Jason Furman: Why Everyone Is Wrong About the Economy

Jason Furman: Why Everyone Is Wrong About the Economy

Released Wednesday, 16th April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Jason Furman: Why Everyone Is Wrong About the Economy

Jason Furman: Why Everyone Is Wrong About the Economy

Jason Furman: Why Everyone Is Wrong About the Economy

Jason Furman: Why Everyone Is Wrong About the Economy

Wednesday, 16th April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:00

This is The Reason Interview

0:02

with Nick Gillespie. My guest

0:04

today is Harvard economist Jason

0:06

Furman, who is one of

0:08

Barack Obama's chief economic advisors

0:10

and an architect of the

0:12

Affordable Care Act. These days,

0:14

he's in the news for

0:17

his withering critique of Joe

0:19

Biden's dismal economic record and

0:21

his two -fisted attacks on Donald

0:23

Trump's trade policy. We talk

0:25

about Furman's defense of global

0:27

markets, Obamacare's unfulfilled promises, and

0:30

why he now thinks the national

0:32

debt and ai are bigger deals

0:34

than he used to believe here

0:36

is the reason interview with jason

0:38

firman uh

0:42

jason firman thanks for talking to reason

0:44

really excited to do so love love

0:46

reading you So

0:48

you recently wrote a piece

0:50

talking about the failure of

0:52

Bidenomics and what you called

0:54

the post -neoliberal delusion. Let's

0:57

start with that. You know, Irving Kristol

0:59

famously said that a neoconservative is a

1:01

liberal who got mugged by reality. What

1:04

is a neoliberal, the way that you're defining

1:06

that term? Sometimes I think a

1:08

neoliberal is like whatever I happen

1:10

to think that somebody else disagrees with

1:12

and they bundle it all together. It's

1:15

often defined more in the negative

1:17

as an epithet. If I had to

1:19

do it in the positive, it

1:21

is one, understands gains from trade,

1:24

that when you have markets, when

1:26

you have exchange, you can end

1:28

up with more for everyone. Number

1:31

two, respects.

1:33

a corollary that follows from that, that

1:35

decentralized decisions can result in the

1:37

best outcome. Now, you may want regulation

1:39

or taxes to move them in

1:41

a certain direction, and I might want

1:43

more of those than you would

1:45

want. I suspect that's true. Number

1:48

three, that scarcity

1:50

is at the heart of

1:52

all interesting public policy problems,

1:54

and so you have to

1:57

respect trade -offs. budget constraints.

1:59

At a macro level, that means

2:01

you have to worry about the

2:03

budget deficit. At a micro level,

2:05

that means you have to do

2:07

cost benefit analysis. And finally, something

2:09

that follows from all of that,

2:11

that you don't have an automatic,

2:13

easy answer to any question. You

2:15

really have to sort of work

2:17

through it, do the analysis, and

2:19

figure it out. So there's some

2:21

technocratic mindset associated with it as

2:23

well. You said that neoliberal is

2:25

often invoked as a kind of

2:27

term of derision or dismissal. And

2:29

I think I'm right about this, correct me

2:32

if I'm wrong, that it started being

2:34

used in that way around the end

2:36

of the 90s, you know, after NAFTA

2:38

had been passed, started by, I guess,

2:40

Reagan, Bush, then, you

2:42

know, ultimately done by Clinton. And

2:44

then at the end of the

2:47

90s, the beginning of the World

2:49

Trade Organization. And this is when...

2:51

people who were interested in kind

2:53

of increasing global trade and lowering

2:55

tax or tariff barriers and things

2:57

like that started to be called

2:59

pejoratively neoliberals. Does that track? That

3:02

tracks, but it really exploded about

3:04

a decade ago because there wasn't,

3:06

at least on the democratic side,

3:09

a very well articulated alternative

3:11

to it. And in some ways

3:13

there isn't, but there are a

3:15

set of them. Modern monetary theory

3:17

with deficits don't matter. A neo

3:19

-Brandeisian approach to antitrust that says

3:21

big companies are presumptively bad. Right,

3:23

just bigness is a curse. And

3:26

the fact that they're big means

3:28

we should be thinking bad. Breaking

3:30

them up. Yep. During

3:32

the inflation debates, the focus on

3:34

greed as a cause of inflation

3:37

and stopping greed as a solution

3:39

to inflation. And then people writing

3:41

about industrial policy. So

3:43

these are some different

3:45

strands. But they all

3:47

combine together in a

3:49

rejection of a lot

3:52

of those ideas of

3:54

gains from trade, decentralization.

3:58

and the importance of taking trade off seriously.

4:00

So this is, I mean, you were in

4:02

the Obama administration. I mean,

4:04

this is a pretty lonely place

4:06

you're occupying as somebody who identifies with

4:08

the Democratic Party, right? It's

4:11

not totally lonely. I mean, President

4:13

Obama put a lot of effort into

4:15

negotiating the Trans -Pacific Partnership, a free

4:17

trade agreement with our friends in

4:19

the Pacific. He had a proposal that

4:21

I spent a lot of time

4:23

on, on corporate tax reform that would

4:25

have lowered the corporate tax rate.

4:27

He proposed 28%. At the time, it

4:29

was 35%. And he was, I think,

4:32

pretty sympathetic to the markets. But

4:34

Obama left office a decade ago. Sorry.

4:36

At this point, it's

4:38

mixed. You know, it's

4:40

not like people don't listen to economists.

4:43

There's economists in government. There's economists

4:45

in Fed. There's a lot of economists

4:47

around. In the Biden administration, I

4:49

would say the policy took a turn

4:51

against this. And the rhetoric took

4:53

a massive pivot against this. In

4:55

some ways, the language turned even more

4:58

than the policy did. I mean,

5:00

you know, you would have been

5:02

working with Joe Biden, you know,

5:04

in the Obama White House. I

5:06

mean, did you see it coming

5:08

that? his presidency was going to

5:10

be as, you know, as tilted

5:13

towards kind of progressive concerns as

5:15

opposed to kind of, you know,

5:18

market -friendly liberal concerns?

5:20

Or did that kind of

5:22

blindside you? It mostly blindsided

5:24

me compared to Obama. Obama's

5:27

quite cerebral, comes at things from

5:29

the perspective of ideas and policy,

5:31

may end up with a big

5:33

dose of politics. He wouldn't have

5:35

gotten where he was without that.

5:37

Biden pretty much starts and ends

5:39

with politics. He

5:43

has certain things he likes. He

5:45

definitely likes labor unions quite a

5:47

lot. So that part of it

5:49

was not a surprise. But the

5:51

degree to which he adopted something

5:53

that was much more towards the

5:55

left within the Democratic Party, yeah,

5:57

that did surprise me after he

6:00

ran in the primaries as the

6:02

centrist. Why do you think

6:04

the neoliberal consensus, and again,

6:06

your article is called The

6:08

Post -Neoliberal Delusion, why did

6:10

that neoliberal coalition

6:12

within the Democratic Party breakdown?

