and Scott Black Professor
2:48
of Political Economy at the Harvard
2:50
Kennedy School. I'm an economist. I
2:52
study labor markets, skills, technology, education,
2:54
future of work, AI, and all
2:56
things in between. You're one of
2:58
those Harvard economists, so that makes
3:00
you a member of the concentrated
3:02
elite, right? I suppose it does.
3:04
Yeah. I don't feel that way,
3:06
but you know, that's what's funny
3:08
about something like this is, you
3:10
know, I mean, I'm just, like
3:12
many of us in these positions,
3:14
they're just kind of a regular
3:16
guy who found himself here. So
3:18
I don't think very few people
3:20
who are in the quote unquote
3:22
elite feel as though they are.
3:24
Yeah, we're just, we're just three,
3:26
you know, white men, not part of
3:29
the elite, talking about the
3:31
discipline of economics. or you
3:33
know whatever orthodox you know
3:35
the orthodox the anyway and
3:38
you know one of the
3:40
really interesting angles that you
3:42
take and that we I
3:44
suppose we had not really
3:47
considered is how concentrated it
3:49
is how dominated it is
3:51
by relatively few institutions and
3:54
people and in particular how
3:56
different that is from the
3:58
other sciences so So for our
4:00
listeners to talk a little bit about
4:03
that and try to compare and contrast.
4:05
Sure. Well, I should say that one
4:07
of the reasons that the economics discipline
4:09
is concentrated is because economists do research
4:12
that's increasingly empirical, and that was the
4:14
topic of my column that we can
4:16
be talking about later, but relative to,
4:19
let's say, an engineer. or hard scientists
4:21
of any kind that has a lab
4:23
and materials. You know, economists' work is
4:25
much less capital intensive, and so it's
4:28
easier to move. So that's one reason
4:30
why economists are more concentrated, just to
4:32
be, I think fair and transparent about
4:34
that is that you see a lot
4:36
of patterns of people who start off
4:39
in departments that are not at the
4:41
very top who, you know, show their
4:43
ability to publish in top journals and
4:45
get grants and get cited and influence
4:47
the field and they end up. ranked
4:49
very highly and I think that's more true
4:52
in economics than in other
4:54
disciplines. Having said that, I think
4:56
a main reason that the economics
4:58
profession is relatively concentrated in my
5:00
view is that we in economics
5:02
are much more of an interpretive
5:04
field than we like to believe
5:06
by interpretive I mean something like
5:08
the humanities, which is an example
5:10
of a field that is reinterpreting
5:12
existing work. or existing things about
5:14
society in new ways for people.
5:16
This is an important function, but it's
5:18
much more subjective than something that I
5:21
would call purely empirical discipline. Like if
5:23
you think about physics or anything in the
5:25
natural science, is often the title of the paper
5:27
is the finding. You know, we found this protein
5:29
that did this. And you don't see paper, you
5:31
know, one thing I love about economics is it's
5:33
kind of a bit of both. You know, we
5:35
uncover new facts about the world, but we
5:37
also interpret them. And I think you see
5:40
this pattern. of greater concentration of major prizes
5:42
in fields that are more interpretive. You know,
5:44
so like in the humanities you see, you
5:46
know, much more concentration and art in history,
5:48
you know, you see those scholars in those
5:51
fields are much more likely to be in
5:53
the very top departments, whereas the top scholars
5:55
in, let's say, engineering or physics are much
5:57
more widely distributed because if you have some
6:00
great... discovery, it's just kind of, that's the
6:02
discovery. And you can win the Nobel Prize
6:04
for that, even if you're at, you know,
6:06
the University. And because there are much more
6:08
objective measures of whether it's significant or not,
6:10
like if you invent the airplane, you know,
6:12
now people can fly. Yeah, and I should
6:14
say to Nick, just to be clear, I
6:16
mean, I think that's, doesn't necessarily mean
6:18
that it's like anti theoretical. So, empiricism
6:21
in theory are not opposites or not
6:23
opposites. It's not that there's anything wrong
6:25
with being more theoretical, it's just you
6:27
have to understand that it's like whether
6:29
a theory is true is inherently more
6:31
subjective than whether an empirical result is true.
6:33
I have to think about that. Is that
6:35
true? It kind of puts economics in a
6:37
difficult position because it's not, you
6:39
can't categorize it as a natural science because
6:42
it's not. really a science
6:44
at least most of what
6:46
what Orthodox economics does but
6:48
you don't want to classify
6:51
it as humanity because over
6:53
the past 50 years it's
6:55
largely been inhumane well well I
6:58
don't know about I mean I'm
7:00
not sure I'm not sure I
7:02
agree with that oh come on
7:04
good joke good joke but To
7:06
be serious, I think it is
7:08
one of the things I love
7:10
about the field of economics and
7:12
when it's done right, is that
7:14
it's a combination of theory and
7:16
empirics, combination of interpretive and empirical.
