Episode Transcript
Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.
Use Ctrl + F to search
0:00
This is The Reason Interview
0:02
with Nick Gillespie. My guest
0:04
today is Harvard economist Jason
0:06
Furman, who is one of
0:08
Barack Obama's chief economic advisors
0:10
and an architect of the
0:12
Affordable Care Act. These days,
0:14
he's in the news for
0:17
his withering critique of Joe
0:19
Biden's dismal economic record and
0:21
his two -fisted attacks on Donald
0:23
Trump's trade policy. We talk
0:25
about Furman's defense of global
0:27
markets, Obamacare's unfulfilled promises, and
0:30
why he now thinks the national
0:32
debt and ai are bigger deals
0:34
than he used to believe here
0:36
is the reason interview with jason
0:38
firman uh
0:42
jason firman thanks for talking to reason
0:44
really excited to do so love love
0:46
reading you So
0:48
you recently wrote a piece
0:50
talking about the failure of
0:52
Bidenomics and what you called
0:54
the post -neoliberal delusion. Let's
0:57
start with that. You know, Irving Kristol
0:59
famously said that a neoconservative is a
1:01
liberal who got mugged by reality. What
1:04
is a neoliberal, the way that you're defining
1:06
that term? Sometimes I think a
1:08
neoliberal is like whatever I happen
1:10
to think that somebody else disagrees with
1:12
and they bundle it all together. It's
1:15
often defined more in the negative
1:17
as an epithet. If I had to
1:19
do it in the positive, it
1:21
is one, understands gains from trade,
1:24
that when you have markets, when
1:26
you have exchange, you can end
1:28
up with more for everyone. Number
1:31
two, respects.
1:33
a corollary that follows from that, that
1:35
decentralized decisions can result in the
1:37
best outcome. Now, you may want regulation
1:39
or taxes to move them in
1:41
a certain direction, and I might want
1:43
more of those than you would
1:45
want. I suspect that's true. Number
1:48
three, that scarcity
1:50
is at the heart of
1:52
all interesting public policy problems,
1:54
and so you have to
1:57
respect trade -offs. budget constraints.
1:59
At a macro level, that means
2:01
you have to worry about the
2:03
budget deficit. At a micro level,
2:05
that means you have to do
2:07
cost benefit analysis. And finally, something
2:09
that follows from all of that,
2:11
that you don't have an automatic,
2:13
easy answer to any question. You
2:15
really have to sort of work
2:17
through it, do the analysis, and
2:19
figure it out. So there's some
2:21
technocratic mindset associated with it as
2:23
well. You said that neoliberal is
2:25
often invoked as a kind of
2:27
term of derision or dismissal. And
2:29
I think I'm right about this, correct me
2:32
if I'm wrong, that it started being
2:34
used in that way around the end
2:36
of the 90s, you know, after NAFTA
2:38
had been passed, started by, I guess,
2:40
Reagan, Bush, then, you
2:42
know, ultimately done by Clinton. And
2:44
then at the end of the
2:47
90s, the beginning of the World
2:49
Trade Organization. And this is when...
2:51
people who were interested in kind
2:53
of increasing global trade and lowering
2:55
tax or tariff barriers and things
2:57
like that started to be called
2:59
pejoratively neoliberals. Does that track? That
3:02
tracks, but it really exploded about
3:04
a decade ago because there wasn't,
3:06
at least on the democratic side,
3:09
a very well articulated alternative
3:11
to it. And in some ways
3:13
there isn't, but there are a
3:15
set of them. Modern monetary theory
3:17
with deficits don't matter. A neo
3:19
-Brandeisian approach to antitrust that says
3:21
big companies are presumptively bad. Right,
3:23
just bigness is a curse. And
3:26
the fact that they're big means
3:28
we should be thinking bad. Breaking
3:30
them up. Yep. During
3:32
the inflation debates, the focus on
3:34
greed as a cause of inflation
3:37
and stopping greed as a solution
3:39
to inflation. And then people writing
3:41
about industrial policy. So
3:43
these are some different
3:45
strands. But they all
3:47
combine together in a
3:49
rejection of a lot
3:52
of those ideas of
3:54
gains from trade, decentralization.
3:58
and the importance of taking trade off seriously.
4:00
So this is, I mean, you were in
4:02
the Obama administration. I mean,
4:04
this is a pretty lonely place
4:06
you're occupying as somebody who identifies with
4:08
the Democratic Party, right? It's
4:11
not totally lonely. I mean, President
4:13
Obama put a lot of effort into
4:15
negotiating the Trans -Pacific Partnership, a free
4:17
trade agreement with our friends in
4:19
the Pacific. He had a proposal that
4:21
I spent a lot of time
4:23
on, on corporate tax reform that would
4:25
have lowered the corporate tax rate.
4:27
He proposed 28%. At the time, it
4:29
was 35%. And he was, I think,
4:32
pretty sympathetic to the markets. But
4:34
Obama left office a decade ago. Sorry.
4:36
At this point, it's
4:38
mixed. You know, it's
4:40
not like people don't listen to economists.
4:43
There's economists in government. There's economists
4:45
in Fed. There's a lot of economists
4:47
around. In the Biden administration, I
4:49
would say the policy took a turn
4:51
against this. And the rhetoric took
4:53
a massive pivot against this. In
4:55
some ways, the language turned even more
4:58
than the policy did. I mean,
5:00
you know, you would have been
5:02
working with Joe Biden, you know,
5:04
in the Obama White House. I
5:06
mean, did you see it coming
5:08
that? his presidency was going to
5:10
be as, you know, as tilted
5:13
towards kind of progressive concerns as
5:15
opposed to kind of, you know,
5:18
market -friendly liberal concerns?
5:20
Or did that kind of
5:22
blindside you? It mostly blindsided
5:24
me compared to Obama. Obama's
5:27
quite cerebral, comes at things from
5:29
the perspective of ideas and policy,
5:31
may end up with a big
5:33
dose of politics. He wouldn't have
5:35
gotten where he was without that.
5:37
Biden pretty much starts and ends
5:39
with politics. He
5:43
has certain things he likes. He
5:45
definitely likes labor unions quite a
5:47
lot. So that part of it
5:49
was not a surprise. But the
5:51
degree to which he adopted something
5:53
that was much more towards the
5:55
left within the Democratic Party, yeah,
5:57
that did surprise me after he
6:00
ran in the primaries as the
6:02
centrist. Why do you think
6:04
the neoliberal consensus, and again,
6:06
your article is called The
6:08
Post -Neoliberal Delusion, why did
6:10
that neoliberal coalition
6:12
within the Democratic Party breakdown?