6:16

I don't know. There's one argument

6:19

that it is China entered

6:21

the WTO, lots of suffering resulted,

6:23

and there was a populist

6:25

revolt in the form of Donald

6:27

Trump, and you needed to

6:30

listen to that and learn. I'm

6:32

much less sure that that's the

6:34

case. If you look at inequality

6:36

in the 20 years after China

6:38

entered the WTO, it actually went

6:40

up much less than it did

6:42

in the 20 years before China

6:44

And most economists at this point,

6:46

to the extent they talk about

6:48

a China shock, it had kind

6:50

of been absorbed by around 2010

6:53

anyway. Yes, you can debate the

6:55

original China shop because there were

6:57

definitely negative sides. There were also

6:59

a bunch of positive sides. I

7:01

think the positives that weighed, the

7:03

negatives. Regardless, everyone agreed it was

7:05

basically over. I think it's also

7:07

possible, and this is real speculation

7:09

on my part, that there are

7:11

ways in which the Democratic Party

7:13

got culturally out of touch with

7:15

Americans, that that led to some

7:17

backlash. And that was then misinterpreted

7:19

and used as an argument for

7:21

changing. on economic policy. What do

7:23

you think the role of somebody

7:25

like Bernie Sanders is in this,

7:27

whether it's a rhetorical or a

7:29

policy shift? He obviously, you know,

7:31

the fact that Hillary Clinton won,

7:33

or rather Hillary Clinton lost in

7:35

what should have been an easy

7:37

win. I mean, I think that's

7:39

a legitimate statement, but Sanders, clearly

7:41

his insurgency in 2016 hurt her

7:43

on some level. And is

7:45

it then that, like, if Hillary may

7:47

or may not have been a neoliberal

7:49

the way you're talking about it, but

7:51

Sanders definitely was not. He was anti -WTO.

7:53

He was anti -trade, very pro -union protectionist.

7:55

Is that where some of the energy

7:57

for rejection of neoliberalism in the Democratic

7:59

Party comes from? Look, I'm not a...

8:01

expert. I'm a hobbyist. I pay a

8:03

bit of attention. I have much more

8:05

conviction around what I think is good

8:07

for the world and bad for the

8:09

world. And by the way, if you're

8:11

governing and you do things that are

8:13

good for the world, I think you

8:15

get rewarded. Do things that are bad

8:17

for the world, you get punished. And

8:19

we just saw that in the last

8:21

election. But I

8:24

don't know. Americans

8:26

are a strange mixture of

8:29

contradictory views. I myself have

8:31

a set of contradictory views.

8:34

You can tap into a sort

8:36

of fear and loathing of billionaires.

8:38

And every billionaire is a policy

8:41

failure. But people can also laud

8:43

and be thrilled about the things

8:45

that billionaires invented and did and

8:47

changed their lives and understand that

8:49

and both of those together at

8:52

once. Yeah, on that point, Forbes,

8:54

I guess, came out with its newest

8:56

billionaires list. And Jerry Seinfeld is a

8:58

billionaire now. And it's like, I don't

9:00

think people think about Jerry. Seinfeld

9:02

and Elon Musk in the same category.

9:05

But who has Jerry Seinfeld killed, right?

9:07

Who has he hurt? Yeah. I mean,

9:09

Robert Nozick in his book had an

9:11

example of Wilt Chamberlain. I do that

9:13

in my class. I'm not sure they've

9:15

all heard of Wilt Chamberlain. So I

9:17

put Taylor. Wilt Chamberlain post -MeToo, I

9:19

don't know. I put Taylor Swift up

9:21

on the screen. And, you know, did

9:24

she make you better? I do

9:26

say that I'm not endorsing

9:28

her music. But,

9:30

you know, did she make people

9:32

worse off by being a billionaire

9:34

or did she make people better

9:36

off and in the course of

9:39

that became a billionaire? Ken, you

9:41

know, as you noted, I mean,

9:43

there's a shift on the right

9:45

also. You know, Trump is post

9:47

-neoliberal. He does not like global

9:49

trade. He does not like. you

9:52

know, kind of market forces. To

9:54

some degree, he's more pro -business, I

9:56

think, in a real way than

9:58

Hillary Clinton, Biden, or Kamala Harris

10:00

might have been. But he's antagonistic

10:02

towards the liberal project, if we're

10:05

talking about things like global trade

10:07

and decentralized, you know, open borders,

10:09

open services, and things like that.

10:12

Why, from an economic point of view,

10:14

we're not talking politics here, You

10:17

know, the period of, you know, in

10:19

the post -war generally, but then since

10:21

the collapse of the Soviet Union

10:23

and since, you know, the WTO was

10:25

created at the beginning of this

10:27

century, things have gotten better for the

10:29

vast majority of people in America,

10:31

you know, on a material basis. Why

10:33

then are people, why do

10:36

they not see that and why

10:38

are they captivated by things

10:40

like, you know, stronger tariff policies

10:42

and more protectionism? Yeah. So

10:44

first of all, on the premise

10:46

of your question, I agree. President

10:49

Trump, in some ways, is

10:51

an even bigger rejection of anything

10:53

resembling economic analysis, thinking about

10:55

trade -offs, thinking about gains from

10:57

trade and the like. And for

11:00

the most part, has eschewed

11:02

any intellectual rationalization of it. There's

11:04

some people out there like

11:06

Orrin Cass that provide some. intellectual

11:09

foundations for it or attempt to

11:11

provide some intellectual foundations for it. But

11:13

for the most part, that's actually

11:15

not what Donald Trump is interested in.

11:17

They make a lot of noise.

11:19

On the pro -business, in the wake

11:21

of the tariff announcements, I thought it

11:23

was striking how many people from

11:26

the administration, including the Treasury Secretary, went

11:28

out to talk down big business

11:30

as a globalist project, as something for

11:32

the elite. We don't care about

11:34

the stock market. We don't care about

11:36

the businesses. pretty

11:38

pivoting pretty quickly away

11:40

from business. So what's

11:43

the commonality here? There's

11:46

always the sense that things used

11:48

to be better. And that if

11:50

we could just get back to

11:52

the golden age that was, that's

11:54

been a powerful thing throughout humanity.

11:56

That siren. Song has been more

11:58

powerful in the wake of financial

12:00

crises. It's something you see. That's

12:02

where populists often arise. And when

12:04

Trump first rose, we weren't that

12:06

far past a financial crisis. We've

12:08

just had another type of enormous

12:10

amount of dislocation in our country,

12:12

both from COVID and through a

12:14

set of extremely rapid cultural changes.

12:17

And so I tend to blame

12:19

that. rather than looking at the

12:21

statistics on median family income, which

12:23

has grown quite strongly, or even

12:25

wage inequality, which has actually fallen.

