Episode Transcript
Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.
Use Ctrl + F to search
0:00
Support for scratch and
0:02
win comes from M.
0:04
Steinert and Sons, guiding
0:06
musicians of all skill
0:08
levels to their ideal
0:10
piano for 165 years,
0:12
featuring the Steinway Spirio,
0:14
the world's finest high-resolution
0:17
player piano, M. steinert.com.
0:19
One of the questions I get
0:21
about the series is, what do
0:24
you mean when you say America's
0:26
most successful lottery? Like, are you
0:28
sure success is the right word
0:31
here? The answer, I think, is
0:33
yes. And here is what I
0:35
mean by it. Every part of
0:37
government has a purpose. Maybe it's
0:39
to build roads, educate children, protect
0:41
the environment. The purpose of
0:44
the lottery is to raise
0:46
money by selling lottery tickets.
0:48
And by that measure, however
0:50
you feel about the purpose,
0:52
the mass lottery is a great
0:54
success. We should be proud of it.
0:56
We should be proud of it. I wish
0:58
every part of my government were
1:01
so successful at its own purpose.
1:03
Now if you've been with us
1:05
since our first season about the
1:07
mighty infrastructure project known as the
1:10
Big Dig, you know that it
1:12
did not go so smoothly. Obviously
1:14
that was a very different
1:16
kind of government endeavor. It
1:19
involved tunneling through downtown Boston
1:21
and under the harbor. But
1:23
if you step back and stick
1:25
with me here, The lottery and
1:27
the big dig have a lot
1:29
in common. They required
1:32
coordination, design, technical
1:34
expertise, political support, people
1:36
power, all the ingredients
1:39
of state action.
1:41
So why do the
1:44
two stories play out
1:46
so, so differently? From
1:56
GBH News, this is scratch
1:58
and win. I'm Ian. Today I'm
2:00
talking with Mark Dunkelman about
2:03
his new book, Why Nothing Works.
2:05
Mark is a fellow at Brown
2:07
University, and he and I started
2:10
corresponding after the Big Dig series
2:12
came out when we realized we
2:14
were exploring a similar question of
2:17
why it was so hard for
2:19
the government to do big things.
2:21
As I was finishing up my
2:24
book, I was listening to your
2:26
podcast and thinking to myself, man.
2:28
We really have stumbled on a
2:31
similar body of thinking at
2:33
the same time. My hope
2:35
with this conversation is to
2:38
take Mark a little beyond
2:40
that question and his comfort
2:42
zone to consider why do
2:45
some parts of the government
2:47
work better than others?
3:01
I feel like our projects are
3:03
already somewhat in conversation, so
3:05
it's great to be personally
3:07
in conversation. Agree. And so
3:09
to help set that up,
3:11
I was wondering if you
3:14
could lay out your thesis
3:16
in that you described there
3:18
are these two kind
3:20
of core impulses of
3:22
American progressivism. Could you
3:24
describe what those impulses
3:26
are? So my view is
3:28
that progressivism when it was
3:31
born in the late 1800s came
3:33
with it two Impulses as you
3:35
say that are sort of
3:37
in a strange marriage and
3:40
that most progressives don't even
3:42
realize that they themselves possess
3:45
The first impulse is what I
3:47
call a Hamiltonian impulse. And the
3:50
Hamiltonian impulse as you might remember
3:52
with Alexander Hamilton is to centralize
3:54
power in some bureaucracy or agency
3:57
that can do great things for
3:59
people. who couldn't do it
4:01
for themselves. So you see a tragedy
4:04
to the common. There's a
4:06
whole neighborhood without a good
4:08
sewer system. No one resident
4:10
can build a sewer for
4:13
themselves. So you need to bring power
4:15
up into some centralized authority
4:17
that sits above everyone
4:19
else and that authority
4:22
will decide where the... sewer
4:24
pipes are going to go, how
4:26
they're going to be connected, where
4:28
the sewage is going to go,
4:30
that's a Hamiltonian impulse. In many
4:32
cases, like with climate change,
4:35
progressives continue to have a
4:37
Hamiltonian view. We need to push
4:39
power up into some bureaucracy that
4:41
will tell the polluters not
4:43
to emit carbon that have
4:46
that authority. We at the
4:48
same time have a second
4:50
impulse, Jeffersonian impulse, and many
4:52
will remember Jefferson, the white slave
4:54
union farmer, but yet the still
4:56
the ordinary person and his fear
4:58
was centralized authority. Like he was
5:01
afraid of the crown, he was
5:03
afraid of a big powerful government
5:05
in the United States as well.
5:07
He wanted to push power down
5:09
to ordinary people, so he was
5:11
really about rights. And so that
5:14
impulse also exists within the
5:16
progressive mind and heart today. Like
5:18
you think about the issue of
5:20
reproductive rights. And the fear is
5:22
once again a centralized bureaucrat telling
5:24
a woman what to do with
5:27
her body. And so our solution
5:29
to that problem is to push
5:31
power down into the individual so that
5:33
she can make a choice at her
5:35
own volition. And these two impulses
5:37
exist within the hearts
5:39
and minds of progressivism
5:41
of individual progressives at the same
5:44
time. Like if you went into a
5:46
coffee shop today and saw probably a
5:48
young person. Who you thought was a Democrat
5:51
and asked them what are your top
5:53
two voting issues and they said climate
5:55
change and reproductive rights? You wouldn't think
5:57
anything about it Right, but these two
5:59
ideas are born from these two different
6:02
impulses. So it's not to say
6:04
in my view that one of these
6:06
impulses is good and one is
6:08
bad or one is more progressive
6:10
and one less. It's that these
6:12
are two different ideas about how
6:15
power should be changed in order
6:17
to drive progress and we progressives
6:19
are betwixt in between.