6:16
I don't know. There's one argument
6:19
that it is China entered
6:21
the WTO, lots of suffering resulted,
6:23
and there was a populist
6:25
revolt in the form of Donald
6:27
Trump, and you needed to
6:30
listen to that and learn. I'm
6:32
much less sure that that's the
6:34
case. If you look at inequality
6:36
in the 20 years after China
6:38
entered the WTO, it actually went
6:40
up much less than it did
6:42
in the 20 years before China
6:44
And most economists at this point,
6:46
to the extent they talk about
6:48
a China shock, it had kind
6:50
of been absorbed by around 2010
6:53
anyway. Yes, you can debate the
6:55
original China shop because there were
6:57
definitely negative sides. There were also
6:59
a bunch of positive sides. I
7:01
think the positives that weighed, the
7:03
negatives. Regardless, everyone agreed it was
7:05
basically over. I think it's also
7:07
possible, and this is real speculation
7:09
on my part, that there are
7:11
ways in which the Democratic Party
7:13
got culturally out of touch with
7:15
Americans, that that led to some
7:17
backlash. And that was then misinterpreted
7:19
and used as an argument for
7:21
changing. on economic policy. What do
7:23
you think the role of somebody
7:25
like Bernie Sanders is in this,
7:27
whether it's a rhetorical or a
7:29
policy shift? He obviously, you know,
7:31
the fact that Hillary Clinton won,
7:33
or rather Hillary Clinton lost in
7:35
what should have been an easy
7:37
win. I mean, I think that's
7:39
a legitimate statement, but Sanders, clearly
7:41
his insurgency in 2016 hurt her
7:43
on some level. And is
7:45
it then that, like, if Hillary may
7:47
or may not have been a neoliberal
7:49
the way you're talking about it, but
7:51
Sanders definitely was not. He was anti -WTO.
7:53
He was anti -trade, very pro -union protectionist.
7:55
Is that where some of the energy
7:57
for rejection of neoliberalism in the Democratic
7:59
Party comes from? Look, I'm not a...
8:01
expert. I'm a hobbyist. I pay a
8:03
bit of attention. I have much more
8:05
conviction around what I think is good
8:07
for the world and bad for the
8:09
world. And by the way, if you're
8:11
governing and you do things that are
8:13
good for the world, I think you
8:15
get rewarded. Do things that are bad
8:17
for the world, you get punished. And
8:19
we just saw that in the last
8:21
election. But I
8:24
don't know. Americans
8:26
are a strange mixture of
8:29
contradictory views. I myself have
8:31
a set of contradictory views.
8:34
You can tap into a sort
8:36
of fear and loathing of billionaires.
8:38
And every billionaire is a policy
8:41
failure. But people can also laud
8:43
and be thrilled about the things
8:45
that billionaires invented and did and
8:47
changed their lives and understand that
8:49
and both of those together at
8:52
once. Yeah, on that point, Forbes,
8:54
I guess, came out with its newest
8:56
billionaires list. And Jerry Seinfeld is a
8:58
billionaire now. And it's like, I don't
9:00
think people think about Jerry. Seinfeld
9:02
and Elon Musk in the same category.
9:05
But who has Jerry Seinfeld killed, right?
9:07
Who has he hurt? Yeah. I mean,
9:09
Robert Nozick in his book had an
9:11
example of Wilt Chamberlain. I do that
9:13
in my class. I'm not sure they've
9:15
all heard of Wilt Chamberlain. So I
9:17
put Taylor. Wilt Chamberlain post -MeToo, I
9:19
don't know. I put Taylor Swift up
9:21
on the screen. And, you know, did
9:24
she make you better? I do
9:26
say that I'm not endorsing
9:28
her music. But,
9:30
you know, did she make people
9:32
worse off by being a billionaire
9:34
or did she make people better
9:36
off and in the course of
9:39
that became a billionaire? Ken, you
9:41
know, as you noted, I mean,
9:43
there's a shift on the right
9:45
also. You know, Trump is post
9:47
-neoliberal. He does not like global
9:49
trade. He does not like. you
9:52
know, kind of market forces. To
9:54
some degree, he's more pro -business, I
9:56
think, in a real way than
9:58
Hillary Clinton, Biden, or Kamala Harris
10:00
might have been. But he's antagonistic
10:02
towards the liberal project, if we're
10:05
talking about things like global trade
10:07
and decentralized, you know, open borders,
10:09
open services, and things like that.
10:12
Why, from an economic point of view,
10:14
we're not talking politics here, You
10:17
know, the period of, you know, in
10:19
the post -war generally, but then since
10:21
the collapse of the Soviet Union
10:23
and since, you know, the WTO was
10:25
created at the beginning of this
10:27
century, things have gotten better for the
10:29
vast majority of people in America,
10:31
you know, on a material basis. Why
10:33
then are people, why do
10:36
they not see that and why
10:38
are they captivated by things
10:40
like, you know, stronger tariff policies
10:42
and more protectionism? Yeah. So
10:44
first of all, on the premise
10:46
of your question, I agree. President
10:49
Trump, in some ways, is
10:51
an even bigger rejection of anything
10:53
resembling economic analysis, thinking about
10:55
trade -offs, thinking about gains from
10:57
trade and the like. And for
11:00
the most part, has eschewed
11:02
any intellectual rationalization of it. There's
11:04
some people out there like
11:06
Orrin Cass that provide some. intellectual
11:09
foundations for it or attempt to
11:11
provide some intellectual foundations for it. But
11:13
for the most part, that's actually
11:15
not what Donald Trump is interested in.
11:17
They make a lot of noise.
11:19
On the pro -business, in the wake
11:21
of the tariff announcements, I thought it
11:23
was striking how many people from
11:26
the administration, including the Treasury Secretary, went
11:28
out to talk down big business
11:30
as a globalist project, as something for
11:32
the elite. We don't care about
11:34
the stock market. We don't care about
11:36
the businesses. pretty
11:38
pivoting pretty quickly away
11:40
from business. So what's
11:43
the commonality here? There's
11:46
always the sense that things used
11:48
to be better. And that if
11:50
we could just get back to
11:52
the golden age that was, that's
11:54
been a powerful thing throughout humanity.
11:56
That siren. Song has been more
11:58
powerful in the wake of financial
12:00
crises. It's something you see. That's
12:02
where populists often arise. And when
12:04
Trump first rose, we weren't that
12:06
far past a financial crisis. We've
12:08
just had another type of enormous
12:10
amount of dislocation in our country,
12:12
both from COVID and through a
12:14
set of extremely rapid cultural changes.
12:17
And so I tend to blame
12:19
that. rather than looking at the
12:21
statistics on median family income, which
12:23
has grown quite strongly, or even
12:25
wage inequality, which has actually fallen.
