Episode Transcript
Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.
Use Ctrl + F to search
0:00
This is The Reason Interview with Nick
0:02
Gillespie. Before you do
0:04
anything else, please subscribe to
0:07
my new YouTube channel at
0:09
youtube.com/the at sign and then
0:12
The Reason Interview. That's youtube.com/at
0:14
The Reason Interview. My guest
0:16
today is John Arnold, the
0:19
former Enron Wunderkin turned billionaire
0:21
philanthropist who's determined to hack
0:24
America's most expensive and least
0:26
accountable public sector systems in
0:28
areas like criminal justice, education,
0:31
and pensions. Fun fact,
0:33
he was once called the most hated
0:35
man in pension land by governing magazine
0:37
due to his reform efforts. We
0:40
talk about why those public pensions are
0:42
so out of control and how to
0:45
fix them, how Medicare squeezes
0:47
billions of unnecessary dollars out of
0:49
taxpayers, and how Enron
0:51
scammed its investors, not despite
0:53
regulations, but in full view
0:55
of them. And we discuss
0:58
why, despite all our problems,
1:00
he's still betting on America to get better,
1:02
not worse. Here is the
1:04
Reasoned Interview with John Arnold. John
1:10
Arnold, thanks for talking to me. Great to
1:12
be here. So you and
1:15
your wife, Laura, head up
1:17
Arnold Ventures, which is a
1:19
gigantic philanthropy. I want
1:21
to get into that. And I also want
1:23
to start by asking you, you signed on
1:26
to the giving pledge. Explain
1:28
what the giving pledge is and
1:30
why you said, yeah, this is
1:32
us. So the giving pledge is
1:34
a non -binding pledge that somebody
1:36
signs that says we can give
1:38
away at least half of our
1:41
assets to the philanthropic sector
1:43
at some point. And it
1:45
started in the early 2010s,
1:47
right? Thereabouts? Exactly. Yeah. Exactly.
1:50
And I think we were always inclined
1:52
that way. I think
1:54
we have the benefit of getting to
1:56
see, you know, 100 plus years
1:59
of very significant wealth in this country.
2:02
And the good things it can do and also the bad
2:04
things it can do. And I think
2:06
one of the learnings of seeing
2:08
different families deal with the wealth,
2:11
especially second generation and third generation,
2:14
is that, you know, at times it brings
2:16
families together and at times it divides. I
2:18
mean, they're Canadian, but this
2:21
is the MacArthur Foundation, right?
2:23
Where the older generation of
2:25
the MacArthur money, what
2:27
it was a guy who is
2:29
conservative, his son who publishes Harper's is
2:32
very liberal. So there's partly there's that
2:34
right, but I can I ask, you
2:36
know, it's a truism within kind of
2:39
libertarian circles that, you know, people like
2:41
Henry Ford, or build
2:43
gates, have done much more for
2:46
society by building the products that
2:48
made them billionaires rather than the
2:50
philanthropy they do. Absolutely. I
2:53
think the private sector solves most problems
2:55
and I think that's the default. If
2:58
a problem exists, the private
3:00
sector should try to do it. Now, at times,
3:03
it's not incentivized to do it or there are
3:05
bad incentives. And so
3:07
then the government is kind of round two.
3:09
So you think about like public goods, right?
3:11
The private sector is not going to fund
3:13
those in the right way. And
3:15
so that there is a role for
3:17
government to come in and do the
3:19
things that private sector is not. And
3:21
then I think philanthropy is third. In
3:23
some ways, it's maybe the least effective
3:25
of the three, even though all the
3:27
inefficiencies associated with government that you
3:30
know, philanthropy is looking for things
3:32
where the private sector and the public
3:34
sector either don't have the incentive or
3:36
the will to try to address those
3:39
issues. Or yeah, I mean, part of
3:41
it is just a knowledge problem, right?
3:43
Where nobody's thinking about these problems and
3:45
maybe the private sector is an incentivized
3:48
to do research on them in the
3:50
public sector isn't either. Exactly. Or,
3:52
you know, the public sector might
3:55
not be incentivized, you know, the public sector is driven
3:57
by politicians, right? And so you got to think about
3:59
what are the incentives for politicians. And one of
4:01
those is you want to talk about things that
4:03
work. And if you fund something as a politician,
4:06
if you champion something, and it
4:08
doesn't work, your political opponent in the next
4:10
race is going to use it against you.
4:12
Look at all this money you lost. Do
4:14
you, you know, there's a truism, particularly, I
4:17
think it's on the kind of right side
4:19
of the political spectrum to say, well, you
4:21
know what, philanthropy worked, charity worked, and then
4:24
the government, particularly in the progressive era in
4:26
the early 20th century, started usurping. You
4:28
know various kinds of functions that
4:31
you know groups often based on
4:33
ethnicity or some other or Something
4:35
else, you know some other affinity
4:38
got pushed out of the market. Does
4:40
that ring true to you? I think You
4:42
take 100 years ago, 200 years ago, things
4:44
were much more built around the family. The
4:46
families were bigger, families stayed together, you stayed
4:48
on the same piece of land often. And
4:51
so one generation took care of the next. Or
4:54
whenever one generation got too old, then you had
4:56
the kids taking care of the parents. And
4:59
that's not how we live today. And so
5:01
kind of over time, as people have become
5:04
more nomadic across the US, and I think
5:06
there's a lot of benefit to that. And
5:08
that's how people want to live, at least
5:10
today. then it's kind of
5:12
changed what the family dynamic is. And
5:15
so sometimes, you know, the kids can't take care
5:17
of the parents or vice versa, or
5:19
you're away from your family. And
5:22
so I think the role of
5:24
government's probably changed just as family
5:26
dynamic has changed. How you are
5:28
famously a Houstonian, how are you
5:30
one of these people who say,
5:32
I am like a 10th generation
5:34
Texan, or like how long have
5:37
you been planted in Houston as
5:39
a... raised in Texas, born in
5:41
Dallas. My brother was born
5:43
in... Dallas is practically Canada though. right? I
5:47
brother was born as
5:49
was born in Pennsylvania. So parents moved
5:51
between my brother and me. Yeah, came
5:53
down for opportunity. I came down for
5:55
a job. I think that's why a
5:57
lot of people move to Texas. Yeah,
5:59
and certainly whether moving or now, right?