6:21
We're vexed against ourselves in the
6:23
sense that we believe in both
6:25
of them and have to think
6:27
pretty hard to apply one in
6:29
one spot and one in another, or
6:31
to figure out what the right balance
6:33
is. Yeah, I love this idea. It
6:36
kind of troubles the conventional linear
6:38
nature of like the left and
6:40
right. And what you're suggesting is
6:43
that it's not just a matter
6:45
of how far left, but like
6:47
how far left along which of
6:50
these tracks. It's operating on different
6:52
axis, which is interesting. That's exactly
6:54
right. It is, you know, one
6:57
of the fears I had when
6:59
I wrote the book. and delineated
7:01
between Hamiltonian and Jeffersonian impulses, was
7:04
that people would say, oh, well,
7:06
clearly the mods among the progressives
7:08
are Hamiltonian and the, and
7:10
the Libs are Jeffersonian, but
7:12
that's not, certainly not true,
7:14
right? Like you could solve
7:17
our health care mess by
7:19
pushing power up into a
7:21
single-payer system, right? That would
7:23
be a Hamiltonian system, and
7:25
it's embraced by the far
7:27
left. you know, and you can find
7:29
situations the other way as well. So
7:32
my view is that both of
7:34
these impulses are in the
7:36
hearts and minds of both
7:38
the both moderate and the
7:40
most quote-unquote liberal progressives,
7:43
and that we're operating on an
7:46
axis that people don't
7:48
really consider. You said it's
7:50
not an either-or. It's not like,
7:52
you know... Lyndon Johnson is either
7:54
a Hamiltonian or a Jeffersonian. So
7:56
I'm wondering if you could give
7:58
an example of... a figure, a
8:01
project from the past when we
8:03
can see those two impulses working
8:05
together. Yeah, well, the reason that
8:08
I struggle is that both
8:10
impulses are almost always
8:12
at work in some way
8:14
or another. Like there's never
8:17
been a project that was
8:19
entirely Hamiltonian and never been
8:21
a project that was entirely
8:24
Jeffersonian. So they're always working
8:26
and there are tradeoffs. no
8:29
matter how you balance the
8:31
two. So the quintessential example
8:33
of Hamiltonian Progressivism,
8:35
sort of at its apex, is
8:37
the Tennessee Valley Authority, where
8:40
this little lawyer named
8:42
David Lilenthal from Wisconsin
8:44
was basically vested with
8:46
dictatorial powers in the upper south
8:49
of the United States. And the
8:51
problem at the time was that
8:53
the local utilities in and around
8:55
the upper south did not believe that
8:57
it was. going to be profitable
9:00
for them to wire up all
9:02
the poor farms that sat in
9:04
the countryside. And so in that
9:07
case, Franklin Roosevelt invested
9:09
David Lelenthal as
9:11
the head of the Tennessee
9:13
Valley Authority to do this
9:16
on his own using federal
9:18
workers. And he damned rivers,
9:20
created electrical generation, condemned land,
9:23
built poles connected those wires
9:25
to various farms. And what's
9:27
so remarkable about it is that
9:29
Lilnthal in that situation, who was
9:32
still remembered, to the degree he
9:34
is remembered, as a hero, for
9:36
having, you know, brought the lights
9:38
to this huge swath of the
9:40
countryside that was really, you know,
9:42
living in the 19th century, but
9:45
in the middle of the 20th,
9:47
he was exercising essentially the same
9:49
power that Robert Moses would exert
9:51
in New York City, when he was...
9:53
viewed today or is viewed today because
9:56
of the power broker which came out
9:58
in 1974 as a villain. But
10:00
it's the same basic paradigm. None
10:02
of the people who were opposed
10:05
to this project had any real
10:07
standing to oppose it. And so
10:09
just depending on the gloss you
10:12
put on a story, and I
10:14
think the big dig was spectacular
10:16
for this very reason, you looked
10:19
at how various people, depending on
10:21
their vantage point, took away different
10:24
lessons from the big dig. Was
10:26
it a boondoggle? Was it? an
10:28
incredible feat of engineering. Was it
10:31
both of these things at the
10:33
same time? And what does it
10:35
mean for the way that we
10:38
view government generally? And I think
10:40
that probably the way that we
10:43
each answer that question stems not
10:45
from the big dig itself, but
10:47
from our general view of whether
10:50
we think government is competent and
10:52
the stories that we have and
10:54
the experiences that we have. And
10:57
we bring that what Walter Littman
10:59
would have called the stories in
11:01
our heads. to each individual challenge.