12:27

Yeah, and I mean this, it

12:29

grew under Trump, you know, and

12:31

then there's the COVID moment. And

12:33

then after that, under Biden, real

12:35

median household income, individual income all went

12:38

up, which is a good sign. It's

12:40

a sign that the economy is kind

12:42

of delivering. but people

12:44

aren't interested in that. When

12:46

you said there have been radical

12:48

or rapid social transformations, what

12:50

do you mean? I just meant

12:52

the Black Lives Matter movement,

12:54

how rapidly things change related to

12:56

trans and the like. There

12:59

was a sense that a lot

13:01

of people in the country

13:03

were being caught in a very

13:05

big and very rapid set

13:07

of changes. When

13:10

you're talking about the failure of

13:12

Bidenomics, Biden spent a lot of

13:14

money on a couple of big

13:16

projects or big spending bills. Can

13:18

you talk about them and how

13:20

they failed to deliver what he

13:23

and his supporters claimed that they

13:25

were going to do? Yeah, let's

13:27

just tick through five quickly. There's

13:29

the American Rescue Plan, $1 .9

13:31

trillion. And the main

13:33

thing we got from that

13:35

was inflation. It's possible there was

13:38

a slightly faster recovery, but

13:40

the U .S. recovery wasn't actually

13:42

much faster than any other place,

13:44

at least in 2021 and

13:46

into 2022. Second, student

13:48

loan relief. This to me

13:50

in many ways was the most

13:53

egregious. This was done in August

13:55

2022. Inflation was raging.

13:57

The deficit was high. Interest

13:59

rates were high. And another

14:01

$500 billion was poured on

14:03

top of that without Congress. authorizing

14:06

that money in a way that

14:08

I think is quite abusive of

14:10

presidential authority. Third,

14:12

infrastructure. Here I

14:15

have a mixed view. I think

14:17

it's a noble goal. I think

14:19

it is a worthwhile goal. But

14:21

it was accompanied with so many

14:23

new rules and restraints on how

14:25

the money would go out. Moreover,

14:27

so much money was spent so

14:29

quickly in an economy that was

14:31

already overstretched that it ended up

14:33

driving prices up. rather than getting

14:35

more infrastructure. That's where I think

14:37

things like the abundance agenda are

14:39

quite important that are about building

14:41

more stuff. Fourth is

14:43

climate. Here, I like a

14:45

lot of it. I would love a

14:47

carbon tax. To me, that's the

14:49

simple solution. I think libertarians should love

14:51

that solution too. Well, I think

14:54

in principle they do. And then like

14:56

when you start. looking at the

14:58

politics against dice here, but in any

15:00

case. So that's what I'd love.

15:02

You can't pass one. That's not Biden's

15:04

fault. There was a combination of

15:06

subsidizing the use of wind and electricity.

15:08

I think that's okay. Those use

15:10

less carbon. But there was also a

15:12

lot of remaking American industry. So

15:14

we would make solar panels in the

15:16

United States. That's where I... get

15:18

off the train. I'd rather just buy

15:21

the cheapest ones from around the

15:23

world. And finally, there's the chips program

15:25

where from an economic perspective, I

15:27

think we're going to get worse microchips

15:29

and not create great jobs. National

15:31

security and resilience, I think it will

15:33

be a plus. And that plus

15:35

outweighs for me the economic minus. I'm

15:37

willing to pay a cost in

15:39

terms of efficiency to have microchips made

15:41

here, advanced ones, instead of all

15:43

in Taiwan. They're more

15:45

expensive and they're less good. But they're ours.

15:48

That's not my goal. Yeah, but I would

15:50

say that about very few things. And

15:52

that's where, again, the cost benefit comes

15:54

into play. If you tell me that

15:56

you think your microchip plan is going

15:58

to create more jobs and better jobs

16:00

and increase economic growth, I'm not going

16:02

to believe you. If you come and

16:04

tell me, you know what? It's going

16:06

to cost some money. It's going to

16:08

be a little bit inefficient. but

16:10

here's what the national security benefit is,

16:13

then we can go back and forth.

16:15

How big is the economic cost? How

16:17

big is the national security benefit? Is

16:19

it worth it? Is it not? Some

16:21

of these programs, and there were some

16:23

of them under Trump and under Biden

16:25

when we're talking about COVID. Can you

16:27

explain from an economic point of view?

16:30

I am merely, I'm a simple

16:32

English major and a psychology

16:34

major. Why is it

16:36

bad when to... Tell people

16:38

at a time like COVID,

16:41

we're going to double or

16:43

triple your unemployment benefits and

16:45

extend them for long periods

16:47

of time. Why does that

16:49

end up having a bad effect on

16:51

the economy? Right. Well, if your goal

16:53

is to get people not to work,

16:55

and that might have been a goal

16:57

in March and April of 2020, that's

17:00

a perfectly fine way to do

17:02

it. The policy lasted

17:04

through September 2021. At

17:06

that point, there were record

17:08

job openings. People were

17:10

either vaccinated. or had caught

17:12

COVID and were less susceptible to

17:14

it again. And by that point,

17:16

it really started to interfere with

17:19

people getting back into work. I

17:21

mean, why would you possibly want

17:23

to work when you could get

17:25

more money not working? I think

17:27

that almost every day until my

17:29

retirement, I'm sure. And then the

17:31

second issue in the whole response

17:34

is if you give people more

17:36

money, let's say we as a

17:38

country were producing and buying and

17:40

selling $1 ,000 a year. 1 ,000

17:42

units of whatever. You give people

17:44

enough money to buy 1 ,100. At

17:47

the same time that something's happened

17:49

to the economy, so it can only

17:51

make 900, the result is you're

17:53

not going to get more stuff. You're

17:55

just going to get higher prices

17:57

for the existing amount of stuff. is

17:59

more dollars chasing the same number

18:01

of goods. This is textbook inflation. Yeah,

18:03

exactly. So it made sense to

18:05

protect people. you

18:08

don't want your living standards to go

18:10

way, way down because of COVID. But

18:12

what we ended up doing was not

18:14

doing the math and figuring out what

18:16

you needed to do to protect people,

18:18

not doing the targeting to get to

18:20

the people who needed it. And so

18:22

the result was just much, much, much

18:24

more money than we could possibly make

18:26

in terms of stuff. And so it

18:28

drove up the price of that stuff.

18:30

Where does it come from? I mean,

18:32

has it always been this way that

18:35

You know, what you're saying is

18:37

obvious, but then it became

18:39

politically inexpedient to admit that, particularly

18:41

when Biden was in office

18:43

and this was happening or when

18:45

he was starting to run

18:47

for president and then Harris. I

18:50

mean, is it just simply

18:52

political posturing that Democrats are

18:54

not going to admit the

18:56

policies that their guys pursued,

18:58

you know, caused inflation? just

19:01

in the same way that Republicans

19:03

won't admit it when it's their

19:06

guy in the dock. I think

19:08

there's a real problem with the

19:10

way information is aggregated and transmitted.

19:12

There were some people I know

19:14

who, when that first stimulus bill

19:16

were passed, who were emailing

19:18

me, hey, this is really too large,

19:21

but I don't want to undermine Biden

19:23

by saying that. Or,

19:25

you know, this is too large, but

19:27

I'm afraid people are in the student

19:29

loan case. This is a bad policy,

19:31

but I don't want to get destroyed

19:34

the way, Jason, I saw you get

19:36

destroyed on Twitter. Some people,

19:38

though, don't even quite see that. So

19:40

I've had people reach out to me

19:42

who have said, hey, you know, aren't

19:44

the Trump tax cuts going to cause

19:46

inflation, Jason? You should write about that.