7:18
So that's what's fun about it
7:20
when it's done right. Can we just go
7:22
back to the thing that you just said, which
7:24
is really interesting is that
7:26
empirics is easier to examine than
7:28
theory. What's amazing about economic
7:31
theory is how unaligned the theory is
7:33
with the evidence. Right? That's the
7:35
frustrating thing about economics,
7:38
is that in theory, as you
7:40
raise the minimum wage, you should
7:42
have fewer jobs, as long as you
7:44
assume a bunch of things which are
7:46
not true about the world. So what
7:49
I would say about that, Nick,
7:51
is it just means the existing
7:53
theory is incomplete, not the theory
7:56
per se is bad, right? So I'm
7:58
not saying theory is bad. But theory
8:00
should be connected to what actually
8:02
happens in the real world, right? I agree.
8:04
I agree. And so the right way to
8:07
proceed as a science is to develop theories
8:09
and then test them. Yes. And those are
8:11
two sides of the same coin. And so
8:13
I think, but I think when you have
8:16
scholars who are purely theorists and they're theorizing
8:18
about. how to interpret the world, so like
8:20
how should we think about big issues,
8:22
like here's what Karl Marx was a
8:24
theorist, you know, Adam Smith was a
8:26
theorist. These are people who were, you
8:28
know, the, the kind of titans of
8:30
early economics before we could really touch
8:32
data, before we could test a lot
8:34
of the claims. Those are things that
8:36
where the way I decide how much
8:38
I value that scholarship is much more
8:40
subjective. It's like, like, does it seem
8:42
like it has the ring of truth?
8:44
Is it internally consistent? kind of developed
8:47
mathematical tools to develop theories that are
8:49
sometimes beautiful. And sometimes they're right, like
8:51
auction theory, you know, was incredibly successful
8:53
in the real world. But oftentimes those
8:55
theories, you know, people win pride for
8:57
those theories actually before they're put to
8:59
the test. And so then what happens
9:01
is if somebody writes a really good
9:03
theory, everybody loves it, everything else they
9:05
write is brilliant too, because of the
9:07
early developments they made in theory. You
9:09
see that in a lot of interpretive
9:11
disciplines, you know, Foko, for example. once
9:13
somebody establishes a reputation as a leader
9:15
in their field everything they write has
9:17
the same halo effect to it whereas
9:19
empirical work it's much more one by one like
9:21
did you discover some really important
9:23
you know material compound did you
9:25
discover did you make a new invention and
9:28
when you do discover something in
9:30
empirically that just invites a Nobel
9:32
Prize winner to call you a camp following
9:34
whore I don't know what you're referring
9:36
to that sounds like the nick does
9:38
it's the famous James Buchanan op-ed in
9:40
the Wall Street Journal on the Kruger,
9:42
the first minimum wage study to show,
9:44
is that it... Yeah. Yeah. But you know, the
9:47
minimum wage is a great example of, in
9:49
my view, how in the longer sweep
9:51
of this theory and empirical work can
9:53
interact to develop something richer and more
9:56
interesting. So we had these, you know,
9:58
perfectly competitive, like, basically... There's some theories
10:00
of perfect competition in labor markets where
10:03
information was perfect. But you know, that
10:05
doesn't reflect the economic discipline today at
10:07
all. And part of the reason is
10:09
because people say, well, in this perfectly
10:11
competitive economy, it must be that the
10:14
minimum wage increases in the minimum wage
10:16
will lead to employment losses. We don't
10:18
find that. That must mean that maybe
10:20
firms have market power. There's some monopsy.
10:23
And so there's, you know, some of
10:25
the most exciting recent work in economics
10:27
is developing theories of monopsiny
10:29
power. I suppose what's 50 trillion
10:32
dollars between friends
10:34
right? 79 trillion. Oh is it
10:36
79 trillion dollars now? 79 trillion.
10:38
I mean because in the real
10:41
world that view that markets
10:43
were perfectly efficient and
10:45
all this stuff did lead
10:47
to a 79 trillion dollar transfer
10:50
of income from the bottom nine
10:52
deciles to the top 1% over
10:54
the last 50 years. So these
10:57
are pretty serious. These are pretty
10:59
serious issues. So Nick, that's quite
11:02
a theory. Do you have any
11:04
empirical work to test it? We
11:06
do, we do, there is, huge
11:09
amounts, huge amounts. There's, well, it's
11:11
based on the original, the original
11:13
Rand report from a few years
11:16
ago, but there's an update coming
11:18
that, you know, updates the numbers,
11:21
the top line numbers on this.