11:04
You mentioned Robert Moses, who is
11:06
just this inescapable figure in anything
11:09
to do with urban planning, transportation,
11:11
infrastructure, government works, period. I'm curious,
11:13
how important do you think he
11:16
is and the narrative around him
11:18
in kind of souring progressives on
11:20
that Hamiltonian side? I'm going to
11:23
give you a long answer to
11:25
this question. You know, during the
11:28
1968 Democratic National Convention, there were
11:30
these two warring sides. One was
11:32
inside the convention hall, led by
11:35
Richard Daly, the mayor of Chicago,
11:37
who essentially sicked the Chicago Police
11:39
Department on the protesters outside, led
11:42
by the Chicago Seven, Abby Hoffman
11:44
and Jerry Rubin, and these folks
11:46
who were very suspicious of centralized
11:49
authority. viewed through that prism of
11:51
those two sides, those inside the
11:54
convention hall and those marching outside,
11:56
those in... are the Hamiltonians and
11:58
those on the outside aren't just
12:01
protesting the war they have a
12:03
much more universal gripe about centralized
12:05
authority like they don't like the
12:08
war they don't like Robert McNamara
12:10
they don't like Lyndon Johnson they
12:13
don't like folks like Robert Moses
12:15
who is the most powerful figure
12:17
in New York City he's like
12:20
a Hamiltonian of central casting yeah
12:22
and This book, The Power Brooker,
12:24
that comes out in 1974, exposes
12:27
him for all the things that
12:29
he's done that seem to be
12:31
cutting New York off at the
12:34
knees. He's built these highways and
12:36
terrible places. He's built housing in
12:39
ways that aren't conducive to urban
12:41
life. He's threatened communities. He's done
12:43
terrible environmental damage, on and on
12:46
and on. Blocked public transportation projects.
12:48
There's a whole litany of things
12:50
that he's done. And the power
12:53
broker, which wants the Pulitzer Prize
12:55
in 1975, is designed to take
12:58
down his reputation, which had been
13:00
so sterling in previous years. My
13:02
view is that what Robert Carrow,
13:05
who writes the power broker, is
13:07
he's taking the argument that was
13:09
made on the outside of the
13:12
1968 DNC, he's taking the core
13:14
message, which is that there is
13:16
rot in the middle of the
13:19
American establishment. that needs to be
13:21
exposed and needs to be checked.
13:24
And he's putting it in this
13:26
beautifully told story about Robert Moses,
13:28
essentially presenting it in an erudite
13:31
thoughtful way. People don't remember, but
13:33
like the power broker is released,
13:35
like within weeks of Richard Nixon's
13:38
resignation. And during that period, there
13:40
are a whole series of cultural...
13:43
Moments as well like Chinatown the
13:45
movie Chinatown comes out you may
13:47
remember is a story of like
13:50
a villainous developer who is stealing
13:52
water from the valley outside of
13:54
Los Angeles and bringing it to
13:57
the city. The movie network comes
13:59
out and like the Howard Beals
14:01
famous line, I'm mad as hell
14:04
and I'm not gonna take it
14:06
anymore, right? That's a calling out
14:09
of the establishment, right? Like that,
14:11
I'm mad as hell at the
14:13
establishment. And like, perhaps the apotheosis
14:16
of this comes in the 80s
14:18
and people may or may not
14:20
remember this famous apple. Super Bowl
14:23
ad the 1984 ad the 1984
14:25
ad right and like the apple
14:28
is is sort of absconding the
14:30
zeitgeist of the old Abby Hoffman
14:32
Jerry Rubin it's like a young
14:35
woman uses a javelin or a
14:37
it's a big hammer a sledgehammer
14:39
and mashes the screen and so
14:42
that we can all be free
14:44
right In all of these things,
14:46
the underlying story in our heads
14:49
is a Jeffersonian one, right? It
14:51
is that there is some powerful
14:54
figure above us, and what we
14:56
need to do is be released
14:58
from its tentacles, if we are
15:01
going to make the most of
15:03
our lives, no longer would liberalism,
15:05
the Democratic Party, no longer would
15:08
they really embrace the Hamiltonian notion
15:10
of solving problems. Do you know
15:13
the old line about The Velvet
15:15
Underground that not that many people
15:17
listened to them, but everybody who
15:20
did started a band? You ever
15:22
heard that? I have not. I
15:24
feel like there's something there similar
15:27
with the Power Broker. The book
15:29
is like 1,200 pages long. I
15:31
don't think that like the average
15:34
person has read it. There are
15:36
probably a lot of people who
15:39
own it and have not read
15:41
it. But it is so influential.
15:43
It seems to me in policy
15:46
circles and academic circles and in
15:48
like you said kind of distilling
15:50
this moment in this instinct into
15:53
just you know the most detailed
15:55
gripping account possible. Yeah, you know
15:58
today it almost goes without saying.
16:00
That we presume that there is
16:02
a shadowy force that is operating
16:05
beyond our own perception. And so
16:07
if the story in your head
16:09
is that there is a shadowy
16:12
entity that is out for you
16:14
and out for its own profit,
16:16
your natural impulse, everyone's natural impulse,
16:19
would be, let's put checks. and
16:21
balances around that shadow impulse so
16:24
that it can, so that this
16:26
entity cannot do what it intends
16:28
to do. So tell me about
16:31
the checks and balances. What are
16:33
the concrete policy changes that come
16:35
out of this era and how
16:38
do they change how government works?