6:01
Yeah, exactly. Did so let's talk your
6:03
areas of interest are kind of interesting.
6:06
I mean, you you fund a lot
6:08
of K through 12 education stuff. And
6:10
you were big on the KIP. schools,
6:13
knowledge is power program. That's what
6:15
it's an acronym for. You do
6:17
criminal justice, you do pension reform
6:20
and you fund some of reason
6:22
foundations work on that. And
6:24
then also things like open
6:26
science or the integrity of
6:28
science. How do
6:31
you pick what your
6:33
foundation funds? We're involved in
6:35
about a dozen different areas. add
6:39
on housing and infrastructure policy and
6:41
health care costs. I
6:44
think the tie amongst them is that experience
6:46
in the K -12 reform movement,
6:48
which I've been part of for
6:50
over 25 years now, was kind
6:52
of a learning that top
6:55
-down implementation of programs is
6:57
very difficult and just doesn't
6:59
work, especially for a bottoms
7:01
-up type of field like
7:03
K -12 is. So much
7:05
of school successes about the
7:07
teacher and the principal that
7:09
are in the building. And
7:12
so the question is, if you're the
7:14
bureaucrat from above trying to push down
7:16
this new curriculum, trying to say like,
7:19
the school should do X, Y, Z. even
7:22
when the research shows that they're successful,
7:24
it's just very hard for that stuff
7:26
to scale and be successful. And so
7:28
we've very much over time, you know,
7:30
got a theory of change in K
7:33
-12 just about policy rather than programs
7:35
and about the rules and incentives of systems
7:37
and drive behavior. talk a little bit about
7:39
that. Is it that, you know,
7:41
in one of the stats, I remember this
7:43
was decades ago, I did some education stuff
7:46
and one of the most amazing facts
7:48
you know, that I came across, and
7:50
maybe it's not that interesting, but in
7:52
1930, there was something like 130 ,000
7:54
school districts in America. Basically, every town
7:57
was its own school district. There are
7:59
now fewer than 13 ,000. So
8:01
there's been, you know, the
8:03
population has exploded compared to, you
8:05
know, 100 years ago, and the
8:07
number of school districts has declined.
8:09
I mean, there's just so much
8:11
more centralization. But what you're saying
8:13
is that in education, you find
8:15
the real change happens kind of
8:17
dispersed throughout the system. Right.
8:20
So we're thinking about it from,
8:22
again, from the system standpoint about,
8:25
I guess, with the first principle
8:27
that government shouldn't be both the
8:30
service provider and the regulator. Right.
8:32
can't regulate yourself. There has to
8:34
be an accountability mechanism from coming
8:36
from somewhere else. Now,
8:38
technically, the state regulates the
8:41
school district. In reality, the
8:43
state is very, very reluctant to step in.
8:45
The politics involved in that are very difficult
8:47
on both sides. And so,
8:50
historically, you've had the school district just
8:52
be accountable to itself. And that may
8:54
be an elected school board, and there's
8:56
all kinds of types of problems, I
8:58
think, with single district elected school boards.
9:01
And so the question is, what's
9:04
the right role of government? And
9:06
we think that government should be
9:08
a strong regulator of of non
9:11
-profit service providers, i
9:13
.e. charter schools. So this kind of
9:15
goes back to my first entry was
9:17
with KIP and this charter school that
9:19
was getting very different results from the
9:21
school down the street that was educating
9:24
a same demographic. you
9:26
know, is there a secret sauce to
9:29
education other than involvement by all of
9:31
the stakeholders, you know, particularly parents, but
9:33
also teachers, et cetera? God, I wish
9:35
there was. I think K -12 is
9:37
the field that's just been hardest to
9:39
crack. And it's not just in
9:41
the US. There's no urban school system that
9:44
looks at it and say, oh, they've nailed
9:46
it. And they're the ones that have to.
9:48
I mean, the first city that comes up
9:50
with a better than average school system, however
9:52
you define that, would be like the greatest
9:55
city in the world. Everybody would want to
9:57
live there. Right. It's
9:59
ironic is that this problem
10:01
vexes the world as well.
10:05
Kind of famously, Wendy Cobb, who started
10:07
Teach for America, she ended up starting
10:10
Teach for All because she was getting
10:12
so many requests from people in other
10:14
countries saying, we're struggling with our schools.
10:16
Help us. And so she started
10:18
Teach for All and she works in dozens of countries
10:20
now. But kind of
10:22
every country, especially for the
10:25
low income and at risk
10:27
populations, really struggles with education.
10:31
pension reform. You in 2017,
10:33
Governing Magazine referred to you
10:35
in a genuinely flattering article
10:37
as the most hated man
10:39
in pension land. What
10:42
is your interest in pension reform? And
10:44
what's if charter schools are kind of
10:46
the big picture takeaway for education, hit
10:48
through 12 education, what's the big reform
10:51
in pensions? Yeah, well, I will fact
10:53
check that is true. Certainly,
10:56
there's a time when we were the most
10:58
hated people. So
11:01
I think 49 out of 50 states
11:03
have a balanced budget amendment. And the
11:05
purpose of that is to say that
11:07
the current generation should be paying for
11:10
the services that the current generation is
11:12
getting. It shouldn't be punning the
11:14
cost to the next generation. And
11:16
more or less that balanced budget
11:18
amendment works with one big exception.
11:22
And that exception has gotten so big you can
11:24
drive a truck through it and that's public pensions.