12:27
Yeah, and I mean this, it
12:29
grew under Trump, you know, and
12:31
then there's the COVID moment. And
12:33
then after that, under Biden, real
12:35
median household income, individual income all went
12:38
up, which is a good sign. It's
12:40
a sign that the economy is kind
12:42
of delivering. but people
12:44
aren't interested in that. When
12:46
you said there have been radical
12:48
or rapid social transformations, what
12:50
do you mean? I just meant
12:52
the Black Lives Matter movement,
12:54
how rapidly things change related to
12:56
trans and the like. There
12:59
was a sense that a lot
13:01
of people in the country
13:03
were being caught in a very
13:05
big and very rapid set
13:07
of changes. When
13:10
you're talking about the failure of
13:12
Bidenomics, Biden spent a lot of
13:14
money on a couple of big
13:16
projects or big spending bills. Can
13:18
you talk about them and how
13:20
they failed to deliver what he
13:23
and his supporters claimed that they
13:25
were going to do? Yeah, let's
13:27
just tick through five quickly. There's
13:29
the American Rescue Plan, $1 .9
13:31
trillion. And the main
13:33
thing we got from that
13:35
was inflation. It's possible there was
13:38
a slightly faster recovery, but
13:40
the U .S. recovery wasn't actually
13:42
much faster than any other place,
13:44
at least in 2021 and
13:46
into 2022. Second, student
13:48
loan relief. This to me
13:50
in many ways was the most
13:53
egregious. This was done in August
13:55
2022. Inflation was raging.
13:57
The deficit was high. Interest
13:59
rates were high. And another
14:01
$500 billion was poured on
14:03
top of that without Congress. authorizing
14:06
that money in a way that
14:08
I think is quite abusive of
14:10
presidential authority. Third,
14:12
infrastructure. Here I
14:15
have a mixed view. I think
14:17
it's a noble goal. I think
14:19
it is a worthwhile goal. But
14:21
it was accompanied with so many
14:23
new rules and restraints on how
14:25
the money would go out. Moreover,
14:27
so much money was spent so
14:29
quickly in an economy that was
14:31
already overstretched that it ended up
14:33
driving prices up. rather than getting
14:35
more infrastructure. That's where I think
14:37
things like the abundance agenda are
14:39
quite important that are about building
14:41
more stuff. Fourth is
14:43
climate. Here, I like a
14:45
lot of it. I would love a
14:47
carbon tax. To me, that's the
14:49
simple solution. I think libertarians should love
14:51
that solution too. Well, I think
14:54
in principle they do. And then like
14:56
when you start. looking at the
14:58
politics against dice here, but in any
15:00
case. So that's what I'd love.
15:02
You can't pass one. That's not Biden's
15:04
fault. There was a combination of
15:06
subsidizing the use of wind and electricity.
15:08
I think that's okay. Those use
15:10
less carbon. But there was also a
15:12
lot of remaking American industry. So
15:14
we would make solar panels in the
15:16
United States. That's where I... get
15:18
off the train. I'd rather just buy
15:21
the cheapest ones from around the
15:23
world. And finally, there's the chips program
15:25
where from an economic perspective, I
15:27
think we're going to get worse microchips
15:29
and not create great jobs. National
15:31
security and resilience, I think it will
15:33
be a plus. And that plus
15:35
outweighs for me the economic minus. I'm
15:37
willing to pay a cost in
15:39
terms of efficiency to have microchips made
15:41
here, advanced ones, instead of all
15:43
in Taiwan. They're more
15:45
expensive and they're less good. But they're ours.
15:48
That's not my goal. Yeah, but I would
15:50
say that about very few things. And
15:52
that's where, again, the cost benefit comes
15:54
into play. If you tell me that
15:56
you think your microchip plan is going
15:58
to create more jobs and better jobs
16:00
and increase economic growth, I'm not going
16:02
to believe you. If you come and
16:04
tell me, you know what? It's going
16:06
to cost some money. It's going to
16:08
be a little bit inefficient. but
16:10
here's what the national security benefit is,
16:13
then we can go back and forth.
16:15
How big is the economic cost? How
16:17
big is the national security benefit? Is
16:19
it worth it? Is it not? Some
16:21
of these programs, and there were some
16:23
of them under Trump and under Biden
16:25
when we're talking about COVID. Can you
16:27
explain from an economic point of view?
16:30
I am merely, I'm a simple
16:32
English major and a psychology
16:34
major. Why is it
16:36
bad when to... Tell people
16:38
at a time like COVID,
16:41
we're going to double or
16:43
triple your unemployment benefits and
16:45
extend them for long periods
16:47
of time. Why does that
16:49
end up having a bad effect on
16:51
the economy? Right. Well, if your goal
16:53
is to get people not to work,
16:55
and that might have been a goal
16:57
in March and April of 2020, that's
17:00
a perfectly fine way to do
17:02
it. The policy lasted
17:04
through September 2021. At
17:06
that point, there were record
17:08
job openings. People were
17:10
either vaccinated. or had caught
17:12
COVID and were less susceptible to
17:14
it again. And by that point,
17:16
it really started to interfere with
17:19
people getting back into work. I
17:21
mean, why would you possibly want
17:23
to work when you could get
17:25
more money not working? I think
17:27
that almost every day until my
17:29
retirement, I'm sure. And then the
17:31
second issue in the whole response
17:34
is if you give people more
17:36
money, let's say we as a
17:38
country were producing and buying and
17:40
selling $1 ,000 a year. 1 ,000
17:42
units of whatever. You give people
17:44
enough money to buy 1 ,100. At
17:47
the same time that something's happened
17:49
to the economy, so it can only
17:51
make 900, the result is you're
17:53
not going to get more stuff. You're
17:55
just going to get higher prices
17:57
for the existing amount of stuff. is
17:59
more dollars chasing the same number
18:01
of goods. This is textbook inflation. Yeah,
18:03
exactly. So it made sense to
18:05
protect people. you
18:08
don't want your living standards to go
18:10
way, way down because of COVID. But
18:12
what we ended up doing was not
18:14
doing the math and figuring out what
18:16
you needed to do to protect people,
18:18
not doing the targeting to get to
18:20
the people who needed it. And so
18:22
the result was just much, much, much
18:24
more money than we could possibly make
18:26
in terms of stuff. And so it
18:28
drove up the price of that stuff.
18:30
Where does it come from? I mean,
18:32
has it always been this way that
18:35
You know, what you're saying is
18:37
obvious, but then it became
18:39
politically inexpedient to admit that, particularly
18:41
when Biden was in office
18:43
and this was happening or when
18:45
he was starting to run
18:47
for president and then Harris. I
18:50
mean, is it just simply
18:52
political posturing that Democrats are
18:54
not going to admit the
18:56
policies that their guys pursued,
18:58
you know, caused inflation? just
19:01
in the same way that Republicans
19:03
won't admit it when it's their
19:06
guy in the dock. I think
19:08
there's a real problem with the
19:10
way information is aggregated and transmitted.
19:12
There were some people I know
19:14
who, when that first stimulus bill
19:16
were passed, who were emailing
19:18
me, hey, this is really too large,
19:21
but I don't want to undermine Biden
19:23
by saying that. Or,
19:25
you know, this is too large, but
19:27
I'm afraid people are in the student
19:29
loan case. This is a bad policy,
19:31
but I don't want to get destroyed
19:34
the way, Jason, I saw you get
19:36
destroyed on Twitter. Some people,
19:38
though, don't even quite see that. So
19:40
I've had people reach out to me
19:42
who have said, hey, you know, aren't
19:44
the Trump tax cuts going to cause
19:46
inflation, Jason? You should write about that.