16:40
So there are various and sundry,
16:43
but they are pervasive. They are
16:45
essentially hurdles at every step. We
16:47
created, for example, environmental hurdles. So
16:50
we created the... National Environmental Policy
16:52
Act in 1970, which is the
16:54
law that essentially mandates the environmental
16:57
impact statements for big projects. That
16:59
was a big part of the
17:01
story of the Big Dig. We've
17:04
created, you know, the Endangered Species
17:06
Act. We, the Clean Water Act,
17:09
the Clean Air Act, all of
17:11
these are designed in some cases
17:13
to empower a... bureaucracy like the
17:16
EPA to impose regulations, but in
17:18
many cases it creates causes of
17:20
action that allow individuals to challenge
17:23
decisions made by centralized authority. One
17:25
of the stories in my book
17:27
is the story of an effort
17:30
to build a transmission line through
17:32
Maine so that Massachusetts could green
17:35
its grid using hydropower produced in
17:37
Quebec and you needed some sort
17:39
of transmission line to bring that
17:42
power down. And among the things
17:44
that happened in the course of
17:46
the opposition to cutting that line
17:49
through the Northwoods of Maine, they
17:51
created a referendum whereby the people
17:54
were allowed to vote on whether
17:56
they thought that the power company
17:58
should be allowed to, you know,
18:01
take this sliver. of land through
18:03
the North Woods. Quite a contrast
18:05
with the Tennessee Valley Authority example.
18:08
Completely, completely a contrast. So in
18:10
most cases, the checks are not
18:12
created in the mind frame of
18:15
we're going to impose a Jeffersonian
18:17
check on this Hamiltonian establishment, right?
18:20
It is we want to save
18:22
this species from being... rendered extinct
18:24
by a project. We want to
18:27
save the Vista looking out across
18:29
the coast that's uninterrupted with a
18:31
bunch of wind turbines. We want
18:34
to ensure that there's no pollutant
18:36
emitting factory put up in a
18:39
residential neighborhood. Like these are like
18:41
generally the checks are designed for
18:43
good reason. But once they become
18:46
so voluminous that like it's almost
18:48
impossible to clear all the hurdles,
18:50
it becomes almost impossible to get
18:53
anything done. When I was working
18:55
on the big dig, one of
18:57
the questions I would ask, almost
19:00
everyone I interviewed who was involved
19:02
with the project on inside and
19:05
outside, was whether they felt there
19:07
was a fundamental tension between, you
19:09
know, a project trying to be
19:12
democratic and inclusive, and on the
19:14
other hand, effective and efficient. And
19:16
I found that a lot of
19:19
people, especially when I would ask
19:21
activists about this question, you know,
19:24
folks who had fought the highways,
19:26
who had fought those fights, they
19:28
did not want to see it
19:31
as a zero-sum game, that, you
19:33
know, that there's not simply a
19:35
choice we have to make, a
19:38
tradeoff we have to make between
19:40
effective government and democratic government. Do
19:42
you think there is a fundamental
19:45
tension and that we do have
19:47
to balance those things? The
19:51
short answer is yes. The
19:53
longer answer is that we,
19:55
certainly on the left, Have
19:57
a fantasy that if you
19:59
talk to everybody and everyone
20:01
else talks to everyone else
20:03
That we will be able
20:05
to find some solution that
20:07
everyone can agree to That
20:09
if you simply bring you
20:11
know, it's sort of remarkable
20:13
if you probably did this
20:15
when you were doing the
20:17
big dig if you go
20:20
to all the big think
20:22
tanks and download all of
20:24
their White papers on infrastructure
20:26
and how to do infrastructure
20:28
better The first recommendation is
20:30
almost invariably approach the community
20:32
earlier in the process. The
20:34
notion is that if you
20:36
just tell people that we're
20:38
going to drive a high-speed
20:40
rail line through your downtown.
20:42
early enough, they can find
20:44
some sort of accommodation or
20:46
that they can be bought
20:49
off with a new ice
20:51
skating rink that the high-speed
20:53
rail developer is going to
20:55
build for them or somehow
20:57
they will at least have
20:59
felt consulted and therefore a
21:01
seed. But the truth is
21:03
that in most cases, like
21:05
there is no obvious place
21:07
to put the high-speed rail
21:09
line. Every place has an
21:11
interest in not being changed.
21:13
No one wants their property
21:15
be taken. No one wants
21:18
to live near the factory.
21:20
No one wants to live
21:22
near the homeless shelter. No
21:24
one wants to have the
21:26
highway be too close or
21:28
too far from their little
21:30
hamlet. And so I don't
21:32
know whether in all cases
21:34
we need to think of
21:36
it as a tradeoff between
21:38
effective government and democratic government,
21:40
but there are tradeoffs to
21:42
be made. And we need
21:44
some system where... Not everyone
21:47
benefits, some people suffer and
21:49
the whole society benefits, we
21:51
need some system for being
21:53
able to balance those two
21:55
priorities. It's interesting to me
21:57
that this reevaluation of how
21:59
we build the sort of
22:01
environmental regulation, citizen input, is
22:03
happening. now. You know, so
22:05
your book came out this
22:07
month. Ezra Klein and Derek
22:09
Thompson published a book called
22:11
Abundance the same month, exploring
22:13
similar themes. And I think
22:16
it's much bigger than that.