11:26
And so what's happened is that oftentimes that
11:29
you have a public union contract that
11:32
comes up and politicians have to make
11:34
a choice. They say either we give
11:36
them more money for their kind of
11:38
annual raises, which means we
11:41
either have to cut services or raise taxes,
11:43
or we can punt this. We can
11:46
offer them instead of raising their salaries,
11:48
we can give them more benefits. And
11:51
that's kind of the secret way to hide
11:53
the cost. And we don't have to make
11:55
this hard trade off. Why do state employees
11:57
buy into that though? Because this is, you
11:59
know, a lot of the times, I mean,
12:01
it kind of happens. But often, you know,
12:04
like, why wouldn't they be like, no, no,
12:06
we want, we'll take 50 % of what
12:08
you say you'll pay us in the future.
12:10
We'll take that now. Yeah. And the irony
12:12
is that, you know, when you do studies
12:14
and look at how much would you trade
12:17
off in pension benefits for current income? the
12:20
state should be paying more in current income
12:22
because that's what most employees actually value. And
12:24
it would be less money over the long
12:26
haul. Over the long haul, but that's not
12:28
where the political incentives are, of course. But
12:30
I think the reason is that
12:33
it's become a reason as to
12:35
why people will join is that
12:37
they understand that they get less
12:39
money today with a very, very
12:41
generous benefit in the future. And
12:43
I guess there is a long
12:45
period of time, particularly Right
12:48
after World War II where that the
12:50
fringe benefits or whatever, you know the
12:52
compensation package might have been more if
12:54
you got job security and like a
12:56
Cadillac retirement plan and health care plan
12:58
that made sense Yeah, so we're still
13:00
kind of locked in that. What's what's
13:02
the best way out of this trap?
13:04
So I think there's three components. One
13:06
is get rid of the abuses. So
13:09
there are some loopholes in the system
13:11
like you could not take a vacation
13:13
for the final 10 years of your
13:15
career and use all that. You spike
13:17
the pension like the last year or
13:19
two. You buy other people's overtime and
13:21
suddenly your salary might have been 70
13:23
grand, but you make $200 ,000 your
13:25
last year and that's what you're paying.
13:27
And then you get 70 % of
13:29
$200 ,000 right until you die. Until
13:33
you're killed. And
13:36
so, you know, those what I call
13:38
kind of loopholes or abuses, that wasn't
13:40
how the intent of the system, right?
13:42
So that's a component of it. I
13:44
think it's a relatively small component. And
13:46
that's kind of been locked down, right?
13:48
I mean, most of that's been much
13:50
of that's been taken care of. You
13:53
know, that was really reading about some of
13:56
those abuses caught my eye and got me
13:58
very interested. And then as you start to
14:00
research, you understand that it's the funding design
14:02
and benefit design that are driving. the major
14:04
problems. And the funding design
14:06
is how much is the city or
14:09
state putting away today in order to
14:11
meet that benefit tomorrow. And
14:13
you can play lots of games there. Either
14:15
you can just blatantly underfund it based upon
14:18
the actual real tables, or you can make
14:20
these very aggressive assumptions. And so
14:22
there's kind of famously that the more
14:24
you assume that the your investments will
14:26
make over the years the less money
14:29
you have to put aside today and
14:31
so and you have states like California
14:33
Illinois, etc. I have really done a
14:35
bet I mean they've they've exploited that
14:37
yeah where they're like yeah you're gonna
14:39
be making you know 10 % average
14:42
return on these investments that we're not
14:44
even making so we don't have to
14:46
fund as much right now exactly And
14:48
everybody's kind of in on the game.
14:50
And what was curious to me as
14:53
I started digging in and started talking
14:55
to unions and started talking to some
14:57
of the representatives is they recognize these
14:59
return assumptions are too high, but they
15:01
don't want them changed. They don't want
15:03
them lowered. They should, because
15:06
that would force the state or state
15:08
to put more money in today to
15:10
make it, you know, ensure, raise the
15:12
probability that that payout exists in the
15:14
future. They are convinced
15:16
that whatever the city or state
15:18
is supposed to pay, they
15:20
will end up paying, they'll find a way, and
15:23
they are worried that if you
15:25
lower the return percentage assumption that
15:28
that draw on money today will
15:30
put more kind of force the
15:32
issue and encourage reform that they
15:35
don't want to see. So then
15:37
is it I mean is that
15:39
is the big answer a shift
15:41
to define contribution rather than to
15:44
find benefit plan? If
15:46
you at private sector people have
15:48
a hybrid you have Social Security
15:50
and you have a 401k or
15:52
IRA right and so there's this
15:54
component of it that You don't
15:56
want to let people kind of
15:58
risk everything in a private investment
16:00
portfolio and you know end up
16:02
65 years old with nothing right
16:04
And so that's what social security
16:06
allows is kind of a guaranteed
16:08
stream that's there for as long
16:10
as you live. And that's important.
16:13
And so we think that something that looks
16:15
like a hybrid system is right for kind
16:18
of 90 % of Americans, why not the
16:20
100 % Americans? And that seems to be
16:22
gaining ground. I mean, in the way that
16:24
school choice has certainly been exploding over the
16:27
past couple of years after a
16:29
lot of build up, but it
16:31
seems like more states, more localities
16:34
are okay with the idea of
16:36
creating defined contribution plans for public
16:39
sector employees. Yeah, certainly for new
16:41
employees. I think there's a principle
16:43
of, you know, don't change the
16:46
benefits that have already been earned.
16:49
I think there's some other ways, some other reforms
16:52
you can do in order to make sure that
16:54
the risk is shared between the state and the
16:56
employee. What are
16:58
some of those? One is
17:00
that your cost of living
17:03
adjustment is lower if the
17:05
fund is underfunded by a
17:07
certain amount. If
17:09
the investment returns are not
17:11
meeting the assumption that both
17:13
the employee and the state
17:15
share some of that risk
17:17
rather than it being 100
17:19
% on the state. Talk
17:21
about your interest in healthcare.