11:23
It's the, due to rising inequality
11:25
since 1975. Basically, it's
11:27
counterfactual how much the
11:30
bottom 90% would have
11:32
earned had income distributions
11:34
remain constant across distributions
11:36
over the past 50
11:38
years. Sorry, sorry, you're
11:40
assigning 100% of the
11:42
credit for that to... Well,
11:44
rising in... Economics. Well, who's been
11:47
guiding the economy for the past
11:49
50 years? Yeah. I mean, look,
11:51
the decisions were made, choices were
11:54
made, it wasn't like inevitable that
11:56
we were going to concentrate, wealth,
11:59
and power. the top. Yeah and
12:01
the consensus in the economics profession
12:03
for decades was that there was a
12:05
basically a mechanical inverse correlation between the
12:07
amount that you paid people at the
12:10
bottom and the number of jobs
12:12
in the economy and I can tell
12:14
you because we we do this work
12:16
directly 15 years ago when I
12:19
went and started talking to people
12:21
you know in the United States
12:23
Senate whether they were Democrats or
12:25
Republicans that consensus had completely shaped
12:28
their view of policy. So it
12:30
really wasn't until 2012 when
12:32
we cooked up the $15
12:34
minimum wage that that framework
12:37
of thought began to get
12:39
disrupted. But it was, I mean,
12:42
that theory, which lives in
12:44
academia, totally captured
12:46
the policy-making apparatus
12:48
and resulted in the
12:50
minimum wage not tracking productivity
12:53
gains, basically stuck it. you
12:55
know, 1980 levels. I mean,
12:57
the $7.25 minimum wage a
13:00
day, $2.13 per hour for
13:02
tipped workers, is a
13:04
byproduct of that consensus.
13:07
That's how we got
13:09
that. Well, I mean, I guess I would,
13:11
I mean, obviously we can't, we can't hash
13:13
all this out. Yeah, yeah. I taught a
13:15
class for several years at the Kennedy School
13:17
and in the Econ Department here called the
13:19
Cause of the Consequences of In Equality. And
13:21
part of what I did in that class
13:24
was tried to get students to apportion credit
13:26
for different forces to the rise in inequality
13:28
in the US and globally since the 1970s.
13:30
And part of the point was. So where
13:32
did you guys come out? That's really interesting.
13:34
Yeah, yeah. So part of the point was
13:36
to say, whatever your favorite explanation is, it
13:38
has to be, if it's going to
13:40
be monocausal, it's going to be
13:42
one thing. It has to be
13:44
consistent with all the fact patterns.
13:46
And it has to explain, for
13:48
example, why top incomes rose in
13:50
all the OECD countries, even though
13:52
the top marginal tax rate changed
13:54
in different times, the different rates
13:56
in those countries. So it can't
13:58
just be taxes. But just, I was
14:01
trying to teach students the skill of
14:03
weighing a bunch of different explanations in
14:05
their heads, all of which are contributing
14:07
in some ways, but none of which
14:09
are fully consistent with any set of
14:11
facts. And so I think that's a
14:14
useful exercise and I would apply that
14:16
here to say. The economics profession surely
14:18
deserves some blame for what's happened in
14:20
terms of inequality in the country since
14:22
1970. But I would say also a
14:24
lot of it is political decisions too.
14:27
Is that, you know, that kind of...
14:29
But the political decisions are at least
14:31
partially informed by the economics profession.
14:33
Yeah, of course. All I can
14:35
tell you is when lefty, when
14:37
lefty democratic senators deeply believe that
14:39
if you raise the minimum wage,
14:41
it will be, it will kill
14:43
jobs. Right? the chemistry department didn't
14:45
come up with that the poetry
14:47
department didn't come up with that
14:49
it was the economics department that
14:51
came up with that and that and
14:53
that to a certain extent has been
14:56
the challenge of governing in the United
14:58
States and in the West overall because
15:00
lots of most of the West was
15:02
sort of dominated by the neoliberal this
15:04
sort of generalized neoliberal
15:07
framework and getting and getting back
15:09
to actually the the core topic of
15:11
the piece you wrote in the Atlantic.
15:13
It wasn't just the economics department, it
15:16
was the economics department at a handful
15:18
of elite universities predominantly. Yeah. If you
15:20
could go into the idea of what
15:22
like eight schools, is that what the
15:25
number was? I can't remember. It was
15:27
something like eight schools, yeah. Yeah. Although,
15:29
you know, given our previous conversation, you
15:31
might not be so excited about my
15:33
description for that, which is to fund...
15:35
practical work what I
15:38
would think of as engineering work
15:40
in economics at less elite departments
15:42
so that I would say yeah
15:45
yeah yeah 100% okay good so
15:47
I would say yeah this is
15:49
economics equivalent of DEA we're going
15:51
to have more diversity and okay
15:53
no yeah diversity is the core
15:56
value yeah I mean just because
15:58
we are putting you on the spot
16:00
a little bit doesn't mean we
16:02
think it's fun. Just because we're
16:05
going to put you on the
16:07
spot a little bit doesn't mean
16:09
we you know we're not trying
16:12
to shoot the messenger or blame
16:14
you for all of this. But
16:16
the other thing that I've always
16:19
been puzzled by is the
16:21
hold let me let me back up
16:23
and say that human societies
16:26
are constructs that are
16:28
held together by stories,
16:30
right? By narratives. And
16:33
for all of human history,
16:35
those narratives generally
16:38
are produced by and
16:40
benefit elites, right? The
16:42
stories are not necessarily
16:44
true, but they are very good
16:47
for the people in charge,
16:49
generally. I mean, if they're
16:51
the ones telling them, yes,
16:53
people like to tell stories.