22:18
I think to some extent
22:20
the series we did on
22:22
the big dig felt kind
22:24
of swept up in this
22:26
same energy. Which is something
22:28
that I don't think I
22:30
really perceive going into the
22:32
project, and it really, one
22:34
of the surprises of putting
22:36
that out in the world
22:38
was realizing just how ready
22:40
and excited people on the
22:42
left were to celebrate this
22:45
big, you know, supposed boondoggle
22:47
of a project. And so
22:49
I'm curious, why now? Why
22:51
is this in the air
22:53
now? I
22:56
think from a purely political
22:58
standpoint, this is salient today
23:01
because we're losing. I think
23:03
that the notion that government
23:06
doesn't work, and that's a
23:08
notion that is shared on
23:10
the right and the left,
23:13
is a terrible presupposition for
23:15
the Democratic Party that wants
23:18
to argue to people that
23:20
government is a solution to
23:23
problems to problems. If
23:25
you're able to set aside the
23:28
desire to ascribe Donald Trump's emergence
23:30
on the scene as one born
23:32
from pure prejudice and bigotry and
23:34
xenophobia and sexism and all the
23:37
lousy things that are associated with
23:39
him and sort of wonder why
23:41
is it that all these people
23:43
who see that, who have been
23:46
told that, who have been barised
23:48
with messages about how terrible he
23:50
is, still voted for him. I
23:52
think the underlying notion is. that
23:55
here's a strong man who will
23:57
push through. all these systems that
23:59
don't work, that haven't worked for
24:01
working class families, but frankly, don't
24:04
work for a lot of middle
24:06
class families. And if that's the
24:08
case, then the crucial element that
24:11
progressives haven't yet grappled with is
24:13
how do we present a government
24:15
that actually can deliver? And once
24:17
you realize that we progressives have
24:20
been the ones who are really
24:22
responsible for many of the hurdles,
24:24
that prevent government from acting effectively,
24:26
you don't have to spend your
24:29
time thinking about Donald Trump. You
24:31
realize that if we created these
24:33
problems, we can work our way
24:35
out of them, which isn't as
24:38
a guess that we need to
24:40
return to the era of Robert
24:42
Moses and David Lilenthau doing things
24:44
without anyone having any recourse to
24:47
challenge them. But it is to
24:49
say that like, if we're the
24:51
ones that are stopping the transmission
24:53
line from going through Maine so
24:56
that Massachusetts can green its grid,
24:58
then we... If we change our
25:00
tune, we can probably walk some
25:02
of that back. There is something
25:05
very empowering in realizing that we
25:07
are responsible for our own frustration.
25:09
And to be clear, the problems
25:11
you're identifying are not just with
25:14
physical infrastructure. Right? I mean, this
25:16
also affects health care policy. Could
25:18
you like expand on how this
25:20
idea of procedure affects other areas?
25:23
of government service? So let's work
25:25
through welfare. Sure. Because it's, I
25:27
think, a great example. When the
25:30
program that we now know as
25:32
TANF began in the New Deal
25:34
as aid to dependent children, the
25:36
goal was to create a federal
25:39
welfare system that empowered single mothers
25:41
not to have to go to
25:43
work. The way that we were
25:45
going to do that is that
25:48
we were going to give money
25:50
through social workers to people who
25:52
were cases. in the system. So
25:54
the federal government would provide states
25:57
with money. That money would be
25:59
doled out by social workers. Generally,
26:01
middle class women who would go
26:03
and meet poor women who were
26:06
raising children and give them money
26:08
if they were following the rules.
26:10
But there was a lot of
26:12
discretion given to these social workers.
26:15
And so if a social worker
26:17
was kind, she might throw in
26:19
a few extra dollars if her
26:21
car broke down or whatnot. If,
26:24
on the other hand, she thought
26:26
that the woman wasn't properly following
26:28
some moral code, that she had
26:30
a boyfriend when she shouldn't, that
26:33
she was drinking too much, that
26:35
she was an addict or whatnot,
26:37
she could withhold support. And you
26:39
get to the 1970s and people
26:42
are looking at this and they're
26:44
like, this is awfully weird. Like,
26:46
there's something off-putting about the notion
26:49
that you're essentially... sicking a new
26:51
mother through the government on to
26:53
these women. It feels oppressive, coercive.
26:55
Like there were what they called
26:58
midnight raids where the social workers
27:00
would knock on the door of
27:02
someone's home who was on the
27:04
door and see if there was
27:07
a man in the house. And
27:09
the Jeffersonian reform impulse was to
27:11
make the welfare system AFDC automatic.
27:13
So if, or ministerial, if a.
27:16
person could check these boxes if
27:18
they had an income that they
27:20
could prove was below this level,
27:22
if they had this many dependent
27:25
children, if they etc, etc, if
27:27
they had tried to enroll their
27:29
kid in school. If they, if
27:31
they met these criteria, they would
27:34
get a benefit of some sort.