17:24
What's the main focus of
17:26
Arnold Ventures' interest in healthcare
17:28
policy? Yeah, so we looked
17:30
at it and as we
17:32
kind of decided one day,
17:34
we looked at what are
17:36
the topics that interest us,
17:38
including public finance and education
17:40
and criminal justice, that
17:42
the tie amongst those was this
17:44
policy component and these large systems
17:46
and market failures associated with it.
17:49
And so here's this huge healthcare
17:51
system. It's just obvious that we
17:53
need to start thinking about that.
17:55
And so one of the draws
17:57
was, I know that
17:59
there were a number of
18:02
abuses that or inefficiencies that
18:04
experts had identified, but
18:06
it was one that special interests were
18:08
very powerful in. And so that's why
18:10
- What is the main one of
18:12
those? So there's many.
18:14
So there's a big question
18:16
about How do you price
18:18
pharmaceuticals that are necessary to
18:20
quality of life but have
18:22
a regulated monopoly and that
18:24
are paid for by the
18:27
government? What's the pricing of
18:29
that? There's questions
18:31
about, so in Medicare
18:33
Advantage, you see
18:35
insurance companies have figured out loopholes
18:37
that if we upcode our patient
18:39
population, that is, we make them
18:42
look less healthy than they are.
18:44
then we get higher reimbursements. So
18:47
they tell their doctors, you know,
18:49
you need to spend time and go make sure,
18:51
like, ask every question about, you know, their health,
18:53
that even if this doesn't bother the patient at
18:56
all, they would never have mentioned it to the
18:58
doctor and it doesn't affect their quality of health,
19:00
whatever. If the insurance company
19:02
can check it on their records, they get
19:04
a higher reimbursement, right? And so you kind
19:06
of live in a world where every patient
19:09
is below average health, right? Or
19:12
things like site neutral policy. So
19:14
hospitals get higher reimbursements from Medicare
19:16
than a doctor's office that's in
19:19
the suburbs does. And
19:21
so what happens, the hospitals figure this out, they
19:23
buy the doctor's office, it's the same doctor in
19:25
the same location doing the same service. But now
19:27
it's a hospital. But because the
19:29
sign on the front door changed, you
19:32
know, the rates go up 50%. Are
19:34
you, there's been talk about doge, you
19:36
know, more generally, but getting, turning to
19:38
Medicare and Medicaid fraud. And I know
19:41
Obama's chief economic advisor for a while
19:43
was Christina Romer, a highly respected economist,
19:45
who at one point had published a
19:48
study where nearly 30 % of Medicare,
19:50
she said 30 % of its expenditures
19:52
could have been cut without any effect
19:55
on patient income. So there's a lot
19:57
of I don't know if it's waste,
19:59
fraud, or abuse, but there's a lot
20:02
of looseness in that system. Do
20:04
you think Doge or somebody,
20:06
like how do you cut
20:08
Medicare expenditures without having every
20:10
senior citizen in their personalized
20:13
rascal suit or marching or
20:15
driving on DC? Right. And
20:17
the fundamental principle is we
20:19
don't want to touch access
20:21
to care. Right. That's
20:23
not the right way to try
20:26
to lower costs in the healthcare
20:28
system. It is going after this
20:30
proverbial waste, fraud, and abuse. And
20:32
a lot of this stuff has been identified.
20:36
We've identified some of it. Many other
20:38
people have identified most of it. It's
20:40
always been more of a political problem. And
20:43
again, the health care... is
20:46
the most powerful of any in
20:48
the United States. It is just
20:50
amazing how many dollars and how
20:52
many bodies they have in DC
20:55
to try to make sure that
20:57
the system doesn't change. How do
20:59
you cut that? Yeah, so it
21:01
almost needs a forcing mechanism. And
21:04
you find that whenever Congress wants
21:06
to introduce something new, and
21:10
also feels compelled to pay
21:12
for it. So in the
21:14
IRA, Democrats put
21:16
in pharmaceutical pricing provisions
21:18
in it to save
21:20
money. And now
21:23
with the TCGA extension, that's probably going
21:25
to cost $4 .5 trillion or so.
21:28
And at least in the house reconciliation
21:30
instructions, they've mandated at least $2 trillion
21:32
of savings. And so
21:34
now you have this forcing function
21:36
that necessitates finding money, finding savings.
21:39
And without that, Congress
21:42
wouldn't act. They
21:44
know this stuff. The people in the
21:46
committee, they know it. But this is
21:48
just part of the political process that
21:50
until they need to pay for something
21:52
that they want even more and are
21:54
willing to infuriate all those lobbyists, then
21:56
it doesn't happen. And so we have
21:59
this very interesting window that's going to
22:01
happen sometime this year, right,
22:03
where it actually is, okay, we
22:05
need to find hundreds of billions
22:07
of dollars of savings in the
22:09
healthcare system. And there's more and
22:11
more consensus that that Congress doesn't
22:13
want that to come from access.
22:16
Right. And so then you have to go into
22:19
the waste front abuse. Criminal
22:21
justice year in Texas. Texas
22:24
I don't know if it's still the kind
22:26
of prison capital of America But you know
22:29
it was a big thing what what's your
22:31
interest in criminal justice and you know, what
22:33
are the you know What are what are
22:35
the best ways to kind of make the
22:38
criminal justice system? More I
22:40
was gonna say less punitive. I don't
22:42
actually I mean to be more efficient
22:44
better gas Yeah, yeah, I kind of
22:46
joke that we were government efficiency before
22:48
government efficiency was cool. We just We
22:50
didn't have a catchy name for it.