16:56
Yeah, exactly. The economic narrative
16:58
for the last 50 years
17:00
has been massively biased towards
17:02
the wealthy, right? Tax cuts for
17:05
the rich, create growth, deregulation. in
17:07
the US, in the US, right,
17:09
in particular. Well, I would say,
17:11
it depends on what you mean
17:13
by the fast past few centuries.
17:16
Like I would say that was
17:18
more true in the 80s and
17:20
90s than it's been in the
17:22
last two decades. No, no, no,
17:24
no, no, no, no, for sure.
17:26
During that sort of neoliberal
17:29
era, it really swung that way.
17:31
And you know, when the 50s
17:33
and 60s and 40s, it definitely
17:36
shifted. The common story is
17:38
just a bunch of old rich
17:40
white dudes who conspired to fuck
17:42
over the poor, right, in the
17:44
economics profession, but I don't think
17:46
that that's true, right? Like there
17:49
was no conspiracy. But how did
17:51
it, what's your sense of why
17:53
that happened? How did that happen? And
17:55
I just want to point out that
17:58
the elites were talking about here. it's
18:00
largely old rich white dudes. I
18:02
think in order to dominate the
18:05
profession. Yeah, yeah. So in
18:07
my opinion to try to understand
18:09
this, I think you have to
18:11
go back to the 1970s and
18:13
think about what was happening
18:15
in the country. Yeah. You know,
18:18
inflation was super high. The economy was
18:20
stagnating. People were upset. And so for
18:22
better or worse, you know, we were
18:24
coming out of a time. Yeah. For
18:26
sure. Was that. people wanted something different
18:28
and you know Ronald Reagan in his
18:30
time was was I think was really
18:32
the you know in the Reagan administration
18:34
was really what ushered this in and
18:37
it was in response to public demand.
18:39
Part of it was a sense of
18:41
wanting to increase national competitiveness to win
18:43
the Cold War. It was trying to
18:45
see some economic benefit from the big
18:47
investments we've made in the military industrial complex
18:49
and some of those technologies like were the
18:52
early days of technologies like the internet and
18:54
computers that were really transformative for society and
18:56
kind of upended the winners and losers of
18:58
the country. And so I think in that
19:01
time, you know, some people would say it
19:03
was needed, but it was certainly requested. And
19:05
then what happened was that led to some
19:07
excesses it was you know greed is good
19:10
and you know we had the movie Wall
19:12
Street and we had soaring incomes and then
19:14
I think what you're seeing now is a
19:16
backlash to that so I think of it
19:19
is actually I mean this is not going
19:21
to be surprising I'm the two-handed economist in
19:23
the classic joke I would I would like
19:25
to have something in the middle of those
19:27
two yeah you know I think that competition
19:30
is one of the greatest forces for good
19:32
in all of human society. And
19:34
I think what you see oftentimes
19:36
is the relatively well off insulating
19:38
themselves from competition. So I actually,
19:40
for me, there's something actually quite
19:43
beautiful about neoclassical economics. I just
19:45
think that what happens is people
19:47
under the guise of neoclassical economics
19:49
do things that aren't very competitive
19:51
that end up benefiting rich people.
19:53
So I see a lot of
19:55
what the excesses of that age
19:57
are as being actually non-competitive, capturing.
19:59
100%. And we could have a
20:02
multi-hour conversation about this, but part
20:04
of what led us there, I
20:06
think, are again some of the
20:09
underlying assumptions that make you want
20:11
to believe those things. So for
20:13
example, the idea that seeing the
20:15
economy as a prey to optimal
20:18
equilibrium within which a thing like
20:20
efficiency can be possible. Now if
20:22
you assume that... If you assume certain
20:24
things and other things become possible,
20:27
if you don't assume that it's
20:29
a prey to optimal equilibrium, if
20:31
you think of it as an ecology
20:33
in which the word efficiency actually
20:35
doesn't really apply, then you end
20:37
up just in different places and
20:39
different stuff. But let's not go
20:41
down that red hole. Let's talk
20:43
a little bit more about David's
20:46
prescription for how to make
20:48
the economics profession. better because
20:50
I thought in your article I thought
20:52
you had really good ideas. Well thank
20:54
you for saying that. To be clear
20:56
it was written before the Trump administration
20:59
started slashing funding federal funding for research.