19:48
And I'm like, wait, weren't you the
19:50
same person that a couple of years
19:52
ago told me the Biden fiscal expansion?
19:55
wasn't causing inflation? Like, why does the
19:57
fiscal impact on inflation depend on the
19:59
political party of the person? And it's
20:01
hard to think outside your own bubble
20:03
and your own ecosystem. And all of
20:05
this creates a sort of false sense
20:07
of what it is people actually think
20:09
when a lot of people aren't saying
20:11
what they think. And some of those
20:14
people are tenured professors who aren't going
20:16
to be, you know, in no risk
20:18
of being fired. I
20:20
guess in a similar
20:24
You know, we're hearing this now
20:26
because Trump has, you know, Trump
20:28
has levied tariffs. I mean, depending
20:30
on what day of the week
20:32
and when this airs, who knows
20:34
what the case will be. But,
20:36
you know, currently he's suspended his
20:38
tariffs or put them on ice
20:40
for 90 days except for China, etc.
20:43
But you hear a lot of
20:45
Republicans now saying, well, you know, tariffs
20:47
aren't taxes. and tariffs
20:49
are paid for by the country
20:51
that is sending goods, not
20:54
the people who are importing them
20:56
here in America. You recently
20:58
wrote a piece in the New
21:00
York Times saying that Trump's
21:02
tariffs are based on an economic
21:04
theory that makes no sense. Can
21:07
you explain that? What is
21:09
wrong with the tariffs the
21:11
way that Trump is doing?
21:13
Yeah, basically every step of
21:15
Trump's mentality on trade is
21:17
wrong. First of all, imports
21:20
are good. They're a wonderful
21:22
thing. We like to import
21:24
coffee. We like to import
21:26
cars. We like to import
21:28
the inputs we need for
21:30
American manufacturing. Second of all,
21:32
trade deficits don't reflect other
21:34
countries' tariffs and trade policies.
21:36
There's countries with huge tariffs
21:38
that run large trade deficits.
21:40
There's countries with low tariffs
21:42
that run trade surpluses. Third,
21:44
our retaliation against them is
21:47
going to shrink imports. but
21:49
it's also going to shrink
21:51
exports. And that hurts consumers
21:53
on the import side. It
21:55
hurts American workers on the
21:57
export side. And so just
21:59
every step of his reasoning
22:01
and fixation on trade deficits
22:03
is just the wrong, wrong
22:05
way to think about trade.
22:07
Is there a consensus forming
22:09
that either that that's a
22:12
bad policy, a kind of
22:14
bipartisan or transpartisan? consensus
22:16
forming that, okay, these tariffs are not
22:18
working and we're getting strong signals from
22:20
global markets as well as, you know,
22:22
the things like the S &P 500
22:24
and the Dow Jones. But is,
22:26
you know, is there also a
22:28
kind of transpartisan, you know, coalition
22:30
sort of saying like, oh, maybe
22:32
we should be more protectionist? There's,
22:35
President Trump went so far that
22:37
I think he discredited it
22:39
for even many people on the
22:42
protectionist side. So people like
22:44
free trade more than they ever
22:46
did before right now, more
22:48
than they ever would after listening
22:50
to me extol the benefits
22:52
of free trade. So I don't
22:55
think he's building that much
22:57
of a coalition against it. But
22:59
he has shifted the Overton
23:01
window enormously. I mean, he did
23:03
this initial reciprocal tariff announcement
23:05
on Liberation Day. Then
23:07
he took away. You've lost.
23:10
You're using his language, right?
23:12
You call it the Gulf of
23:14
America as well. I don't care
23:16
much about words. Maybe that's a
23:18
mistake. Then he
23:21
took away some of them,
23:23
the so -called reciprocal part.
23:25
So that left the
23:27
United States with tariff rates
23:29
that are the rates
23:31
that prevail in Iran, Venezuela.
23:33
and a bunch of other countries
23:35
that aren't nearly as economically
23:37
successful as Iran and Venezuela. And
23:40
that's now become the reasonable,
23:43
moderate, decent position. And so the
23:45
Overton window has shifted quite
23:47
a lot, and I'm not sure
23:49
how we can shift it
23:51
back. A place
23:53
where your thinking has evolved
23:55
over the years has
23:57
to do with the role
23:59
of debt and deficits
24:01
in larger macroeconomic concerns. I
24:04
think it was in 2019,
24:06
you wrote a piece with
24:09
Larry Summers, another Harvard grad
24:11
and administration official back in
24:13
the Clinton years. where
24:15
you were kind of poo -pooing, you know,
24:18
debt, you know, it's not that big a
24:20
deal and it should never really get in
24:22
the way of doing what's right, you know,
24:24
in terms of helping the poor, you know,
24:26
et cetera. You have kind
24:28
of revised some of that. Can you talk
24:30
a little bit about where you are now
24:32
and how you got to that position? Yeah.
24:34
So to say I've evolved on the debt
24:37
is unfair. I've zigzagged on the debt. So
24:39
I was concerned about it
24:41
in the 90s. Then I
24:43
got increasingly less concerned about
24:46
it. Then I got more
24:48
concerned about it. I'd like
24:50
to think that I'm following
24:52
the data. And when interest
24:54
rates are low, we really
24:56
could afford more debt. When
24:58
interest rates are high, we
25:00
can't afford more debt. It's
25:02
possible my thinking has evolved
25:04
and changed even subject to
25:06
the data. But a world
25:08
with 70 % debt to
25:11
GDP and a 2 % interest
25:13
rate is just very, very
25:15
different from 100 % debt
25:17
to GDP. 4 .5 % interest
25:19
rate. Why does large and
25:21
persistent and growing national debt,
25:23
and whether we're using debt
25:25
held by the public or
25:27
gross debt, which includes intergovernmental
25:29
holdings, why when that grows
25:32
and particularly crosses the 90
25:34
% or 100 % of GDP
25:36
threshold, why is that a
25:38
problem? So I don't know that we
25:40
know what the threshold is. Argentina
25:42
had a massive financial crisis, including
25:44
a fiscal crisis when it
25:46
had debt of 45 % of
25:48
GDP. The UK during the,
25:50
I think it was the Napoleonic
25:52
Wars, got as high as 250%.
25:55
So it does depend on. why
25:57
you're borrowing, do people trust your
25:59
country, and the like. Right, and
26:01
it helps, I mean, the U .S.,
26:03
beyond everything else, because the dollar
26:05
is the global reserve currency, we're
26:07
working with different rules than, you
26:09
know, smaller countries.
26:11
Yeah, even than Germany or Canada. They
26:14
can borrow much less than we
26:16
can. I mean, the first thing I'd
26:18
say is, if you were czar,
26:20
or I was czar, or anyone was
26:22
czar, there is just no way
26:24
that your economic plan would be, we're
26:26
going to spend at the current
26:28
rate, tax at the current rate, and
26:30
then make some larger abrupt change
26:32
20 years in the future. You would
26:35
rather make a smaller change now
26:37
than a larger change in the future.