19:48

And I'm like, wait, weren't you the

19:50

same person that a couple of years

19:52

ago told me the Biden fiscal expansion?

19:55

wasn't causing inflation? Like, why does the

19:57

fiscal impact on inflation depend on the

19:59

political party of the person? And it's

20:01

hard to think outside your own bubble

20:03

and your own ecosystem. And all of

20:05

this creates a sort of false sense

20:07

of what it is people actually think

20:09

when a lot of people aren't saying

20:11

what they think. And some of those

20:14

people are tenured professors who aren't going

20:16

to be, you know, in no risk

20:18

of being fired. I

20:20

guess in a similar

20:24

You know, we're hearing this now

20:26

because Trump has, you know, Trump

20:28

has levied tariffs. I mean, depending

20:30

on what day of the week

20:32

and when this airs, who knows

20:34

what the case will be. But,

20:36

you know, currently he's suspended his

20:38

tariffs or put them on ice

20:40

for 90 days except for China, etc.

20:43

But you hear a lot of

20:45

Republicans now saying, well, you know, tariffs

20:47

aren't taxes. and tariffs

20:49

are paid for by the country

20:51

that is sending goods, not

20:54

the people who are importing them

20:56

here in America. You recently

20:58

wrote a piece in the New

21:00

York Times saying that Trump's

21:02

tariffs are based on an economic

21:04

theory that makes no sense. Can

21:07

you explain that? What is

21:09

wrong with the tariffs the

21:11

way that Trump is doing?

21:13

Yeah, basically every step of

21:15

Trump's mentality on trade is

21:17

wrong. First of all, imports

21:20

are good. They're a wonderful

21:22

thing. We like to import

21:24

coffee. We like to import

21:26

cars. We like to import

21:28

the inputs we need for

21:30

American manufacturing. Second of all,

21:32

trade deficits don't reflect other

21:34

countries' tariffs and trade policies.

21:36

There's countries with huge tariffs

21:38

that run large trade deficits.

21:40

There's countries with low tariffs

21:42

that run trade surpluses. Third,

21:44

our retaliation against them is

21:47

going to shrink imports. but

21:49

it's also going to shrink

21:51

exports. And that hurts consumers

21:53

on the import side. It

21:55

hurts American workers on the

21:57

export side. And so just

21:59

every step of his reasoning

22:01

and fixation on trade deficits

22:03

is just the wrong, wrong

22:05

way to think about trade.

22:07

Is there a consensus forming

22:09

that either that that's a

22:12

bad policy, a kind of

22:14

bipartisan or transpartisan? consensus

22:16

forming that, okay, these tariffs are not

22:18

working and we're getting strong signals from

22:20

global markets as well as, you know,

22:22

the things like the S &P 500

22:24

and the Dow Jones. But is,

22:26

you know, is there also a

22:28

kind of transpartisan, you know, coalition

22:30

sort of saying like, oh, maybe

22:32

we should be more protectionist? There's,

22:35

President Trump went so far that

22:37

I think he discredited it

22:39

for even many people on the

22:42

protectionist side. So people like

22:44

free trade more than they ever

22:46

did before right now, more

22:48

than they ever would after listening

22:50

to me extol the benefits

22:52

of free trade. So I don't

22:55

think he's building that much

22:57

of a coalition against it. But

22:59

he has shifted the Overton

23:01

window enormously. I mean, he did

23:03

this initial reciprocal tariff announcement

23:05

on Liberation Day. Then

23:07

he took away. You've lost.

23:10

You're using his language, right?

23:12

You call it the Gulf of

23:14

America as well. I don't care

23:16

much about words. Maybe that's a

23:18

mistake. Then he

23:21

took away some of them,

23:23

the so -called reciprocal part.

23:25

So that left the

23:27

United States with tariff rates

23:29

that are the rates

23:31

that prevail in Iran, Venezuela.

23:33

and a bunch of other countries

23:35

that aren't nearly as economically

23:37

successful as Iran and Venezuela. And

23:40

that's now become the reasonable,

23:43

moderate, decent position. And so the

23:45

Overton window has shifted quite

23:47

a lot, and I'm not sure

23:49

how we can shift it

23:51

back. A place

23:53

where your thinking has evolved

23:55

over the years has

23:57

to do with the role

23:59

of debt and deficits

24:01

in larger macroeconomic concerns. I

24:04

think it was in 2019,

24:06

you wrote a piece with

24:09

Larry Summers, another Harvard grad

24:11

and administration official back in

24:13

the Clinton years. where

24:15

you were kind of poo -pooing, you know,

24:18

debt, you know, it's not that big a

24:20

deal and it should never really get in

24:22

the way of doing what's right, you know,

24:24

in terms of helping the poor, you know,

24:26

et cetera. You have kind

24:28

of revised some of that. Can you talk

24:30

a little bit about where you are now

24:32

and how you got to that position? Yeah.

24:34

So to say I've evolved on the debt

24:37

is unfair. I've zigzagged on the debt. So

24:39

I was concerned about it

24:41

in the 90s. Then I

24:43

got increasingly less concerned about

24:46

it. Then I got more

24:48

concerned about it. I'd like

24:50

to think that I'm following

24:52

the data. And when interest

24:54

rates are low, we really

24:56

could afford more debt. When

24:58

interest rates are high, we

25:00

can't afford more debt. It's

25:02

possible my thinking has evolved

25:04

and changed even subject to

25:06

the data. But a world

25:08

with 70 % debt to

25:11

GDP and a 2 % interest

25:13

rate is just very, very

25:15

different from 100 % debt

25:17

to GDP. 4 .5 % interest

25:19

rate. Why does large and

25:21

persistent and growing national debt,

25:23

and whether we're using debt

25:25

held by the public or

25:27

gross debt, which includes intergovernmental

25:29

holdings, why when that grows

25:32

and particularly crosses the 90

25:34

% or 100 % of GDP

25:36

threshold, why is that a

25:38

problem? So I don't know that we

25:40

know what the threshold is. Argentina

25:42

had a massive financial crisis, including

25:44

a fiscal crisis when it

25:46

had debt of 45 % of

25:48

GDP. The UK during the,

25:50

I think it was the Napoleonic

25:52

Wars, got as high as 250%.

25:55

So it does depend on. why

25:57

you're borrowing, do people trust your

25:59

country, and the like. Right, and

26:01

it helps, I mean, the U .S.,

26:03

beyond everything else, because the dollar

26:05

is the global reserve currency, we're

26:07

working with different rules than, you

26:09

know, smaller countries.