22:52
We call it evidence -based policy and
22:54
program integrity. And it's like
22:56
just thinking about the criminal justice system
22:58
and the goals of it and the
23:00
stakeholders. And so you can think about
23:02
the goals. Obviously, public safety is goal
23:04
number one, right? You can never lose
23:06
that. But there's
23:08
also the rights of the accused
23:10
and convicted, the kind of the
23:13
financial cost of the system, the
23:15
collateral damage to neighborhoods and to
23:17
families. And you can think
23:19
of more. And so the question is, how
23:21
do you balance those? And
23:24
especially, how can you improve some of
23:26
the other goals while maintaining or improving
23:28
public safety? And so that's kind of
23:30
our fundamental view of the field. And
23:34
we think there's been a lot
23:36
of things. And I think the
23:38
field has gone from the crime
23:40
bill under Clinton, which when crime
23:42
was climbing, you found the steady
23:44
trend and you know a very
23:46
rational response by Congress that was
23:48
you know just facing the wrath
23:50
of crime in the neighborhoods and
23:52
you had you know black communities
23:54
were calling for and actually leading
23:56
a lot of that effort right
23:58
because of the the damage that
24:00
the criminal activity was having in
24:02
these neighborhoods but we're in a
24:04
very different world right now and
24:06
kind of the amount of crimes
24:08
going down it's been on the
24:10
steady trend down And we've seen
24:12
the effect of that tough -on
24:14
-crime mantra in a number of
24:16
areas. And even Texas saw this.
24:18
So Texas very much had a
24:20
tough -on -crime mantra up until
24:22
about 2007, when there's this big
24:24
kind of famous prison bill that
24:26
came up that says, we need
24:29
to build seven new prisons and
24:31
stepped back and looked at the
24:33
financial cost of that and said,
24:35
OK, we've got to either raise
24:37
taxes or cut spending in education.
24:39
Or like, what if we just do
24:41
things smarter, right? And so it
24:44
went from tough on crime to smart on crime.
24:46
And I think that was the realization
24:49
that a conservative state is looking at
24:51
this saying we can maintain or even
24:53
improve public safety while we run the
24:56
system better. So a lot of it
24:58
is like forcing government to say, okay,
25:00
this has a this has a bill
25:03
that you have to pay kind of
25:05
in the here and now and then
25:07
people suddenly become much more creative, right,
25:10
and how they deliver education or health
25:12
care or safety, public safety. Right.
25:15
So I think there's components of it.
25:18
The criminal justice system is
25:20
just so complex from the
25:23
police, the DAs, public defenders,
25:25
the judges, the jails and
25:28
prisons, reentry system, including
25:30
parole and probation. And
25:32
we kind of work on all of
25:34
that. Yeah. And You know, there's no
25:36
magic bullet in this. There's silver bullet
25:38
in this. It is, you know, this
25:40
is constant. How do you make the
25:42
system slowly better over time? One
25:45
of the you do a lot of
25:47
work on gun violence as well. And
25:50
this for a libertarian audience, I think
25:52
people will be surprised by some of
25:54
the findings that you found the correlation
25:56
between gun ownership and gun violence. What
25:59
what has your, what has Arnold Ventures
26:01
broadly kind of found through its research
26:03
on guns? Yeah, like many issues, we
26:05
kind of get pulled into things. And
26:08
so we often find that policy makers
26:10
are struggling with an issue and they
26:12
come and say, you know, what's going
26:14
on in this field? And so obviously
26:17
there's been a lot of concern about
26:19
mass shootings and about homicides in general,
26:21
and the role of guns in those.
26:23
And so the question to us was,
26:26
you know, What is the evidence show?
26:28
And we very much view that as
26:30
part of our role in public policy
26:32
is generating data. Yeah, both generating research
26:35
as well as translating the research to
26:37
policymakers. And so we ended up funding
26:39
a lot of research on guns as
26:41
well as trying to translate that to
26:44
policymakers. And unfortunately, you
26:47
know, there's not a lot of good answers, right?
26:49
And so I think that one of the learnings
26:51
from it is that, you know, there's a limited
26:53
number of interventions, but, you know, if you look
26:55
at the things that, you know, are both constitutional,
26:58
as well as, you know, understand
27:01
and appreciate the hundreds of millions of guns that
27:04
are on the street today, as
27:06
well as that are effective, right?
27:08
It's a very small and in a
27:10
very broad sense. You know,
27:12
going back to say like the
27:15
mid nineties, there are many more
27:17
guns in circulation and it's legal
27:19
to own or carry guns. Gun
27:21
crime is generally down. But then
27:23
if I'm recalling correctly, some of
27:25
the research I did, I think
27:28
was through a ran study that
27:30
you guys funded finding that, you
27:32
know, for women, particularly having a
27:34
gun in the house raised the
27:36
court. There was a strong. 10
27:38
or 12 percent higher than average
27:41
correlation with suicide, things
27:43
like that. So part of it is
27:45
just figuring out what has actually happened.
27:47
Yeah, I think we've seen states institute
27:50
red flag laws saying that for people
27:52
who are not you know, mentally stable
27:54
for a certain time period that the
27:57
state can remove their guns. You
27:59
know, it's controversial. It's controversial in
28:01
conservative states. There's an effort, you
28:03
know, in Texas right now to
28:05
revoke some of those, or, you
28:07
know, to not recognize other states,
28:09
Red Fly Rawls. And
28:12
so there's, you know, a tough
28:14
area. Unfortunately, not
28:16
everything has a great answer to it. And
28:19
sometimes we just say, we
28:21
don't have a great solution. How
28:23
do you define yourself kind of
28:25
politically or ideologically? Because you fund
28:27
market -based groups, libertarian groups. Your
28:29
background is in trading. I want
28:32
to talk a little bit about
28:34
that. Many
28:37
of your policy goals seem to
28:39
be fully in line with a
28:41
kind of progressive mentality. Do you
28:44
think of yourself as particularly this
28:46
or that when it comes to
28:48
ideology or politics? Yeah, I think
28:50
I'd disagree that our answers are
28:53
more progressive. I wasn't taking
28:55
answers. I mean, like the goals. Yeah.