26:39
In economics, that's called tax smoothing.
26:41
The consequence of not doing that is
26:43
for sure we get less economic
26:45
growth. And we raise the chance of
26:47
a fiscal crisis. And I don't
26:49
know how high that chance is. But
26:51
look, right now, I pay homeowners
26:53
insurance against the risk that my house
26:55
will burn down. The fact that
26:58
my house didn't burn down last year,
27:00
the year before, the year before
27:02
that, doesn't mean I'm like a loser
27:04
and a sucker for having bought
27:06
this. I think of deficit reduction in
27:08
some ways just like that. Why
27:12
does large and growing debt
27:14
reduce economic growth? It means the
27:16
government is borrowing more money,
27:18
which drives up interest rates. Driving
27:20
up interest rates drives down
27:22
business investment, drives down home building.
27:24
The other way in which
27:26
it matters is you might get
27:28
out of that if you
27:31
borrow from abroad to support your
27:33
investment. Your
27:35
economic growth, you have to give
27:37
it to those foreign countries to repay
27:39
them for everything you borrowed. So
27:41
either way, you're either doing less investment
27:43
or you're having to repay foreigners
27:45
if you want to maintain your investment.
27:48
This was during the fiscal crisis
27:50
or the financial crisis or
27:52
shortly after it. Carmen
27:54
Reinhardt, Vincent Reinhardt, and Ken
27:56
Rogoff wrote a paper, one
27:58
version of which then they
28:00
corrected. It really
28:03
said, you know, as you approach
28:05
a 90 percent debt to
28:07
GDP ratio, that these episodes, they
28:09
looked at a series of
28:11
them over the past couple of
28:13
hundred years, you know,
28:15
that it tended to reduce long
28:18
term economic growth, you know, which
28:20
average for them, it was about
28:22
an average of 23 years of
28:24
periods they call debt overhang. And
28:26
it reduced. growth in general from
28:28
something like 3 % annually to 2
28:30
% annually or like 1%. point,
28:33
does that sound about right to
28:35
you? And does that help explain
28:37
the sluggish economic growth that we've
28:39
really been witnessing for a good
28:41
part of the 21st century? I'll
28:43
take your second question first. I
28:45
think the causation might go more
28:48
the other direction, that there was
28:50
a set of sluggishness either from
28:52
slower productivity growth, from demography or
28:54
whatever it was. And in order
28:56
to keep the economy going, We
28:58
needed the extra debt. And what's
29:00
the evidence for that? We didn't
29:02
until 2021 get a lot of
29:05
inflation. So through 2019, the problem
29:07
was low inflation, not high inflation.
29:09
That is generally indicative of demand
29:11
being too low. So I don't
29:13
think the debt was overheating our
29:15
economy. I think it was making
29:17
up for these problems. And that
29:20
was part of why Larry and
29:22
I thought we needed more debt.
29:24
We overshot what we might possibly
29:26
have imagined. In
29:28
terms of Ken Rogoff
29:30
and Carmen Reinhart's research, those
29:32
papers were suggestive. There
29:34
was a lot of correlation,
29:36
not causation. So directionally,
29:38
I think they're right. But
29:40
I'm not convinced about
29:43
some nonlinear threshold. In terms
29:45
of dealing with debt
29:47
and national debt and deficits,
29:49
I mean, you now
29:51
kind of propose We should
29:53
be trying to balance
29:55
the budget, which we've done
29:57
in our lifetime. Balance
30:00
the budget excluding interest payments.
30:02
Balance what's called the primary The
30:04
primary deficit. And also invoking
30:06
a kind of strict PAYGO policy
30:08
for when we spend more
30:10
or spend less. Can you describe
30:12
how PAYGO would work and
30:15
why that's important? I think PAYGO
30:17
is important for two reasons.
30:19
It says that anything you do
30:21
you have to pay for.
30:23
So you want to give money
30:25
for student loan debt relief. Great.
30:28
You can pass a law that
30:30
costs $500 billion. You then need to
30:32
raise taxes by $500 billion or
30:34
cut spending by $500 billion. That
30:37
has a macroeconomic rationale that when you're
30:39
in a hole, you don't want to
30:41
keep digging. And this stops you from
30:43
digging. I think perhaps even more important,
30:45
it lets you figure out whether the
30:47
things you're doing are a good idea
30:49
or not. Almost every idea
30:51
that involves giving money to
30:53
some group is a good idea
30:56
until you ask where the
30:58
money is coming from. If
31:00
you can say, here's where the
31:02
money is coming from, here's where the
31:04
money is going, and on net
31:06
this is still a good idea, it's
31:09
much more likely that this is
31:11
a choice that's worth society making. But
31:13
if you obfuscate that choice and
31:15
you give the benefit to the people
31:17
today for sure, and you... given
31:19
uncertain costs that might even be even
31:21
larger to people in the future,
31:23
then I don't trust that we did
31:25
the right social cost benefit to
31:28
decide whether or not that idea was
31:30
worth it. Do you think there's
31:32
any chance in hell that we're going
31:34
to get back to a budgeting
31:36
process? And this is politics, but it
31:38
stems from economics that we'll get
31:40
to a budgeting process where any of
31:42
this is actually taken seriously. I
31:44
think there's three broad ways that we
31:46
could get back to that, but
31:49
I agree. Maybe we don't. One is
31:51
higher interest rates could really start
31:53
to put pressure on politicians to take
31:55
the debt more seriously. Even with
31:57
the interest rate increases we've seen over
31:59
the last couple of years, we're
32:01
nowhere near the mortgage rates we had
32:03
30 years ago, 40 years ago.
32:05
So higher interest rates, I think, would
32:07
get people's attention. A second is
32:10
there's what is really a political forcing
32:12
event, which is the Social Security
32:14
and Medicare trust funds get exhausted. And
32:16
there's no real economics there. The
32:18
government could just pass a law saying
32:20
ignore the trust fund. But it
32:22
has a sort of... significance.
32:24
And that's a good thing. And we
32:26
should want to hold on to
32:29
that. So that could force action. The
32:31
third thing is just for whatever
32:33
reason, voters could start to care more
32:35
about it. In 1992, Ross Perot
32:37
centered his third party presidential bid around
32:39
debt and deficit in the last
32:42
cycle. And being anti -NAFTA. And being
32:44
anti -NASTA. In the last cycle, RFK
32:46
Jr. centered around all sorts of things,
32:48
but I don't remember the deficit
32:50
being on his list. Yeah. Do you
32:52
think, I mean, is, you know,
32:54
maybe this is one of the limits
32:57
of economics, but where does that,
32:59
you know, okay, Ross Perot is kind
33:01
of an alien who has, you
33:03
know, dropped onto the planet and starts
33:05
talking about deficit. But
33:07
other people talked about that. I
33:10
mean, it was rhetorically, but where, when...
33:13
do voters get motivated to care
33:15
about this rather than that?