21:01
It was, it was and then I
21:03
have I have since written another article
21:05
for the Atlantic about the folly of
21:07
cutting NIH funding so I guess I'm
21:09
on that on that beat. So my
21:11
prescription was look if the problem so
21:13
the not problem the state of the
21:16
economics profession is that it's a mix
21:18
of humanistic and interpretive and empirical as
21:20
I said earlier and what you see
21:22
is increasing concentration of major prizes and
21:24
funding and just kind of clubs in
21:26
more interpretive fields. That's, I think, it's
21:28
not something anyone's doing on purpose to
21:31
your point, Nick. It's kind of inherent
21:33
to the exercise. Yeah, yeah. It's, it's
21:35
like these are measures of what our
21:37
favorite thing is in many cases, right?
21:39
Yeah, it's more about trends, what's hot,
21:41
you know, yeah, right. And so my
21:43
solution was to create through a variety
21:46
of incentives, okay, which is a, you
21:48
know, economic. you know, classic economic point
21:50
of view is to create various
21:52
incentives through a mix of government
21:54
funding and kind of social status
21:56
and a program on both sides
21:58
of like valuing. what I would
22:00
call economic engineering more. So solving practical
22:03
problems using the tools of economics. And
22:05
I think sometimes that involves using high-brow
22:07
theory, mathematical theory. I gave the case
22:09
the example in the article of auction
22:11
theory and how auction theory was used
22:13
to auction off SEC broadband spectrum and
22:15
Paul Milgram and Bob Wilson won the
22:18
Nobel Prize for that. And that was
22:20
like literally save the government billions. And
22:22
so it's not about theory versus imperics.
22:24
It's really about valuing practical contributions and
22:26
not just can you publish an ela.
22:28
paper in a top journal and have
22:30
it be highly cited by your peers. It's
22:33
about an impact test in the world. And
22:35
my argument was the best way to do
22:37
that is for agencies like the NIH and
22:39
the NSF to fund impactful economic research not
22:42
to do things like give, you know, most
22:44
of the NSF's money in Econ is given
22:46
to early career awards, so finding the top
22:48
people in top departments and giving them unconditional
22:51
money drops and NSF doctoral fellowships. which is
22:53
funding graduate students at the top departments. And
22:55
I'm not against any of that. I would
22:57
like more. But if you push me and
23:00
say, you have to budget neutral, I would say, let's
23:02
do more funding of high impact projects, the
23:04
bridge building analogy, like how to create
23:06
good markets that reward, you know, that
23:08
link buyers and sellers, how to like,
23:10
you know, have a more transparent monitoring
23:12
system for the health of the economy,
23:14
creating new data sets, all things that
23:16
just provide public value, I would be
23:18
funding those things. I think that would
23:20
make the professional more egalitarian. It would
23:22
also make the world a better place.
23:24
Yeah, yeah. I mean, I'm often struck when
23:26
I meet with economists sometimes
23:29
how uninterested some of them are
23:31
in what's happening in the real
23:33
world, right? And you're like, and I'm
23:35
like, so how is this going to
23:37
help the average American? And they're like.
23:39
What? It's so hard to mathematize
23:41
that, Nick. You know, you've put
23:44
that, put, you know, that into
23:46
a model. Should have to sign
23:48
the same thing that doctors do
23:51
about whatever, helping people? First, first,
23:53
first, two hours? Yeah, and I
23:55
think, you know, actually, so when
23:58
I wrote this piece, I got
24:00
a lot of, I mean, it obviously generated
24:02
a lot of conversation in my profession. I
24:04
got a lot of notes from people.
24:07
Did you get a lot of hate mail?
24:09
No, no hate mail. Some people thinking I
24:11
was wrong, they weren't unkind about it. They
24:13
were engaging. But the thing that I found
24:15
very striking was that I got, I got like
24:18
almost universal positive feedback from
24:20
the more junior members of the discipline. And
24:22
often they were people saying, hey, we're doing
24:24
this already. I do think people my age
24:26
in a bit younger, my age in a
24:29
bit younger. are like much more into this
24:31
way of work and some of the some
24:33
of the work I'm most excited about in
24:35
the economics profession is work happening among people
24:37
who are you know graduated around the time
24:40
I did or later who were out there
24:42
in the world doing really interesting things so
24:44
a lot of it's already happening. Yeah you
24:46
also and I don't think you use the
24:48
word but I think if I read the piece
24:50
correctly you also think we need to
24:52
do something to change norms
24:54
within the profession, particularly in
24:56
terms of what you're awarding,
24:58
that there's almost no awards
25:01
in economics that are predicated on,
25:03
I don't know, improving people's
25:05
lives. Yeah, or even just impact in
25:07
the real world. So like, one example,
25:10
I think I got cut from the
25:12
piece for space, but I was, the
25:14
society of labor economists, I'm a labor
25:16
economist, so I know that well, has
25:18
an award they just started. called the
25:21
Edla Zero Award, and it's an award
25:23
for a mix of people who've had,
25:25
you know, research for people, sorry, for
25:27
people who had a mix of research
25:29
impact and policy impact. And the first
25:31
award went to John Aabout, who I
25:34
don't know if you know John Aabout,
25:36
but it really distinguished labor economists who
25:38
also has really distinguished labor economists who
25:40
also has worked tirelessly for years to
25:43
improve data access to the census. So
25:45
it's like an award that says, look,
25:47
you're a good. You know, you should
25:49
be rewarded explicitly and implicitly in terms
25:52
of norms for taking your insights into
25:54
the world and making it better. And that's
25:56
very different than, you know, like the Nobel
25:58
Prizes for actual... sciences where
26:00
you're largely, you're often rewarded for
26:03
practical results. Yes, I mean, well,
26:05
part of it is inherent to the
26:07
field itself. So if you discover, you
26:09
know, if you make some scientific
26:12
discovery, regardless of what university you're
26:14
at, it's just clearly valuable and it
26:16
leads to downstream innovations. And so, you know,
26:18
there are lots of examples of that in.