26:11

Yeah, even than Germany or Canada. They

26:14

can borrow much less than we

26:16

can. I mean, the first thing I'd

26:18

say is, if you were czar,

26:20

or I was czar, or anyone was

26:22

czar, there is just no way

26:24

that your economic plan would be, we're

26:26

going to spend at the current

26:28

rate, tax at the current rate, and

26:30

then make some larger abrupt change

26:32

20 years in the future. You would

26:35

rather make a smaller change now

26:37

than a larger change in the future.

26:39

In economics, that's called tax smoothing.

26:41

The consequence of not doing that is

26:43

for sure we get less economic

26:45

growth. And we raise the chance of

26:47

a fiscal crisis. And I don't

26:49

know how high that chance is. But

26:51

look, right now, I pay homeowners

26:53

insurance against the risk that my house

26:55

will burn down. The fact that

26:58

my house didn't burn down last year,

27:00

the year before, the year before

27:02

that, doesn't mean I'm like a loser

27:04

and a sucker for having bought

27:06

this. I think of deficit reduction in

27:08

some ways just like that. Why

27:12

does large and growing debt

27:14

reduce economic growth? It means the

27:16

government is borrowing more money,

27:18

which drives up interest rates. Driving

27:20

up interest rates drives down

27:22

business investment, drives down home building.

27:24

The other way in which

27:26

it matters is you might get

27:28

out of that if you

27:31

borrow from abroad to support your

27:33

investment. Your

27:35

economic growth, you have to give

27:37

it to those foreign countries to repay

27:39

them for everything you borrowed. So

27:41

either way, you're either doing less investment

27:43

or you're having to repay foreigners

27:45

if you want to maintain your investment.

27:48

This was during the fiscal crisis

27:50

or the financial crisis or

27:52

shortly after it. Carmen

27:54

Reinhardt, Vincent Reinhardt, and Ken

27:56

Rogoff wrote a paper, one

27:58

version of which then they

28:00

corrected. It really

28:03

said, you know, as you approach

28:05

a 90 percent debt to

28:07

GDP ratio, that these episodes, they

28:09

looked at a series of

28:11

them over the past couple of

28:13

hundred years, you know,

28:15

that it tended to reduce long

28:18

term economic growth, you know, which

28:20

average for them, it was about

28:22

an average of 23 years of

28:24

periods they call debt overhang. And

28:26

it reduced. growth in general from

28:28

something like 3 % annually to 2

28:30

% annually or like 1%. point,

28:33

does that sound about right to

28:35

you? And does that help explain

28:37

the sluggish economic growth that we've

28:39

really been witnessing for a good

28:41

part of the 21st century? I'll

28:43

take your second question first. I

28:45

think the causation might go more

28:48

the other direction, that there was

28:50

a set of sluggishness either from

28:52

slower productivity growth, from demography or

28:54

whatever it was. And in order

28:56

to keep the economy going, We

28:58

needed the extra debt. And what's

29:00

the evidence for that? We didn't

29:02

until 2021 get a lot of

29:05

inflation. So through 2019, the problem

29:07

was low inflation, not high inflation.

29:09

That is generally indicative of demand

29:11

being too low. So I don't

29:13

think the debt was overheating our

29:15

economy. I think it was making

29:17

up for these problems. And that

29:20

was part of why Larry and

29:22

I thought we needed more debt.

29:24

We overshot what we might possibly

29:26

have imagined. In

29:28

terms of Ken Rogoff

29:30

and Carmen Reinhart's research, those

29:32

papers were suggestive. There

29:34

was a lot of correlation,

29:36

not causation. So directionally,

29:38

I think they're right. But

29:40

I'm not convinced about

29:43

some nonlinear threshold. In terms

29:45

of dealing with debt

29:47

and national debt and deficits,

29:49

I mean, you now

29:51

kind of propose We should

29:53

be trying to balance

29:55

the budget, which we've done

29:57

in our lifetime. Balance

30:00

the budget excluding interest payments.

30:02

Balance what's called the primary The

30:04

primary deficit. And also invoking

30:06

a kind of strict PAYGO policy

30:08

for when we spend more

30:10

or spend less. Can you describe

30:12

how PAYGO would work and

30:15

why that's important? I think PAYGO

30:17

is important for two reasons.

30:19

It says that anything you do

30:21

you have to pay for.

30:23

So you want to give money

30:25

for student loan debt relief. Great.

30:28

You can pass a law that

30:30

costs $500 billion. You then need to

30:32

raise taxes by $500 billion or

30:34

cut spending by $500 billion. That

30:37

has a macroeconomic rationale that when you're

30:39

in a hole, you don't want to

30:41

keep digging. And this stops you from

30:43

digging. I think perhaps even more important,

30:45

it lets you figure out whether the

30:47

things you're doing are a good idea

30:49

or not. Almost every idea

30:51

that involves giving money to

30:53

some group is a good idea

30:56

until you ask where the

30:58

money is coming from. If

31:00

you can say, here's where the

31:02

money is coming from, here's where the

31:04

money is going, and on net

31:06

this is still a good idea, it's

31:09

much more likely that this is

31:11

a choice that's worth society making. But

31:13

if you obfuscate that choice and

31:15

you give the benefit to the people

31:17

today for sure, and you... given

31:19

uncertain costs that might even be even

31:21

larger to people in the future,

31:23

then I don't trust that we did

31:25

the right social cost benefit to

31:28

decide whether or not that idea was

31:30

worth it. Do you think there's

31:32

any chance in hell that we're going

31:34

to get back to a budgeting

31:36

process? And this is politics, but it

31:38

stems from economics that we'll get

31:40

to a budgeting process where any of

31:42

this is actually taken seriously. I

31:44

think there's three broad ways that we

31:46

could get back to that, but

31:49

I agree. Maybe we don't. One is

31:51

higher interest rates could really start

31:53

to put pressure on politicians to take

31:55

the debt more seriously. Even with

31:57

the interest rate increases we've seen over

31:59

the last couple of years, we're

32:01

nowhere near the mortgage rates we had

32:03

30 years ago, 40 years ago.

32:05

So higher interest rates, I think, would

32:07

get people's attention. A second is

32:10

there's what is really a political forcing

32:12

event, which is the Social Security

32:14

and Medicare trust funds get exhausted. And

32:16

there's no real economics there. The

32:18

government could just pass a law saying

32:20

ignore the trust fund. But it

32:22

has a sort of... significance.

32:24

And that's a good thing. And we

32:26

should want to hold on to

32:29

that. So that could force action. The

32:31

third thing is just for whatever

32:33

reason, voters could start to care more

32:35

about it. In 1992, Ross Perot

32:37

centered his third party presidential bid around

32:39

debt and deficit in the last

32:42

cycle. And being anti -NAFTA. And being

32:44

anti -NASTA. In the last cycle, RFK

32:46

Jr. centered around all sorts of things,

32:48

but I don't remember the deficit

32:50

being on his list. Yeah. Do you

32:52

think, I mean, is, you know,

32:54

maybe this is one of the limits

32:57

of economics, but where does that,

32:59

you know, okay, Ross Perot is kind

33:01

of an alien who has, you

33:03

know, dropped onto the planet and starts

33:05

talking about deficit. But

33:07

other people talked about that. I

33:10

mean, it was rhetorically, but where, when...