33:17
Because the past couple of years,
33:19
we've spent a lot of
33:21
time talking about stuff that seems
33:23
pretty marginal to anybody's real
33:25
life, but it happens. I'm
33:27
never sure how much of
33:29
these issues are it's already out
33:31
there in the electorate and a
33:34
skilled politician discovers it versus a
33:36
skilled politician. helps change people's
33:38
mind and convince them that something
33:40
is an issue. So I don't
33:42
know which way the causation went.
33:44
Did the people cause Ross Perot
33:46
or did Ross Perot cause the
33:49
people? Either way, Ross Perot
33:51
did cause Bill Clinton to take
33:53
deficit reduction and campaign on it
33:55
more seriously and resulted in him
33:57
doing more deficit reduction than he
33:59
probably otherwise would have done. And
34:02
obviously, it's also he elected or
34:04
he had two years. where he
34:06
pretty much got to do what
34:08
he wanted, what his priorities were.
34:10
Republicans were elected to majorities in
34:13
the House and the Senate for
34:15
the first time in decades. And
34:18
that, you know, by the end of
34:20
the 90s, things had seemed to work out
34:22
pretty well in terms of things like budget
34:24
deficit. And the end of the Cold War,
34:26
so you could reduce defense spending and whatnot.
34:29
What is, I mean, can you explain
34:31
what's going on with the federal
34:33
budget when we talk about things like
34:35
in 2019? These are
34:38
nominal dollars. We spent
34:40
$4 .4 trillion. 2020,
34:43
COVID happens. It's $6 .7
34:45
trillion. It
34:47
reduced in 2023
34:49
to $6 .1
34:51
trillion. We're currently on
34:53
track to spend $7 .2
34:56
trillion. We're years past COVID. What
34:59
are we spending so much
35:01
more on? Well, you clearly... large
35:04
numbers more than I do because I just
35:06
divide everything by GDP and do it all as
35:08
a share of GDP. Spending
35:10
has increased some as a share of
35:12
GDP. One of the biggest things that
35:14
increased as a share of GDP is
35:16
interest on the debt. And that, by
35:18
the way, is, you know, in some
35:21
sense, it's technically spending, but it's the
35:23
consequence of taxes being lower than spending.
35:25
So tax cuts increase interest and spending
35:27
increases increase interest. If you
35:29
look at the non -interest spending, entitlement
35:31
growth is the things that have
35:34
been growing, Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid.
35:36
With Medicare, the growth has actually
35:38
been much slower than people were counting
35:40
on and hasn't been that rapid. But
35:43
Medicaid is covering a lot more people than
35:45
it was a few years ago. I probably actually
35:47
think that's a good thing. As
35:49
one of the architects of Obamacare,
35:51
you would like that because Medicaid is
35:53
one of the primary ways that
35:55
more people got covered. Exactly. Then
35:58
the goal there was to expand marketplaces,
36:00
but it ended up the marketplaces went
36:02
up a little bit and Medicaid went
36:04
up quite a lot. And is that
36:06
the perfect health system to have in
36:08
our country? Probably not. Do
36:10
I think this is a different
36:12
category of service? Yeah. I
36:14
mean, unless you as a society
36:16
are willing to let the
36:18
person lie outside the hospital. you
36:20
know, dying of whatever it
36:23
is and not treat them. We
36:25
want to have some explicit
36:27
form of care rather than rely
36:29
on a patchwork of, you
36:31
know, bad debt that hospitals are
36:33
forgiving. How do, you know,
36:35
how do we get any kind
36:37
of handle on things like
36:40
Social Security? And Medicare will at
36:42
various points, you know, start
36:44
to grow as well. you
36:46
know, faster than it has
36:48
been. You know, what is the
36:50
preferred, your preferred solution to
36:52
deal with entitlement problems? So if
36:54
I had to write it
36:56
on a specific social security plan,
36:58
I would, for example, extend
37:02
the payroll tax to cover health insurance. That
37:04
would bring in a lot of additional revenue. It
37:06
would do it in a reasonably efficient and
37:08
non manner. By that, you mean just - The
37:10
employer contribution to health insurance. You would lose the
37:13
exclusion for it. So you'd get more revenue
37:15
in. Right. And so it would be, I mean,
37:17
John McCain actually talked about this in 2008.
37:19
He talked about it for income taxes. So I
37:21
just said it for payroll taxes on Social
37:23
Security, but same type of idea. I had written
37:25
about it at the time. I think that's
37:27
a good idea. You have to worry about, does
37:29
it undermine the - system, but as long as
37:32
you have other systems, I don't worry about
37:34
that as much. I would then
37:36
take steps that would cut
37:38
Social Security benefits from their current
37:40
growth path for, say, the
37:42
top one -third of beneficiaries. Doing
37:44
more of that with the retirement
37:46
age, both delaying when you can start
37:48
getting benefits, which has been at
37:50
62 for a very long time. and
37:53
the normal benefit age. And then there's a
37:55
bunch of other changes you could make. And
37:57
I would even strengthen what they do to
37:59
reduce poverty. But these are all sort of
38:01
different tweaks. So you're
38:03
not in for a radical
38:05
rethinking of, say, of
38:07
Social Security, which is kind
38:09
of a bad deal
38:11
for most people. I mean,
38:14
for lower income people, it's
38:16
a good deal. But for
38:18
other people, it's taken out
38:20
in taxes. And then
38:22
you get a bad return on it. Most
38:26
of that bad return comes from
38:28
the fact that we already gave benefits
38:30
to a lot of people in
38:32
the past. And so if you switch
38:34
to a new system now, unless
38:36
you're willing to say for 25 years,
38:38
we're just going to not pay
38:40
any Social Security benefits, then you get
38:43
a good deal. If the new
38:45
people are putting money in private accounts,
38:47
plus they're paying. For the first
38:49
generation of retirees, once you take that
38:51
adjustment into account, you're not actually
38:53
getting much of a better deal out
38:55
of it. So largely, I would
38:57
tweak the existing structure. If accounts are
38:59
important to you, making them an
39:01
add -on account that... adds on to
39:03
the existing system. And if you do
39:06
that, you could do more benefit
39:08
cuts and maintain people's retirement security. That's
39:10
broadly what I would do. From
39:12
a process perspective, though, I really do
39:14
think this is a sort of
39:16
old saying that people say. It needs
39:18
to be bipartisan. If you look
39:20
at the options, the tax -only options
39:22
are really unappealing. The spending -only options
39:24
are really unappealing. Neither party is going
39:27
to want to do this on
39:29
their own. There are a set of,
39:31
by the way, gimmick
39:33
options. We'll transfer
39:35
general revenue. There's proposals to let
39:37
the government borrow money and
39:39
invest that money in stocks and
39:41
leverage it all up. So
39:43
there's a bunch of gimmicks. But
39:45
anything that's real requires pain.
39:48
Anything that requires pain, both parties
39:50
need to be involved with.