28:58
Actually, I think
29:00
I'd disagree with that. I think what we
29:02
find is policy makers want
29:04
solutions, especially local and state
29:06
policymakers who don't have the
29:09
ability just to spend more
29:11
money at problems. They
29:13
want to know what to do. And
29:15
especially if you can come and
29:18
say, here's what the evidence is
29:20
as to how you can improve
29:22
outcomes for any system without spending
29:24
more money. We find that whether
29:26
you're a Republican or a Democrat,
29:29
that there's a lot of interest there. And we work with
29:31
people on the far left, we work with people on the
29:33
far right. You know,
29:35
it tends to be just very much
29:37
issue specific. So we often
29:39
get asked in, right? And so we're not going
29:41
to show up in some community and say, you
29:44
know, you should do X. It's
29:46
a community that's struggling with a problem
29:48
and kind of ask us for help.
29:50
And we try to provide that. And
29:52
that, I mean, what I think, you
29:54
know, what I find most interesting in
29:57
a lot of ways about what you
29:59
guys are doing is this commitment to
30:01
either open science or science with integrity
30:03
or research with integrity, that
30:06
seems fascinating. That's kind of
30:08
what you're focusing on is
30:10
getting actual data and then
30:12
making sure that this stuff
30:14
is real as opposed to
30:16
you're doing research that just
30:18
happens to find what you
30:20
wanted to find. How
30:22
did you get interested in that? I
30:25
had one thing to the previous question
30:27
because I think a lot of One
30:29
of the criteria that we have on
30:31
when to enter a new area is
30:33
when do we think this bipartisan window
30:35
is going to open? And
30:37
we think, you know, we're very
30:39
hesitant to work in partisan issues. There's
30:42
a lot of groups that are interested
30:44
in partisan side. There's a lot of
30:46
funding and think tanks that are interested
30:48
in partisan issues. And there's kind
30:50
of a Darth that are looking at
30:52
where's the policy window open, kind of
30:54
the intersection of left and right. And
30:56
part of that is that the will
30:58
to try to address an issue comes.
31:01
And then we try to hope on, okay,
31:03
where are the bipartisan solutions? Because we think
31:06
if they are bipartisan, that they'll be more
31:08
sustainable. And the
31:10
next administration doesn't throw it out and
31:12
do their own things. So
31:15
the question on what got us
31:17
interested in an evidence base, some
31:21
of that was my background
31:23
in trading and thinking about
31:25
that there had to be,
31:27
you're always questioning, you
31:29
know, what, you know, are
31:32
you right? Are your assumptions on a
31:34
problem right? And every day you go
31:36
in and like, here's my view. What's
31:39
the counter side? What's the counter argument for that?
31:42
And then I think, you know, trying
31:44
to, you know, enter
31:46
this field of philanthropy, which is
31:49
enormously complicated, without
31:51
especially at the time without great data and
31:54
try to figure out, okay, what's the highest
31:56
value add we can have in the field?
31:58
And that was involved trying to read a
32:00
lot of research and a lot of studies.
32:03
And sometimes we learned stuff from
32:05
that and sometimes we ended up
32:07
more confused than when we started
32:09
after that. And so we realized
32:12
that there was both a dearth
32:14
of supply and demand of evidence
32:16
in policymaking. And so we
32:18
wanted to attack both problems and we
32:20
wanted to go fund a lot new
32:22
of high quality research on kind of
32:25
social policy and social programs, try to
32:27
figure out what works and what doesn't.
32:30
And then second, you can do all
32:32
the supply, you can fund,
32:34
but if nobody's taking it up,
32:36
if nobody's using it, then it
32:38
doesn't do any good. So there
32:40
has to be kind of the
32:43
corresponding, how do you increase demand
32:45
for it? And so like this
32:47
week, we were in Oklahoma with
32:49
Governor Stitt. announcing this new program
32:51
to bring new funding for proven
32:54
programs that meet the highest bar
32:56
of success from the research into
32:58
Oklahoma. And it's 10
33:00
million of our money, 10 million of
33:03
state money, which in the grand scheme
33:05
of things is not that much money,
33:07
but it's an attempt to change the
33:09
culture of how state legislatures start allocating.
33:12
What's one of the issues that
33:14
you're like, okay, we're we're going
33:16
to look at, like here's where
33:18
the good research clearly points, these
33:20
are better programs or policies
33:22
than whatever else was being
33:25
considered. Yeah, I think one
33:27
of the trends has been
33:29
this push for college for
33:31
all, right? And trying
33:33
to put as many people into college.
33:36
And then with the benefit of
33:39
hindsight now, we get to see
33:41
what this 20 plus years of
33:43
college for all, what the results
33:46
are. And I think society
33:48
is looking back and saying, scratching their heads and saying,
33:50
you know, there are a
33:52
lot of people who enrolled who
33:54
did not get certificates or degrees
33:56
that the market valued, right, the
33:58
purpose of going. Although there is
34:00
still a premium, right, to having
34:03
a college degree. Well, generally. So
34:05
I think on average, right, those with
34:07
college degrees, you know, do much better
34:09
financially than those without college degrees. But
34:11
a lot of that is selection bias.
34:13
Right. And so if you think about
34:15
the marginal kid, you know, is it
34:17
right? You know, the right path to
34:19
go to college to go to a
34:21
four year college, two year college, you
34:23
know, certificate program, you know, an apprenticeship
34:25
program, etc. And I think,
34:28
you know, one thing that's been missing there. has
34:30
been good data and good transparency
34:33
on outcomes. And so that's
34:35
really, you know, a field that we've
34:37
been trying to push on is like, whenever a kid's
34:39
making that decision is 18 years old and trying to
34:41
decide, what am I going to do for the next
34:43
four years? At least have
34:45
good data about, you know, kids that
34:47
look like me or have the same
34:49
background, academic background that I do. And
34:52
they go to this school and major
34:54
in this thing or get this degree.
34:56
Like, what are they, how?