33:13

do voters get motivated to care

33:15

about this rather than that?

33:17

Because the past couple of years,

33:19

we've spent a lot of

33:21

time talking about stuff that seems

33:23

pretty marginal to anybody's real

33:25

life, but it happens. I'm

33:27

never sure how much of

33:29

these issues are it's already out

33:31

there in the electorate and a

33:34

skilled politician discovers it versus a

33:36

skilled politician. helps change people's

33:38

mind and convince them that something

33:40

is an issue. So I don't

33:42

know which way the causation went.

33:44

Did the people cause Ross Perot

33:46

or did Ross Perot cause the

33:49

people? Either way, Ross Perot

33:51

did cause Bill Clinton to take

33:53

deficit reduction and campaign on it

33:55

more seriously and resulted in him

33:57

doing more deficit reduction than he

33:59

probably otherwise would have done. And

34:02

obviously, it's also he elected or

34:04

he had two years. where he

34:06

pretty much got to do what

34:08

he wanted, what his priorities were.

34:10

Republicans were elected to majorities in

34:13

the House and the Senate for

34:15

the first time in decades. And

34:18

that, you know, by the end of

34:20

the 90s, things had seemed to work out

34:22

pretty well in terms of things like budget

34:24

deficit. And the end of the Cold War,

34:26

so you could reduce defense spending and whatnot.

34:29

What is, I mean, can you explain

34:31

what's going on with the federal

34:33

budget when we talk about things like

34:35

in 2019? These are

34:38

nominal dollars. We spent

34:40

$4 .4 trillion. 2020,

34:43

COVID happens. It's $6 .7

34:45

trillion. It

34:47

reduced in 2023

34:49

to $6 .1

34:51

trillion. We're currently on

34:53

track to spend $7 .2

34:56

trillion. We're years past COVID. What

34:59

are we spending so much

35:01

more on? Well, you clearly... large

35:04

numbers more than I do because I just

35:06

divide everything by GDP and do it all as

35:08

a share of GDP. Spending

35:10

has increased some as a share of

35:12

GDP. One of the biggest things that

35:14

increased as a share of GDP is

35:16

interest on the debt. And that, by

35:18

the way, is, you know, in some

35:21

sense, it's technically spending, but it's the

35:23

consequence of taxes being lower than spending.

35:25

So tax cuts increase interest and spending

35:27

increases increase interest. If you

35:29

look at the non -interest spending, entitlement

35:31

growth is the things that have

35:34

been growing, Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid.

35:36

With Medicare, the growth has actually

35:38

been much slower than people were counting

35:40

on and hasn't been that rapid. But

35:43

Medicaid is covering a lot more people than

35:45

it was a few years ago. I probably actually

35:47

think that's a good thing. As

35:49

one of the architects of Obamacare,

35:51

you would like that because Medicaid is

35:53

one of the primary ways that

35:55

more people got covered. Exactly. Then

35:58

the goal there was to expand marketplaces,

36:00

but it ended up the marketplaces went

36:02

up a little bit and Medicaid went

36:04

up quite a lot. And is that

36:06

the perfect health system to have in

36:08

our country? Probably not. Do

36:10

I think this is a different

36:12

category of service? Yeah. I

36:14

mean, unless you as a society

36:16

are willing to let the

36:18

person lie outside the hospital. you

36:20

know, dying of whatever it

36:23

is and not treat them. We

36:25

want to have some explicit

36:27

form of care rather than rely

36:29

on a patchwork of, you

36:31

know, bad debt that hospitals are

36:33

forgiving. How do, you know,

36:35

how do we get any kind

36:37

of handle on things like

36:40

Social Security? And Medicare will at

36:42

various points, you know, start

36:44

to grow as well. you

36:46

know, faster than it has

36:48

been. You know, what is the

36:50

preferred, your preferred solution to

36:52

deal with entitlement problems? So if

36:54

I had to write it

36:56

on a specific social security plan,

36:58

I would, for example, extend

37:02

the payroll tax to cover health insurance. That

37:04

would bring in a lot of additional revenue. It

37:06

would do it in a reasonably efficient and

37:08

non manner. By that, you mean just - The

37:10

employer contribution to health insurance. You would lose the

37:13

exclusion for it. So you'd get more revenue

37:15

in. Right. And so it would be, I mean,

37:17

John McCain actually talked about this in 2008.

37:19

He talked about it for income taxes. So I

37:21

just said it for payroll taxes on Social

37:23

Security, but same type of idea. I had written

37:25

about it at the time. I think that's

37:27

a good idea. You have to worry about, does

37:29

it undermine the - system, but as long as

37:32

you have other systems, I don't worry about

37:34

that as much. I would then

37:36

take steps that would cut

37:38

Social Security benefits from their current

37:40

growth path for, say, the

37:42

top one -third of beneficiaries. Doing

37:44

more of that with the retirement

37:46

age, both delaying when you can start

37:48

getting benefits, which has been at

37:50

62 for a very long time. and

37:53

the normal benefit age. And then there's a

37:55

bunch of other changes you could make. And

37:57

I would even strengthen what they do to

37:59

reduce poverty. But these are all sort of

38:01

different tweaks. So you're

38:03

not in for a radical

38:05

rethinking of, say, of

38:07

Social Security, which is kind

38:09

of a bad deal

38:11

for most people. I mean,

38:14

for lower income people, it's

38:16

a good deal. But for

38:18

other people, it's taken out

38:20

in taxes. And then

38:22

you get a bad return on it. Most

38:26

of that bad return comes from

38:28

the fact that we already gave benefits

38:30

to a lot of people in

38:32

the past. And so if you switch

38:34

to a new system now, unless

38:36

you're willing to say for 25 years,

38:38

we're just going to not pay

38:40

any Social Security benefits, then you get

38:43

a good deal. If the new

38:45

people are putting money in private accounts,

38:47

plus they're paying. For the first

38:49

generation of retirees, once you take that

38:51

adjustment into account, you're not actually

38:53

getting much of a better deal out

38:55

of it. So largely, I would

38:57

tweak the existing structure. If accounts are

38:59

important to you, making them an

39:01

add -on account that... adds on to

39:03

the existing system. And if you do

39:06

that, you could do more benefit

39:08

cuts and maintain people's retirement security. That's

39:10

broadly what I would do. From

39:12

a process perspective, though, I really do

39:14

think this is a sort of

39:16

old saying that people say. It needs

39:18

to be bipartisan. If you look

39:20

at the options, the tax -only options

39:22

are really unappealing. The spending -only options

39:24

are really unappealing. Neither party is going

39:27

to want to do this on

39:29

their own. There are a set of,

39:31

by the way, gimmick

39:33

options. We'll transfer

39:35

general revenue. There's proposals to let

39:37

the government borrow money and

39:39

invest that money in stocks and

39:41

leverage it all up. So

39:43

there's a bunch of gimmicks. But

39:45

anything that's real requires pain.