39:52
I want to talk about your
39:54
kind of evolution, if we
39:56
can use that term, on AI
39:58
in a second. But has
40:00
any Any of the
40:02
kind of developments since you
40:04
left the Obama administration,
40:06
has any of that shaken
40:08
your faith in a
40:11
kind of Keynesian economics? Maybe
40:13
not a pure Keynesian
40:15
economics, but the idea that
40:17
the government should be
40:19
managing overall supply or demand
40:21
in terms of as
40:23
a kind of counter -cyclical
40:25
intervention to what's going on
40:28
in the economy. So
40:30
as an economic matter, nothing
40:33
has shaken my faith in
40:35
a Keynesian approach. In fact, if
40:37
anything, I think we've seen
40:39
that it really can make quite
40:41
a big difference, both monetary
40:43
and fiscal policy. At the level
40:46
of politics and human decision
40:48
making, I'm now less enamored. by
40:50
the expertise and genius of
40:52
our Congress. And also the Fed,
40:54
I think, has done on
40:56
balance a good job. But there
40:58
have been times I think
41:00
it has gotten things quite wrong.
41:02
Does it generally get things
41:04
wrong by keeping interest rates low
41:07
or? Letting them go too
41:09
high. The error of recent years has been
41:11
keeping them, has been on interest rates
41:13
on the low side. When we're talking like
41:15
recent years, we're really talking, what, about
41:17
like 30 or 35 years? No, I mean,
41:19
we didn't have high inflation prior to
41:21
2020. So really since 2020 is where they
41:23
kept interest rates too low. So what
41:26
does this lead me to? So I think
41:28
monitoring fiscal policy really matter, just the
41:30
way John Maynard Keynes was sketching out. But
41:32
I think people often misapply them. So
41:34
that means I would like more rules. Automatic
41:37
fiscal rules. The unemployment rate goes up,
41:39
money goes out. The unemployment rate comes
41:41
down, money comes back. Same thing with
41:43
interest rates, basically a formula to set
41:45
interest rates. Now with interest rates, I
41:47
would not hand monetary policy over to
41:49
ChatGPT. I don't think it's quite good
41:51
enough to do it yet. But what
41:53
I would do is have the Fed
41:55
chair, every time they do something different
41:57
from what the formula said, get up
41:59
there and say, here's what the formula
42:01
said to do. Here is why I
42:03
went out and chose to do something
42:05
different than that formula. So you'd give
42:07
more, you'd make it more
42:10
of the default. So I have now
42:12
more sympathy for policy rules. And
42:14
is that coming kind of out of
42:16
a Friedmanist monitorist, or maybe not
42:18
monitorism per se, but the idea of
42:20
having predictable default rules then? And
42:22
if you deviate from them, you've got
42:24
to explain why. Yeah. And Milton
42:26
Friedman had one for the growth of
42:28
the money supply. That's not one
42:30
that I think really anyone supports anymore
42:32
because the relationship between the money
42:34
supply and both inflation and output really
42:36
broke down. But John
42:39
Taylor, who's in some ways an heir
42:41
to Milton Friedman, he came up with the
42:43
Taylor rule. And for a long time,
42:45
Republicans were like, hey, this is the thing
42:47
you should do. Democrats were saying, they're
42:49
so wise. Why would they want to listen
42:51
to this rule? It's much better to
42:53
listen to their wisdom. I now
42:55
have a little bit of
42:57
the conservative understanding and skepticism of
42:59
the wisdom even of the
43:01
very best experts. And that says
43:03
a dumb formula isn't perfect,
43:05
but it probably is at least
43:07
less biased and systematic errors
43:10
than you might get from people.
43:12
Why did you become an
43:14
economist? I really
43:16
liked... and a
43:18
logical way of thinking about the world.
43:20
But I really cared about all the
43:22
issues that we're talking about now. I
43:24
mean, I wrote an article in my
43:27
high school newspaper about the budget deficit.
43:29
And I haven't found a copy of
43:31
that. I'd love to find what I
43:33
wrote. Were you for it or against
43:35
it? Whatever it is, I've changed my
43:37
view since that article many times since
43:39
then. So I really like the set
43:41
of issues, but I liked being able
43:43
to think about them in a logical
43:46
and rigorous way. And economics let me
43:48
do that. Do you feel like economics?
43:50
as an academic discipline, is it becoming
43:52
more and more tainted by politics and
43:54
ideology, or is that just a wrong
43:56
way to think about things? If you
43:58
go to an economics there
44:01
is a huge premium on
44:03
coming up with novel and
44:05
counterintuitive ideas. Somebody comes
44:07
up with a conclusion that you
44:09
like, you don't want to... applaud
44:11
them. You want to point out
44:13
some really stupid mistake that they
44:15
made and have everyone think you're
44:17
smart. So I think the process
44:19
of refereeing, of debate, et cetera,
44:21
is healthier than it is in
44:23
most of the social sciences or
44:25
in all of the social sciences.
44:27
That being said, if you look
44:29
under the age of 50 in
44:31
the economics profession, most people are
44:33
on the left. They're not on
44:35
the right. And that does
44:37
affect the questions that people ask,
44:40
the moral approach that underpins their
44:42
work, and maybe the amount of
44:44
effort they put into trying to
44:46
find errors in things. So I
44:48
would love an intellectual ecosystem in
44:50
economics that was more ideologically balanced
44:52
than what we have now. I
44:55
don't think it's terrible. There's certainly
44:57
not discrimination. A lot of the
44:59
key institutions are run by people
45:01
that are older and that actually
45:03
are Republican. I
45:06
think we'll get better answers to
45:08
the questions we care about with
45:10
people coming at it from different
45:12
perspectives. And the main different perspective that
45:15
we're missing is one that's skeptical
45:17
of government, skeptical of the wisdom
45:19
of the people turning the knobs
45:21
and doors. Where does that kind
45:23
of change come from? There's groups like
45:25
Heterodox Academy, which is trying to
45:27
create ideological diversity among faculty. How
45:31
does that happen? Essentially
45:34
through hiring practices or?
45:37
Yeah, look, I mean, people talk about
45:39
disparate treatment where you have discrimination against
45:41
a group. You don't want to hire
45:43
a conservative. I think that might be
45:45
true in some departments. I don't think
45:47
it's true in economics. Then
45:50
there's disparate impact where you just end
45:52
up with different ratios. When
45:54
you have disparate impact, the first step is
45:56
to just be aware of it. And
45:58
then maybe at every stage might
46:00
find something. In history, for example, if
46:02
you went out and rather than
46:04
hiring someone to do sort of ethnic
46:06
studies, you hired someone to do
46:08
military history and you made your military
46:10
history search completely non -ideological, you're more
46:12
likely to pick up someone from
46:14
the conservative side advertising for that job
46:17
than a different type of job.
46:19
So it's the types of questions you
46:21
ask is part of it. You
46:23
know, in the economics of crime. How
46:25
much are you studying the problems
46:27
that police cause with the way they
46:29
police? How much are you studying
46:32
the problems that crime cause for the
46:34
people that are victims of crime?