34:58
effective as that. And then I guess
35:00
going backwards that also I mean clearly
35:03
you know K through 12 curricula particularly
35:05
in high school has changed so that
35:07
in many parts of the country things
35:09
like vocational and technical education has just
35:12
kind of disappeared partly because if everybody's
35:14
going to college then you're not going
35:16
to have as many shop classes etc
35:18
and if you find out that well
35:20
you know what like a lot of
35:23
people would flourish you know doing a
35:25
trade you could start doing that in
35:27
high school. Right. And I think there
35:29
was, you know, been this longstanding concern
35:32
about tracking kids. Right. And,
35:34
you know, today we track them
35:36
at age 18. Right. Right. And
35:38
the question is, is 18 the
35:40
right age? And if
35:42
we think, you know, kids in
35:44
high school should not necessarily be
35:46
tracked, but they can be introduced
35:48
to programs, right? You can have
35:50
more options open. Yeah. Right. And
35:53
so there's been this very broad
35:55
bipartisan interest in kind of reintroducing
35:57
CTE. back into high school. And
35:59
again, just to show like, you know, if you're
36:01
like to work with your hands, here are some
36:03
careers that are in high demand, pay high wages
36:06
that are open to you. And you know, here's
36:08
an introduction to them. You know, you can still
36:10
you're still on the path to go to a
36:12
four -year school if that's what you choose or
36:14
a two -year school, but here's also a career
36:16
path. It's kind of exciting, right? I mean, we
36:18
seem to be at a point where a lot
36:20
of stuff that's been around for, you know, say
36:23
50 or really 100 years, things like occupational licensing,
36:25
zoning, or the kind of
36:27
post -war education system, a
36:30
lot of it's coming up for review,
36:32
right, which is good. You know because
36:34
it but we're living a different world
36:36
agree Can I ask this is a
36:38
might be a strange question to you?
36:40
But what is it like? What's it
36:42
feel like being a billionaire? Because
36:46
there's not that many
36:48
of you You know
36:50
it They that process
36:52
of going from not
36:54
a billionaire. Yeah, too
36:56
very wealthy, right? It
36:59
was kind of shocking. Yeah, it kind of
37:01
is a shock to the system And
37:04
I think it started to change my
37:07
personality a little bit and then my
37:09
family kind of slaps me up right
37:11
like get back to it like okay,
37:14
and then and then like now it's
37:16
you know My vacations are better than
37:18
you know if I if I weren't
37:20
a billionaire, right? But much of my
37:23
life is kind of the same. Yeah,
37:25
and it's like you get happiness from
37:27
you know success in your family you
37:30
get happiness by you know spending time
37:32
with friends By having high quality moments.
37:34
Yeah, I probably work more hours today
37:37
than I've ever worked in my life
37:39
and so And you launched into you
37:41
know kind of your career or maybe
37:43
not launched into your career, but you
37:46
worked at Enron And you and I
37:48
mean when Enron collapsed you were not
37:50
you were not touched by any kind
37:53
of scandal or anything right now But
37:55
what is it like to you know
37:57
if you Google? If somebody Googles you,
37:59
one of the first things to learn
38:02
is that I think in 2001 or
38:04
2002 or so, right before Enron went
38:06
into bankruptcy, you were given,
38:09
I think it was an $8 million
38:11
bonus and you had made them like
38:13
hundreds of millions of dollars. So in
38:15
a way, it's like, why only eight?
38:17
But what is it like to have
38:19
made your bones at the company that
38:21
more than any other company in our
38:23
lifetime is the poster child for just
38:25
kind of bullshit, fake capitalism? Yeah,
38:28
it was you know, I started
38:30
to Enron directly out of school
38:33
when I was 21 years old
38:35
and it was a fantastic place
38:37
to work Because it was growing
38:40
so quickly. It was really pioneering
38:42
a new industry Everybody wanted to
38:44
be Enron. They know all the
38:47
other Historic natural gas pipeline companies
38:49
were the you know hiring Enron
38:51
people away to go, you know
38:54
copy the Enron business model which
38:56
then allowed a young person that
38:58
you know, could prove that they
39:01
could handle responsibility and was motivated
39:03
to move up much faster at
39:06
Enron than in a different type
39:08
of field. And
39:10
so I was a huge beneficiary of that. My
39:12
timing was kind of exactly right. By
39:15
the time I was 26 years old, I was
39:17
the head trader at Enron. And
39:20
Enron was the largest firm
39:22
in my industry. And
39:24
so just an enormous amount of
39:26
benefit from being there at a
39:29
young age. So what was at
39:31
root, what was the scam in
39:33
Enron? And is it, yeah, answer
39:35
that. I think it was hubris.
39:38
It was a company
39:40
where the culture was,
39:42
we can't do wrong.
39:46
And so what started to happen
39:48
was, Enron,
39:50
had a great thing, kind
39:52
of discovered this new industry.
39:55
It actually was kind of originated
39:57
out of the degreagulation of natural
40:00
gas that happened in the 80s.
40:03
And the energy system in America used to
40:05
be very highly regulated, used to be kind
40:07
of the government would set the price of
40:10
natural gas, and then you get these booms
40:12
and And it was
40:14
clear that that was a bad
40:16
system. Jimmy Carter started to do
40:18
regulation in the late 70s and
40:20
then Reagan and then finally with
40:22
Bush. And
40:25
then so what happened was the
40:27
system used to be integrated. We
40:29
had the producer and the pipeline
40:31
and the end user would kind
40:34
of be the same. It was
40:36
recognition that the natural monopoly of
40:38
those three was the pipeline. And
40:40
so let's separate that out and
40:43
highly regulate that. But the
40:45
producers, that's kind of a naturally
40:47
highly competitive market. And end users,
40:49
that's a highly competitive market. So
40:52
it created the need for someone
40:54
to do the logistics of moving
40:56
gas around. And that was really
40:58
what Enron kind of, as it
41:01
emerged from just a natural gas
41:03
pipeline and production company, it started
41:05
being logistics company. And it was
41:07
serving a huge need for the
41:09
market that still exists through today.
41:13
and earned a lot of money
41:15
from it. And it started trying
41:17
to apply that logistics framework to
41:19
other industries. The power industry was
41:21
deregulating during this time as well.
41:23
And there was parts of the
41:25
water industry were deregulating and the
41:27
growth of broadband and people thought
41:29
you could trade broadband and trucking
41:31
and all these things. And
41:34
this was the rise of
41:36
using the internet for disintermediation.