39:48

Anything that requires pain, both parties

39:50

need to be involved with.

39:52

I want to talk about your

39:54

kind of evolution, if we

39:56

can use that term, on AI

39:58

in a second. But has

40:00

any Any of the

40:02

kind of developments since you

40:04

left the Obama administration,

40:06

has any of that shaken

40:08

your faith in a

40:11

kind of Keynesian economics? Maybe

40:13

not a pure Keynesian

40:15

economics, but the idea that

40:17

the government should be

40:19

managing overall supply or demand

40:21

in terms of as

40:23

a kind of counter -cyclical

40:25

intervention to what's going on

40:28

in the economy. So

40:30

as an economic matter, nothing

40:33

has shaken my faith in

40:35

a Keynesian approach. In fact, if

40:37

anything, I think we've seen

40:39

that it really can make quite

40:41

a big difference, both monetary

40:43

and fiscal policy. At the level

40:46

of politics and human decision

40:48

making, I'm now less enamored. by

40:50

the expertise and genius of

40:52

our Congress. And also the Fed,

40:54

I think, has done on

40:56

balance a good job. But there

40:58

have been times I think

41:00

it has gotten things quite wrong.

41:02

Does it generally get things

41:04

wrong by keeping interest rates low

41:07

or? Letting them go too

41:09

high. The error of recent years has been

41:11

keeping them, has been on interest rates

41:13

on the low side. When we're talking like

41:15

recent years, we're really talking, what, about

41:17

like 30 or 35 years? No, I mean,

41:19

we didn't have high inflation prior to

41:21

2020. So really since 2020 is where they

41:23

kept interest rates too low. So what

41:26

does this lead me to? So I think

41:28

monitoring fiscal policy really matter, just the

41:30

way John Maynard Keynes was sketching out. But

41:32

I think people often misapply them. So

41:34

that means I would like more rules. Automatic

41:37

fiscal rules. The unemployment rate goes up,

41:39

money goes out. The unemployment rate comes

41:41

down, money comes back. Same thing with

41:43

interest rates, basically a formula to set

41:45

interest rates. Now with interest rates, I

41:47

would not hand monetary policy over to

41:49

ChatGPT. I don't think it's quite good

41:51

enough to do it yet. But what

41:53

I would do is have the Fed

41:55

chair, every time they do something different

41:57

from what the formula said, get up

41:59

there and say, here's what the formula

42:01

said to do. Here is why I

42:03

went out and chose to do something

42:05

different than that formula. So you'd give

42:07

more, you'd make it more

42:10

of the default. So I have now

42:12

more sympathy for policy rules. And

42:14

is that coming kind of out of

42:16

a Friedmanist monitorist, or maybe not

42:18

monitorism per se, but the idea of

42:20

having predictable default rules then? And

42:22

if you deviate from them, you've got

42:24

to explain why. Yeah. And Milton

42:26

Friedman had one for the growth of

42:28

the money supply. That's not one

42:30

that I think really anyone supports anymore

42:32

because the relationship between the money

42:34

supply and both inflation and output really

42:36

broke down. But John

42:39

Taylor, who's in some ways an heir

42:41

to Milton Friedman, he came up with the

42:43

Taylor rule. And for a long time,

42:45

Republicans were like, hey, this is the thing

42:47

you should do. Democrats were saying, they're

42:49

so wise. Why would they want to listen

42:51

to this rule? It's much better to

42:53

listen to their wisdom. I now

42:55

have a little bit of

42:57

the conservative understanding and skepticism of

42:59

the wisdom even of the

43:01

very best experts. And that says

43:03

a dumb formula isn't perfect,

43:05

but it probably is at least

43:07

less biased and systematic errors

43:10

than you might get from people.

43:12

Why did you become an

43:14

economist? I really

43:16

liked... and a

43:18

logical way of thinking about the world.

43:20

But I really cared about all the

43:22

issues that we're talking about now. I

43:24

mean, I wrote an article in my

43:27

high school newspaper about the budget deficit.

43:29

And I haven't found a copy of

43:31

that. I'd love to find what I

43:33

wrote. Were you for it or against

43:35

it? Whatever it is, I've changed my

43:37

view since that article many times since

43:39

then. So I really like the set

43:41

of issues, but I liked being able

43:43

to think about them in a logical

43:46

and rigorous way. And economics let me

43:48

do that. Do you feel like economics?

43:50

as an academic discipline, is it becoming

43:52

more and more tainted by politics and

43:54

ideology, or is that just a wrong

43:56

way to think about things? If you

43:58

go to an economics there

44:01

is a huge premium on

44:03

coming up with novel and

44:05

counterintuitive ideas. Somebody comes

44:07

up with a conclusion that you

44:09

like, you don't want to... applaud

44:11

them. You want to point out

44:13

some really stupid mistake that they

44:15

made and have everyone think you're

44:17

smart. So I think the process

44:19

of refereeing, of debate, et cetera,

44:21

is healthier than it is in

44:23

most of the social sciences or

44:25

in all of the social sciences.

44:27

That being said, if you look

44:29

under the age of 50 in

44:31

the economics profession, most people are

44:33

on the left. They're not on

44:35

the right. And that does

44:37

affect the questions that people ask,

44:40

the moral approach that underpins their

44:42

work, and maybe the amount of

44:44

effort they put into trying to

44:46

find errors in things. So I

44:48

would love an intellectual ecosystem in

44:50

economics that was more ideologically balanced

44:52

than what we have now. I

44:55

don't think it's terrible. There's certainly

44:57

not discrimination. A lot of the

44:59

key institutions are run by people

45:01

that are older and that actually

45:03

are Republican. I

45:06

think we'll get better answers to

45:08

the questions we care about with

45:10

people coming at it from different

45:12

perspectives. And the main different perspective that

45:15

we're missing is one that's skeptical

45:17

of government, skeptical of the wisdom

45:19

of the people turning the knobs

45:21

and doors. Where does that kind

45:23

of change come from? There's groups like

45:25

Heterodox Academy, which is trying to

45:27

create ideological diversity among faculty. How

45:31

does that happen? Essentially

45:34

through hiring practices or?

45:37

Yeah, look, I mean, people talk about

45:39

disparate treatment where you have discrimination against

45:41

a group. You don't want to hire

45:43

a conservative. I think that might be

45:45

true in some departments. I don't think

45:47

it's true in economics. Then

45:50

there's disparate impact where you just end

45:52

up with different ratios. When

45:54

you have disparate impact, the first step is

45:56

to just be aware of it. And

45:58

then maybe at every stage might

46:00

find something. In history, for example, if

46:02

you went out and rather than

46:04

hiring someone to do sort of ethnic

46:06

studies, you hired someone to do

46:08

military history and you made your military

46:10

history search completely non -ideological, you're more

46:12

likely to pick up someone from

46:14

the conservative side advertising for that job

46:17

than a different type of job.

46:19

So it's the types of questions you

46:21

ask is part of it. You

46:23

know, in the economics of crime. How

46:25

much are you studying the problems

46:27

that police cause with the way they

46:29

police? How much are you studying

46:32

the problems that crime cause for the

46:34

people that are victims of crime?