26:20
in the natural sciences and the physical sciences,
26:22
and actually think in economics, we have that
26:24
too. You know, I do believe economics is
26:27
a science, and I think we can make
26:29
it more so by being a bit more
26:31
systematic about our discoveries. I think you're seeing
26:33
a lot more of that, people taking replication
26:35
much more seriously, making data sets public, you
26:37
know, it's all part of a process that
26:39
we've undergone in a profession. in response to
26:42
criticisms such as yours, and I think those
26:44
are healthy and fair criticisms. You know,
26:46
I made the D.I. joke, but if
26:48
you're going to call economics a science,
26:50
I mean, there's various papers that show
26:52
it, that it is one of the
26:55
least diverse. It is the most, in terms
26:57
of gender equality, racial equality,
26:59
and and a more
27:01
recent study on socioeconomic
27:04
equality that it it
27:06
draws people from higher
27:08
income backgrounds. Disproportionately. Isn't
27:10
the woman that we
27:12
interviewed on that Harvard
27:15
researcher too? Probably because they're
27:17
all these eight schools Nick.
27:19
And I'll tell you it's been
27:21
a struggle on this podcast as
27:23
a couple of old white men
27:26
trying to get guests who aren't
27:28
at the very least white men, we
27:30
make an effort to try to keep
27:33
our guests diverse and it's hard. I
27:35
mean, we have to go out of our
27:37
way to do it because the, when
27:39
we're interviewing economists, because the number outside
27:41
of profession, it's a lot easier, but
27:44
it is so dominated by white men
27:46
of a certain socioeconomic background. So Goldie,
27:48
I mean, I mean, I want, I
27:50
share your view that the profession should
27:52
be more diverse and have done some
27:54
work unless many of us have to
27:57
try to try to make that happen.
27:59
I think that's a. important goal I
28:01
agree with it but as far as
28:03
that whether that I don't think that
28:05
really speaks to whether economics is a
28:07
science for me of what a science
28:09
is a I'm not saying that I'm
28:11
saying but I'm just comparing it to
28:13
other sciences that this is an apples
28:15
to apples comparison if you if you
28:17
compare it to other scientific fields those
28:19
fields you know the hard sciences
28:22
in particular are really diverse. It's
28:24
a lot of first-generation
28:26
Americans within the US.
28:29
It's coming from drawing
28:31
from broader socioeconomic backgrounds.
28:33
It's more gender diverse.
28:36
It's more racially and
28:38
ethnically diverse. Whereas economics,
28:40
if it wants to, you know,
28:43
if you're comparing it as a
28:45
science, it is the least diverse
28:47
of the sciences. Yeah, well, I mean,
28:49
again, like, I'm not... I deplore that, too.
28:51
I just think those are separate issues. To
28:53
me, the definition of a science... isn't based
28:55
on who's in it, it's based on whether
28:57
the profession moves forward a body of knowledge.
28:59
So do we build on our discoveries? Do
29:02
we learn from our mistakes? Do we update
29:04
our theories and our empirical results? And I
29:06
think, you know, no science is perfect and
29:08
economics is no exception to that. We've got
29:10
a lot of work to do. We've been,
29:12
the profession's been wrong about a lot of
29:14
work to do. But I think, I feel
29:16
like we know more in economics than we're
29:18
building a body of knowledge and
29:21
for that I'd call a call
29:23
a call a science. Yeah. If
29:25
you were the Elon Musk of
29:27
economics. Yeah, if you were the
29:29
Elon Musk of economics, and then
29:31
we just subtract the
29:35
sociopathic narcissism.
29:37
And assume that you're
29:39
not that. Yeah. What would
29:41
you do with the profession?