27:36
The social workers were essentially replaced
27:38
by case workers. This is the
27:40
Jeffersonian solution. People who have no
27:43
incentive to really help people. They're
27:45
just trying to make sure that
27:47
the paperwork is right. And like
27:49
the image that we have from
27:52
like ghostbusters of like of an
27:54
EPA bureaucrat who like it just
27:56
wants to follow the rules, it's
27:58
not thinking about the greater good.
28:01
The image that we have of
28:03
the welfare system is a Jeffersonian
28:05
welfare system where the rights are
28:07
endowed in the individuals who are
28:10
getting puny checks and no real
28:12
support from a system that doesn't
28:14
really work. And so, you know,
28:17
there are advantages and advantages to
28:19
both approaches, and you have to
28:21
find a balance that is workable.
28:37
So I want to draw in
28:39
the story of the state lottery,
28:42
which I realize on the surface
28:44
might seem like an odd connection.
28:47
But I think there's a bit
28:49
of irony here, I guess, that
28:51
I'm interested in, in that on
28:54
the one hand, we're talking about
28:56
the big dig, this clearly beneficial
28:58
project that was not run very
29:01
smoothly and was very expensive and
29:03
troubled in all these ways. And
29:05
then on the other hand, you
29:08
have the lottery, a government project
29:10
of somewhat questionable. value and benefit
29:12
that is operated very smoothly and
29:15
efficiently and effectively. And so at
29:17
a high level, the question I
29:19
have is, why do some parts
29:22
of the government work better than
29:24
others? Yeah, I mean, the criticism
29:27
that Alan Errenhol made of the
29:29
book in Washington Monthly was that
29:31
the title, Why Nothing Works, like
29:34
clearly some things do work. It's
29:36
very hard to say that the
29:38
Social Security Administration, doesn't work. You
29:41
know will it be fully funded
29:43
forever like those are those are
29:45
topics that are sure they did
29:48
so what is it that social
29:50
security and the lottery and I
29:52
don't know if there are other
29:55
things you put in that bucket.
29:57
What do they have in common?
29:59
Is there no immediate detriment to
30:02
anybody that they can feel and
30:04
see? Yeah. I wonder if I'm
30:07
just thinking out loud here, but
30:09
there's something about the balance between
30:11
the harms and the benefits. In
30:14
an infrastructure project, like the big
30:16
dig, the harms are extremely concentrated.
30:18
If you are the person who
30:21
lives next to that on ramp
30:23
that is going to be built,
30:25
you know that you are being
30:28
harmed. Whereas the benefits are very
30:30
diffuse. everybody, the thousands of people
30:32
who commute through the city, the
30:35
thousands of people who ride the
30:37
train, whatever it is. In the
30:40
case of something like the lottery,
30:42
the harms are much more diffused.
30:44
There are people who develop gambling
30:47
addictions scattered throughout the state that
30:49
are not an especially organized or,
30:51
you know, powerful constituency. And on
30:54
the other hand, you have benefits.
30:56
that are very real, obviously for
30:58
the handful of people who become
31:01
millionaires, but maybe more importantly for,
31:03
I don't know, the Senate president
31:05
who has a little extra money
31:08
to play with, or for the
31:10
mayor of a small town who
31:12
gets a check from the state
31:15
every year from the state lottery.
31:17
There are these, the benefits are
31:20
very concentrated and tangible in a
31:22
way that creates... a political constituency,
31:24
whereas in the infrastructure the harms
31:27
are very concentrated and tangible in
31:29
a way that energizes opposition or
31:31
energizes a constituency. Do you think,
31:34
does that make sense? Yeah, it
31:36
makes a lot of sense. How
31:38
much of it is just about
31:41
attention then, you know, social security?
31:43
It just operates and nobody pays
31:45
attention to the day-to-day operations of
31:48
it. The lottery, people don't pay
31:50
attention to it. As soon as
31:52
that construction barrier goes up, you
31:55
pay attention to it. Or even
31:57
before, when the design plan goes
32:00
out and you see... the 14-story
32:02
housing building in your neighborhood, people
32:04
pay attention to it. Is that
32:07
sort of what divides the parts
32:09
of government that are able to
32:11
function kind of more smoothly in
32:14
the parts that hit all these
32:16
roadblocks? I mean, I think the
32:18
other way to look at this
32:21
is to say Social Security was
32:23
fairly controversial when it was established,
32:25
less so because it was the
32:28
height of the New Deal. Roosevelt
32:30
didn't have much opposition. But like
32:33
you go back and look at
32:35
the creation of Medicare, Medicaid, like
32:37
the American Medical Association opposed these
32:40
programs. And like there was talk
32:42
of socialism and there was a
32:44
lot of fear of what this
32:47
would do to the private marketplace
32:49
for health care, etc., etc. And
32:51
like the big dig was very
32:54
controversial when it happened, but then
32:56
when it became part of the
32:58
landscape, people... Embraced it and so
33:01
the I think there is some
33:03
notion that once the system is
33:05
up and running Like you aren't
33:08
nearly so caught up in the
33:10
opposition that you had when it
33:13
when things change right? It almost
33:15
makes me wonder as a thought
33:17
experiment like if if every time
33:20
the state lottery rolled out a
33:22
new product. Like if they were
33:24
gonna start offering keno games in
33:27
bars and places that sell alcohol,
33:29
if they had to have like
33:31
a citizen impact statement, and it
33:34
was subject to litigation, I wonder
33:36
what that process would look like,
33:38
if it would draw a lot
33:41
of attention or not, I'm not
33:43
sure. I mean, that's what's fascinating
33:46
about this Hamiltonian, Jeffersonian tension, is
33:48
that. We're not
33:50
of one mind about it. Throughout our
33:52
history, we've had different views in different
33:54
realms about whether we want to raise
33:56
power up into central authority or push
33:58
it down to individuals. When
34:01
you look out across the
34:03
federal bureaucracy, state bureaucracy, are
34:05
there bright spots for you?