46:36
So what research gets funded, for example?
46:38
It's much easier to get funded
46:40
studying problems that face girls than problems
46:42
that face boys. Richard Reeves has
46:44
done a great job of highlighting the
46:46
problems that face boys. Maybe
46:48
the funders will start to listen and
46:51
fund research on that problem. Let's
46:54
talk about AI because this is
46:56
a place where a few years ago
46:58
you wrote, I don't think AI
47:00
is going to be that big a
47:02
deal, that it's going to be
47:04
a kind of technological improvement that will
47:06
be kind of rolled out and
47:09
won't be that disruptive. Now
47:11
you seem to be much more
47:13
bullish on AI. Can you explain why?
47:15
Yeah. So first of all, I
47:17
still have the same view I had
47:19
before, which is our core problem
47:22
we have now is that we have
47:24
too little AI, not too much. Productivity
47:27
growth in some ways is a measure
47:29
of how many things people used to
47:31
do that machines can now do. And
47:33
it's not nearly high enough. I'd like
47:35
to see it much higher. So the
47:37
biggest problem we have is how to
47:39
have more AI. On the
47:41
disruptive side in terms of jobs,
47:43
I also continue to think that AI
47:45
is going to make new types
47:47
of jobs. that it's only going to
47:49
replace parts of some types of
47:51
jobs, that it's going to make us
47:53
richer, so we're going to want
47:55
to consume more services, and all of
47:57
that. So in broad
47:59
strokes, I still think the same
48:01
thing. I'm just much more optimistic,
48:03
and I'm much more optimistic because
48:05
they made breakthroughs at a pace
48:08
that a lot of the experts
48:10
in this area didn't think they
48:12
would. There's still a question of
48:14
how that gets adapted and used
48:16
in the workplace, how long that
48:18
process takes. So I've shifted towards
48:20
a more positive direction. Because there's
48:22
more of it and it seems
48:24
to be speeding up. Yeah. Now,
48:26
another piece, though, of AI that
48:29
I think has been really interesting to
48:31
me is how you think about
48:33
the digital giants and how concerned are
48:35
you about competition in the digital
48:37
space. I continue to be concerned. I
48:39
think antitrust enforcement is important because
48:41
I think competition is the source of
48:44
innovation. But what's really surprised me
48:46
is that the existing incumbents weren't the
48:48
ones that were able to dominate
48:50
in AI. Why does that surprise you,
48:52
though? Isn't that always the case,
48:54
that Microsoft comes along and knocks? knocks
48:57
off IBM even as they have
48:59
a kind of complementary relationship with
49:01
them and whatnot. Yeah, I agree.
49:03
It's happened over and over and
49:05
over again. So maybe this is
49:08
like the opposite of Lucy and
49:10
the football or something. But my
49:12
worry was that we were in
49:14
a place where AI depended so
49:16
much on data and so much
49:18
on scale and that nobody other
49:20
than Google and you
49:22
know, Facebook, Meta would have that
49:24
scale and those resources. And instead,
49:27
what we've seen is it turns
49:29
out that the algorithm matters a
49:31
lot too. And so open AI
49:33
and anthropic and perplexity, you know,
49:35
came to some degree from nowhere.
49:37
They got funding from some of
49:40
the big companies. DeepSeek came
49:42
from even less, probably more than
49:44
they claimed. Does that give you pause
49:46
about like, oh, you know, the
49:48
Chinese communists are going to somehow be
49:50
running everything? On
49:52
AI, I think there's some motivation
49:54
that comes from geopolitics, but boy,
49:57
is it hard to contain innovations
49:59
there. And on foundational models, it's
50:01
hard to be more than six
50:03
months ahead of the next person. And
50:06
so microchips is much
50:08
easier to maintain a
50:10
five, 10 -year lead
50:12
on than it is
50:15
on these algorithms. As
50:17
a final question, Talking
50:19
about AI and the fear
50:21
that we're going to wake
50:24
up tomorrow and whole industries
50:26
will be gone and there
50:28
won't be any jobs left
50:30
for certain types of people.
50:32
Your former boss, Barack Obama,
50:34
famously talked about how ATMs
50:36
had wiped out bank teller
50:38
jobs. This is a kind
50:40
of classic example of where
50:42
people think of technology as
50:44
something that robs people of
50:46
work. You
50:48
know, that certainly is not the case
50:51
even in the retail banking industry. Why
50:53
are we prone to that error
50:55
again and again, that a new
50:57
technology that actually makes things more
51:00
productive is going to put people
51:02
out of work? Be
51:04
clear. I think you got it right.
51:06
But what Obama said is people expected ATM
51:08
to take teller jobs. But instead, we
51:10
ended up with more bank branches because of
51:12
ATMs. And so you ended up with
51:14
more bank tellers, not Or people in the
51:17
banking industry. Yeah. So, you know.
51:19
We have hundreds of years of experience
51:21
with this. You know, no one could
51:23
have imagined what would happen in a
51:25
world where most people weren't working on
51:27
farms. What will they all do? What
51:29
else is there to do? Well, they'll
51:31
go to factories, but now they're not
51:33
in factories. Where have they gone? So
51:35
just our imagination isn't that great, but
51:37
it also doesn't need to be that
51:39
great because that's the beauty of the
51:42
market. Everyone's out there, the businesses, the
51:44
individuals trying to find new things, trying
51:46
to start a new business, trying to
51:48
figure out a new job. You
51:50
know, the central planners don't figure that
51:52
out. It's, you know, sort of a
51:54
Hayekian spontaneous order. And it's worked out
51:56
pretty well for a long time now.
51:59
So that would be my best guess.
52:01
So it will. But then, you know,
52:03
is there a stronger argument to say
52:05
to people that like, hey, you know,
52:07
in the past it all worked out? Or,
52:11
you know, trust the
52:13
Hayekian extended order and decentralization?
52:15
Well, look, you
52:18
know, there's also disruption. I mean,
52:20
the Luddites weren't wrong. These
52:22
machines were bad for the Luddites.
52:24
They were good for society as a
52:26
whole, but not for them. And
52:28
so part of why people are nervous
52:30
is because they don't understand what's
52:32
going to happen. And if only somebody
52:34
could explain it to them, they'd
52:36
be thrilled. Part of why they're nervous
52:38
is because they do understand. And
52:40
they understand that it won't be good
52:42
for them. And it's hard
52:44
to make the longer term
52:46
positive sum case. for the world.
52:49
But if you constantly make
52:51
whatever decision is loss minimizing over
52:53
the next minute, but has,
52:55
you know, costs that grow over
52:57
time, you know, you'll end
52:59
up more like Argentina over time
53:01
and less like the United
53:04
States. Okay. Well, without getting into
53:06
a discussion of Javier Millet,
53:08
who's remaking Argentina, we're going to
53:10
leave it there. Jason Furman,
53:12
thanks for talking to Riva. It's
53:14
been great talking to you.
Podchaser is the ultimate destination for podcast data, search, and discovery. Learn More