29:44
Yeah. I would. influence
29:49
all of
29:51
the major
29:54
professions in
29:57
the of
30:00
new data sets and, you know, creating more
30:02
incentives to do essential descriptive work about the
30:04
economy. So I think we just, professionally, we
30:06
have very little incentive, let me give you
30:08
one example. I recently, with a couple of
30:10
co-authors, Alex Bacon, and Blandon, produced what we
30:12
think of as the first nationally representative survey
30:14
of generative AI usage in the US. So,
30:16
you know, it's been cited a million times
30:18
already, it's incredibly high value work, but like.
30:21
people have very, I mean, we're having trouble
30:23
getting it published, to be honest, because it's
30:25
just simple descriptive work, like what share of
30:27
people are using AI, who's using it, what
30:29
are they using it for, that kind of work is,
30:31
in my view, horribly underprovided in economics, because it's hard to publish
30:33
in a top five journal, in the economics, because it's hard to
30:35
publish in a top five journal, in the economics, because it's
30:37
hard to publish in a top five journal in the top
30:39
five journal, because it's hard to publish in the top five, in
30:42
the top five, and the top five journal, and the top
30:44
five journal, and the top five journal, and the top five
30:46
journal, and the top five journal, and the top five journal, and
30:48
the top five journal, and the top five journal, and the top
30:50
five journal, and the top five journal, and the top five
30:52
journal, and the top five journal, and the top five journal,
30:54
and the top five journal, and the top five journal, and the
30:56
top five journal tweak the incentive so that everyone has a much
30:58
stronger incentive to create data and to create basic insights about
31:00
how the economy works to inform decision-making. And I
31:03
think we should be professionally rewarded for
31:05
that. That's a huge hole in the
31:07
profession, it might be. I don't know.
31:09
On the one hand, you have actual
31:11
empirical data on how AI is being
31:13
used. And on the other hand, you
31:15
have Elon Musk telling you how it's
31:17
being used, which is more authoritative. Well,
31:19
I think... I think minus because he's
31:21
just one guy. And yet he's
31:23
the one with all the rewards.
31:26
Yeah. For now. Okay. I'm sorry.
31:28
I mean, listen, I'm going to
31:30
move today. Yeah. Remember Robespierre. That's
31:32
all I'll say. No, but I
31:34
actually, I mean, I think that
31:36
that kind of change, not only
31:39
would it make, I mean. the
31:41
primary value of it was it
31:43
would make society better we would
31:45
make better decisions yes yeah about
31:47
things that really affect people's livelihoods
31:50
but the other thing is i really do think
31:52
it would make the economic profession more diverse not
31:54
just you know ethnically and you know in terms
31:56
of socioeconomic background but just like a wide variety
31:58
of people would go into it they would see
32:00
value of it. We would, you know,
32:02
and so I think it would, and
32:04
it would improve the public's perception of
32:06
economics because we'd be providing something of
32:09
more value. So that's my magic
32:11
wand. One final question, why do
32:13
you do this work? Because I love it.
32:15
You know, to me this is like a
32:17
hobby more than a job. Like I just
32:19
get excited about it. I mean, I really
32:21
do. Like I wrote that piece because I
32:24
was hoping to influence the profession in a
32:26
way that I think creates more value
32:28
for the world. data nerd
32:30
skills to help people, you
32:32
know, and that's that's why
32:34
I'm doing this and I
32:36
still think it's a really
32:38
valuable thing to try and
32:41
do. That's great. That's
32:43
great. Well, David, thank you
32:45
so much for being with
32:47
us. It's really fun. I
32:49
hope we will see you again
32:52
on the podcast. Best of luck
32:54
on your work. Thank you so
32:56
much. Hey, thanks a lot. It
32:58
was a dialectic neck. Yeah. But
33:01
great guy. And I think really
33:03
on to I think an important
33:05
problem. I thought it was really
33:07
interesting conversation because it really
33:09
did highlight some of the
33:12
stuff that has emerged, but
33:14
you don't really think about
33:16
the source of. And you know, I
33:18
think Nick, we need to get into
33:20
a little bit about why this
33:23
is important. And that is,
33:25
you know, we made this
33:27
comparison to. you know corporate
33:29
America how it's monopolized by
33:32
big powerful corporations and
33:34
that reduces competition
33:36
and innovation. And that's
33:39
a really important point, that
33:41
there just isn't a lot of
33:43
competition within the Econ field, because
33:46
if you want to make it
33:48
in the Econ field, if you
33:50
want to be a prestigious economist,
33:52
if you want to potentially win
33:54
a major prize like the Nobel,
33:56
or you want to be named to
33:58
the Federal Reserve. or the
34:00
Treasury Department or some top
34:03
administration official, you need to
34:05
go along to get along at
34:08
these handful of elite universities,
34:10
and so you're not incentivized
34:13
to rock the boat in any
34:15
way. Yeah. The other thing is, and this
34:17
is something we haven't talked
34:19
about for a while on the
34:21
podcast, but one of the... core assumptions
34:23
that we make in our own
34:25
economics is that it's when I
34:27
talk about diversity and I brought
34:29
that up a couple times it's
34:31
not about fairness it's not I
34:33
mean it is but it's not
34:35
simply about fairness it's that this
34:38
is where innovation comes from
34:40
you want cognitive diversity and
34:42
you don't get cognitive diversity
34:44
if you out of a
34:46
set of institutions that don't
34:48
have socio-economic, gender,
34:51
racial, etc. diversity.