34:07
Are there areas of government
34:09
that you think do work
34:11
very smoothly or very effectively?
34:14
Yeah, I mean, you're seeing
34:16
now this broad-based attempt by
34:18
the Trump administration to take
34:20
down these research institutions. In
34:22
many cases, that research has
34:24
worked out entirely to our
34:26
benefit. I mean, you know,
34:28
we should have given Trump
34:30
more credit. Maybe he would
34:32
be in a different frame
34:34
of mind, but warp speed
34:36
brought us vaccines, like those
34:38
are miracle drugs. And they
34:41
were done by centralized agencies
34:43
where they have a certain
34:45
mechanism for deciding who gets
34:47
funding and how much. And
34:49
sometimes they're going to make
34:51
terrible decisions by the same
34:53
token, like, you know, our
34:55
public health is... Much improved
34:57
in general because of decisions
34:59
made by centralized experts who
35:01
understand the science and are
35:03
making discretionary Choices about where
35:05
funding should go. So like
35:08
that's actually a pretty good
35:10
case like the NIH the
35:12
NIH The NIH the DARPA
35:14
which is the defense's industries
35:16
sort of research arm, you
35:18
know when the food and
35:20
drug administration was established at
35:22
the beginning of the 20th
35:24
century like those bills bills
35:26
or very controversial at the
35:28
time because no one had
35:30
ever thought to give the
35:33
federal government that kind of
35:35
regulatory power over the things
35:37
that we eat. And to
35:39
this day, like the degree
35:41
to which we have safe
35:43
food in our grocery stores,
35:45
like that's a result of
35:47
federal regulation. We're not having
35:49
community meetings about whether the...
35:51
FDA has approved the sale
35:53
of eggs from this circumstance,
35:55
right? There we have invested
35:57
power in. centralized experts and
36:00
we depend and celebrate when
36:02
they get things right or
36:04
we or they get things
36:06
right so frequently that we
36:08
we don't even really question
36:10
whether we would want to
36:12
take the authority away from
36:14
them. Mm-hmm. As you just
36:16
mentioned, we're in a moment
36:18
now where the federal government
36:20
is being transformed and some
36:22
parts of it are simply
36:24
being turned off and I
36:27
wonder I feel like there's
36:29
a natural reaction to that
36:31
from folks on the left
36:33
to defend the institutions, right?
36:35
To defend the rules and
36:37
the procedures as they were.
36:39
And I'm wondering if that
36:41
poses a challenge to the
36:43
kind of argument that you're
36:45
making about the need to
36:47
reform the way government works.
36:49
I'm just wondering how you
36:51
think about... the impulse to
36:54
defend the institutions and to
36:56
make them better? Well, I
36:58
certainly am not supportive of
37:00
just a sledgehammer approach to
37:02
reform me the federal government.
37:04
And it seems to me
37:06
that we should be doing
37:08
it in a thoughtful way,
37:10
but you're right that like
37:12
when Elon Musk sends out
37:14
an email asking people to
37:16
justify what they did that
37:18
week they did that week,
37:21
Progressive shouldn't be against that.
37:23
Maybe a burden for those
37:25
people to have to justify
37:27
what they did, but they
37:29
should be able to justify
37:31
what they did that week.
37:33
You don't want to be
37:35
defending the notion that there
37:37
are bureaucrats who have jobs
37:39
who are not actually producing
37:41
for the public interest. They're
37:43
being paid with taxpayer dollars
37:46
for a reason. So like
37:48
the notion that we wouldn't
37:50
constantly be trying to improve
37:52
and reform bureaucracies so that
37:54
they're more effective. That should
37:56
be our point of view.
37:58
Their point of view is
38:00
that government is generally bad.
38:02
trying to undermine it so
38:04
that people are not getting
38:06
the benefit of having a
38:08
proactive, thoughtful, effective public sector.
38:10
Like, they don't believe in
38:13
the public sector. They want
38:15
to give more power to
38:17
the private sector. That's not
38:19
a progressive point of view.
38:21
But that doesn't mean that
38:23
progressives should be in favor
38:25
of ineffective government. That should
38:27
be, in fact, more offensive
38:29
to us than it is
38:31
to them. Like there should
38:33
be more examples of us.
38:35
taking a scalpel to ineffective
38:37
bureaucracies and firing people who
38:40
aren't doing their job and
38:42
evaluating whether this program is
38:44
more effective at fighting property
38:46
than this program. And so
38:48
we're going to eliminate the
38:50
second program and invest more
38:52
in the first. That should
38:54
be constantly on our minds.