46:36

So what research gets funded, for example?

46:38

It's much easier to get funded

46:40

studying problems that face girls than problems

46:42

that face boys. Richard Reeves has

46:44

done a great job of highlighting the

46:46

problems that face boys. Maybe

46:48

the funders will start to listen and

46:51

fund research on that problem. Let's

46:54

talk about AI because this is

46:56

a place where a few years ago

46:58

you wrote, I don't think AI

47:00

is going to be that big a

47:02

deal, that it's going to be

47:04

a kind of technological improvement that will

47:06

be kind of rolled out and

47:09

won't be that disruptive. Now

47:11

you seem to be much more

47:13

bullish on AI. Can you explain why?

47:15

Yeah. So first of all, I

47:17

still have the same view I had

47:19

before, which is our core problem

47:22

we have now is that we have

47:24

too little AI, not too much. Productivity

47:27

growth in some ways is a measure

47:29

of how many things people used to

47:31

do that machines can now do. And

47:33

it's not nearly high enough. I'd like

47:35

to see it much higher. So the

47:37

biggest problem we have is how to

47:39

have more AI. On the

47:41

disruptive side in terms of jobs,

47:43

I also continue to think that AI

47:45

is going to make new types

47:47

of jobs. that it's only going to

47:49

replace parts of some types of

47:51

jobs, that it's going to make us

47:53

richer, so we're going to want

47:55

to consume more services, and all of

47:57

that. So in broad

47:59

strokes, I still think the same

48:01

thing. I'm just much more optimistic,

48:03

and I'm much more optimistic because

48:05

they made breakthroughs at a pace

48:08

that a lot of the experts

48:10

in this area didn't think they

48:12

would. There's still a question of

48:14

how that gets adapted and used

48:16

in the workplace, how long that

48:18

process takes. So I've shifted towards

48:20

a more positive direction. Because there's

48:22

more of it and it seems

48:24

to be speeding up. Yeah. Now,

48:26

another piece, though, of AI that

48:29

I think has been really interesting to

48:31

me is how you think about

48:33

the digital giants and how concerned are

48:35

you about competition in the digital

48:37

space. I continue to be concerned. I

48:39

think antitrust enforcement is important because

48:41

I think competition is the source of

48:44

innovation. But what's really surprised me

48:46

is that the existing incumbents weren't the

48:48

ones that were able to dominate

48:50

in AI. Why does that surprise you,

48:52

though? Isn't that always the case,

48:54

that Microsoft comes along and knocks? knocks

48:57

off IBM even as they have

48:59

a kind of complementary relationship with

49:01

them and whatnot. Yeah, I agree.

49:03

It's happened over and over and

49:05

over again. So maybe this is

49:08

like the opposite of Lucy and

49:10

the football or something. But my

49:12

worry was that we were in

49:14

a place where AI depended so

49:16

much on data and so much

49:18

on scale and that nobody other

49:20

than Google and you

49:22

know, Facebook, Meta would have that

49:24

scale and those resources. And instead,

49:27

what we've seen is it turns

49:29

out that the algorithm matters a

49:31

lot too. And so open AI

49:33

and anthropic and perplexity, you know,

49:35

came to some degree from nowhere.

49:37

They got funding from some of

49:40

the big companies. DeepSeek came

49:42

from even less, probably more than

49:44

they claimed. Does that give you pause

49:46

about like, oh, you know, the

49:48

Chinese communists are going to somehow be

49:50

running everything? On

49:52

AI, I think there's some motivation

49:54

that comes from geopolitics, but boy,

49:57

is it hard to contain innovations

49:59

there. And on foundational models, it's

50:01

hard to be more than six

50:03

months ahead of the next person. And

50:06

so microchips is much

50:08

easier to maintain a

50:10

five, 10 -year lead

50:12

on than it is

50:15

on these algorithms. As

50:17

a final question, Talking

50:19

about AI and the fear

50:21

that we're going to wake

50:24

up tomorrow and whole industries

50:26

will be gone and there

50:28

won't be any jobs left

50:30

for certain types of people.

50:32

Your former boss, Barack Obama,

50:34

famously talked about how ATMs

50:36

had wiped out bank teller

50:38

jobs. This is a kind

50:40

of classic example of where

50:42

people think of technology as

50:44

something that robs people of

50:46

work. You

50:48

know, that certainly is not the case

50:51

even in the retail banking industry. Why

50:53

are we prone to that error

50:55

again and again, that a new

50:57

technology that actually makes things more

51:00

productive is going to put people

51:02

out of work? Be

51:04

clear. I think you got it right.

51:06

But what Obama said is people expected ATM

51:08

to take teller jobs. But instead, we

51:10

ended up with more bank branches because of

51:12

ATMs. And so you ended up with

51:14

more bank tellers, not Or people in the

51:17

banking industry. Yeah. So, you know.

51:19

We have hundreds of years of experience

51:21

with this. You know, no one could

51:23

have imagined what would happen in a

51:25

world where most people weren't working on

51:27

farms. What will they all do? What

51:29

else is there to do? Well, they'll

51:31

go to factories, but now they're not

51:33

in factories. Where have they gone? So

51:35

just our imagination isn't that great, but

51:37

it also doesn't need to be that

51:39

great because that's the beauty of the

51:42

market. Everyone's out there, the businesses, the

51:44

individuals trying to find new things, trying

51:46

to start a new business, trying to

51:48

figure out a new job. You

51:50

know, the central planners don't figure that

51:52

out. It's, you know, sort of a

51:54

Hayekian spontaneous order. And it's worked out

51:56

pretty well for a long time now.

51:59

So that would be my best guess.

52:01

So it will. But then, you know,

52:03

is there a stronger argument to say

52:05

to people that like, hey, you know,

52:07

in the past it all worked out? Or,

52:11

you know, trust the

52:13

Hayekian extended order and decentralization?

52:15

Well, look, you

52:18

know, there's also disruption. I mean,

52:20

the Luddites weren't wrong. These

52:22

machines were bad for the Luddites.

52:24

They were good for society as a

52:26

whole, but not for them. And

52:28

so part of why people are nervous

52:30

is because they don't understand what's

52:32

going to happen. And if only somebody

52:34

could explain it to them, they'd

52:36

be thrilled. Part of why they're nervous

52:38

is because they do understand. And

52:40

they understand that it won't be good

52:42

for them. And it's hard

52:44

to make the longer term

52:46

positive sum case. for the world.

52:49

But if you constantly make

52:51

whatever decision is loss minimizing over

52:53

the next minute, but has,

52:55

you know, costs that grow over

52:57

time, you know, you'll end

52:59

up more like Argentina over time

53:01

and less like the United

53:04

States. Okay. Well, without getting into

53:06

a discussion of Javier Millet,

53:08

who's remaking Argentina, we're going to

53:10

leave it there. Jason Furman,

53:12

thanks for talking to Riva. It's

53:14

been great talking to you.

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features