34:53
You're not going to get
34:55
as much out of it. So
34:58
when you have a profession dominated
35:00
by the same type of people
35:03
working at the same type of
35:05
institutions, you're going to get
35:07
less innovation because you have
35:09
less people, fewer people working
35:11
at these problems coming at
35:14
it from different perspectives, which
35:16
is where innovation comes from.
35:18
And so that has, I
35:20
think, arguably led to stagnation
35:23
within the field for a
35:25
very long time. That's why it's
35:27
important. For sure. And because it's
35:29
such an influential field in terms
35:32
of politics and policy. You want
35:34
that competition and diversity to be
35:37
there. Yeah, and you know, the
35:39
truth is that I don't care
35:41
if you're a scientist or, you know,
35:44
I suppose, you know, the best
35:46
scientists are better at,
35:48
I don't put this. The thing
35:50
about people is what we believe
35:53
is rarely based on facts and
35:55
evidence. It's what makes us feel
35:57
good. And if you're an old...
36:00
rich guy an economic framework that
36:02
privileges old white rich guys is
36:04
just going to feel better than
36:07
one that privileges people who
36:09
are not like you and so you know if
36:11
the if the if the profession had
36:13
been more diverse over the
36:15
last 50 years but socioeconomically
36:18
racially gender I think it's
36:20
likely that we wouldn't have
36:22
ended up with these frameworks so much
36:24
because a lot of people who were
36:26
in the field would have would have
36:28
pushed back on them. They would have
36:30
been like, you know, tax cuts for
36:33
the rich probably don't create
36:35
growth. That's just a thing rich
36:37
people say to poor people. Oh,
36:39
you're just a you're just a
36:41
camp following court. Yeah. I mean,
36:43
this is, you are challenging the
36:45
core economic, the core principle of
36:47
economic science. I mean, I, I
36:50
go back to the, that Paul
36:52
Romer piece that I mentioned, the,
36:54
the trouble with macro economics and
36:56
a weirdly funny paper. by
36:58
an economist, but in his
37:01
abstract, he compares the past
37:03
50 years of macroeconomics to
37:05
string theory. He says
37:07
a parallel with string
37:09
theory from physics hints
37:11
at a general failure
37:14
mode of science. that
37:16
is triggered when respect
37:18
for highly regarded leaders
37:20
evolves into a deference
37:22
to authority, that displaces
37:24
objective fact from its
37:26
position as the ultimate
37:28
determinant of scientific truth. And
37:30
to some extent, Nick, this is
37:32
what we've been pushing back here
37:34
on this podcast for years. There
37:37
is scientific truth out there. And,
37:39
you know, David's not wrong. A
37:41
lot of people in the profession...
37:44
understand this, they accept it,
37:46
it's talked about within the profession,
37:48
it just doesn't come through to the
37:50
people making the decisions. Correct. And
37:52
that's the big problem, is that
37:54
you can still get away with
37:57
saying that lower taxes for rich people
37:59
will be... good for the economy
38:01
or that raising the minimum wage
38:03
will be bad for the economy,
38:05
right? be bad for the economy right like is why
38:07
we're about to get tax cuts
38:09
for the rich to no increase
38:11
in the minimum wage. in the
38:13
minimum wage right. Well, that was
38:15
fun. well that again, if you want
38:17
to read more from David,
38:19
we will provide a link to
38:22
his piece in a Atlantic, his piece
38:24
in up break up big econ Pitch
38:30
Fork Economics is produced by Civic Ventures. If you
38:32
like the show, make sure to follow, rate, and
38:34
review us wherever you get your podcasts. Find us
38:36
on other platforms like Twitter, Facebook, Instagram, and Threads
38:38
at Pitch Fork Economics. Knicks on Twitter and Facebook
38:40
economics. Knicks on Twitter and Facebook as well at
38:42
Nick Hanhauer. For more content from us, you can
38:44
subscribe to our weekly newsletter the pitch over on
38:47
substack. And for links to for links
38:49
to everything we just
38:51
mentioned, plus transcripts and more,
38:53
visit our website our website.com. As
38:55
As always from our
38:57
team at Civic Ventures, thanks for
38:59
listening. See you next
39:01
week. week.
Podchaser is the ultimate destination for podcast data, search, and discovery. Learn More