38:56
How can we squeeze more
38:58
out of the lemon of
39:00
what the taxpayers have given
39:02
us so that they are
39:04
seeing, feeling, and touching? really
39:07
an effective institution. We should
39:09
be the stewards of good
39:11
government, not Elon Musk. To
39:13
close, I'm curious, looking ahead,
39:15
is there a policy area,
39:17
a project where you feel
39:19
like the left needs to
39:21
take up that more emboldened,
39:23
muscular, creative energy? Where do
39:25
you see the potential for
39:27
that? So there's this famous
39:29
story where Robert Carrow who's
39:32
written this book about Robert
39:34
Moses. He says, you know,
39:36
every time I go to
39:38
a cocktail party, someone comes
39:40
up to me, often someone
39:42
of the real estate variety,
39:44
and says to me, isn't
39:46
it time we had another
39:48
Robert Moses? And Carrow responds,
39:50
you know, I not being
39:52
someone who wants to get
39:54
into an argument. Simply say
39:56
no and walk away. And.
40:00
I think that the
40:02
thing that I took
40:04
from that was that
40:06
there are would be
40:08
Robert Moses's everywhere. Like
40:10
New York is not
40:12
short of middle-aged men
40:14
with gumption, right? But
40:17
what's changed is the
40:19
environment in which those
40:21
people operate. So I
40:23
think that there are
40:25
progressives of all stripes
40:27
who are eager, willing...
40:29
maybe frothing at the
40:31
mouth to do big
40:33
things, to improve public
40:36
health, to improve infrastructure,
40:38
to build more housing,
40:40
people who want to
40:42
take care, to take
40:44
the best advantage of
40:46
the clean energy revolution,
40:48
like who want to
40:50
save the climate. On
40:52
all these fronts, I
40:54
think that there's enormous
40:57
possibility and enormous excitement,
40:59
but that reforms... designed
41:01
to stop bad projects
41:03
from happening are now
41:05
precluding good ones from
41:07
getting off the ground.
41:09
Thanks so much. Thanks
41:11
for having me. You
41:13
made me love you.
41:15
I didn't want to
41:18
do it. I didn't
41:20
want to do it.
41:22
I didn't want to
41:24
do it. the
41:28
time you knew
41:30
it. I guess
41:33
you always knew
41:35
it. You made
41:37
me happy sometimes.
41:39
You made me
41:41
sad. But there
41:43
were times dear.
41:45
You made me
41:47
feel so bad.
41:49
Mark Dunkleman is
41:51
the author of
41:53
Why Nothing Works.
41:55
Who and how
41:57
to bring it
41:59
back. And that
42:01
is it for our run
42:03
of interview episodes this season.
42:06
However, we will be back
42:08
in your feed next week
42:10
to share a story from
42:13
our friends at NPR's Through
42:15
Line that zeros in on
42:17
a truly key figure in
42:20
the everlasting push and pull
42:22
between Jeffersonian and Hamiltonian thinking.
42:24
It's a great story, so
42:27
stay tuned for that. And
42:29
also just stay tuned to
42:31
this feed. We will be
42:34
back with another series sometime
42:36
in the next year. And
42:38
the best way to know
42:41
about it is to subscribe
42:43
and follow wherever you're listening
42:46
right now. You can also
42:48
follow me on socials. Probably
42:50
the best place to hear
42:53
about new projects I've got
42:55
is on Blue Sky at
42:57
Ian Cost. I don't think
43:00
there's another Ian Cost on
43:02
there, so you'll find me.
43:04
This episode was edited by
43:07
Lacy Roberts. May Lay is
43:09
the project manager and the
43:11
executive producer is Devin Maverick
43:14
Robbins. My co-producer for the
43:16
whole scratch and win series
43:18
is Isabelle Hibbert. Scratch and
43:21
win is a production of
43:23
GBH News and distributed by
43:25
PRX. Yes, I do. Indeed,
43:28
I do. You know I
43:30
do. So give me, give
43:32
me, give me, give me
43:35
what I cry for. You
43:37
know you got the brand
43:39
of kisses that I die
43:42
for. You know you made
43:44
me. You know you made
43:47
me. You know you made
43:49
me. all
43:59
the time. you know, it. Thank
44:01
you. Hey, I want to make sure
44:03
that you know, this series you're listening to
44:05
right now is part of an ongoing feed,
44:08
I want to make
44:10
sure that you know
44:12
this series you're listening
44:14
to right now us
44:16
part of an ongoing
44:18
feed stories from the
44:20
past to help us
44:22
understand our present. all Our
44:25
first season is all
44:27
about infrastructure. The second
44:29
season is about gambling. and
44:31
we've got more seasons planned. planned. So So
44:33
if you want to stay on top of
44:35
what the team and I are doing,
44:37
go ahead and follow or subscribe to this
44:39
podcast wherever you listen. We've got
44:42
some really exciting stories coming up, and I
44:44
hope you'll stay with us. Thanks.
44:46
us. Thanks.
Podchaser is the ultimate destination for podcast data, search, and discovery. Learn More