41:39
And so there was kind of
41:41
a lot of value creation to
41:43
be done. And
41:45
Enron was, you know, started having
41:47
these very consistent and high growth
41:49
earnings. And because of that, it
41:52
got rewarded by the market by
41:54
having a high PE valuation and
41:56
much higher than its peers. Right.
41:59
And then you almost get trapped
42:02
by that, where if you're being
42:04
rewarded because you're growing faster and
42:06
more consistently than the market, The
42:09
problem is that if you ever miss
42:11
that, you lose that huge premium. And
42:14
if not, your stock goes down 5%, but you
42:16
lose 50%. And I think kind of looking back,
42:18
it was very similar to what happened with GE.
42:21
The two companies were kind of
42:23
almost identical in their hubris and
42:25
how they traded relative to their
42:27
peer companies. And you
42:30
saw GE, which came days
42:32
from going bankrupt. It was only
42:34
saved because it was deemed a
42:36
strategic financial institution in 2008. And
42:39
it took 10 years for them to work out. And
42:43
Enron did go bankrupt, of course.
42:45
One of the things that's interesting
42:47
is Enron, almost a year before
42:49
the scandal kind of publicly hit
42:51
and it kind of was vaporized,
42:54
the market started You know
42:56
turning against it. So in a way
42:58
I mean like Enron is held up
43:01
as this you know This is what
43:03
capitalism brings these fake companies that create
43:05
bubbles and then you know destroy the
43:07
lives of people That's one way of
43:09
looking at it as part of it
43:12
also that the markets kind of over
43:14
time like they figure out who's scamming
43:16
and who's not yeah, and I think
43:18
the regulation changed mm -hmm after Enron
43:20
and I think you know people complain
43:23
about it, but one of the you
43:25
know great things about the U .S.
43:27
capital market system is that investors put
43:29
a higher level of trust into American
43:32
companies than they do overseas companies, partially
43:34
because of these regs. And we can have the
43:37
debates about the cost benefit and is it a
43:39
little bit too much? Is it not enough? But
43:42
I think some of that regulatory
43:44
framework is valuable. And
43:47
because of that, again,
43:49
the American companies trade
43:52
at higher multiples because of the
43:54
confidence from investors and they're held
43:56
to higher standards. And
43:59
I think capital markets over time figure
44:01
these things out. The
44:03
frauds, unfortunately, you can't get rid
44:06
of them entirely. And
44:08
whenever it happens, there's always going to be a lot of pain.
44:10
There's to be a lot of pain from the employees. to
44:13
be a lot of pain from
44:15
investors in the communities in which
44:17
these firms operate. But
44:20
I think We've gotten
44:22
better as a society,
44:24
as a financial industry
44:26
of minimizing those over
44:29
time. You
44:31
say, okay, sometimes the regulations go
44:33
overboard, sometimes they're not enough. Coming
44:36
out of the, I guess Enrom
44:39
but the tech bubble more generally,
44:41
there were things like Sarbanes Oxley,
44:43
which supposedly chased a lot of
44:45
companies. over to Europe. They would
44:47
list there rather than the US
44:49
because of some of the clauses
44:51
that were put into financial regulation,
44:53
something like Dodd -Frank coming out
44:55
of the financial crisis. Is
44:58
there a way to get
45:00
regulation right from the beginning
45:02
as opposed to reacting and
45:04
then overreacting and then having
45:06
a correction to that? I
45:09
don't think there is. I think a lot
45:11
of this is just learning by doing. Financial
45:15
industry changes over time. People
45:18
find ways to get around the regulation and
45:20
then you kind of have to adjust it
45:22
or wait for something to blow up and
45:25
get the political will to adjust it. And
45:28
so I think this is the
45:30
benefit of what happens at state
45:32
policy versus federal policy is that
45:34
getting things right the first time
45:36
is very difficult. And
45:39
in state policy, they're willing to go
45:41
back on an issue and fix it
45:43
the next year and adjust it again
45:45
the next year. And you see this
45:47
with housing policies. And they'll pass something.
45:50
And then the industry says, OK, you
45:52
adjust these three things, but you forgot
45:54
this fourth thing. Or this isn't working.
45:56
And you go fix it. Whereas at
45:58
the federal level, it feels like once
46:01
every 20 years, you get one bill
46:03
on an issue, whether that's for health
46:05
care or financial industry. and
46:07
or immigration not even at 250
46:10
exactly exactly and you're stuck with
46:12
the mistakes of it yeah right
46:14
and and then it becomes a
46:16
longer that those loopholes or and
46:18
the bad regulatory regime lasts the
46:21
harder it is to fix it
46:23
and you almost need the whole
46:25
thing to blow up somehow in
46:27
order to get the political will
46:30
to go do it again. You
46:32
have a very lively Twitter presence
46:34
and when I read your stuff
46:36
on Twitter, I'm like, oh, this
46:39
is optimistic in the sense that
46:41
you're engaging questions and they seem
46:43
to be answerable and that we
46:45
can do policy better rather than
46:48
worse. Do you feel like
46:50
we're we're in a good age for
46:52
public policy or for the possibilities of
46:54
things? I mean, how do you how
46:56
do you feel about the next couple
46:59
of years, the next 10 years, the
47:01
next 20 years? Great
47:04
question. First, I think you're
47:06
the first person who's ever said my Twitter feed
47:08
was optimistic. I should remind
47:11
sometimes. You know, I
47:13
think we've always tried to not just
47:15
point out problems but try to be
47:17
constructive and say, okay, here's a problem
47:20
and here's an idea about how to
47:22
make the system better. It's easy to
47:24
sit in the audience and just throw
47:26
peanuts at the people who are coming
47:28
up with policy and actually coming up
47:30
with better policies hard. And
47:33
so we've tried to keep that standard. But
47:35
next 10, 20 years,
47:38
it's always made sense to
47:40
bet on America. Right. It's
47:42
been such a robust country
47:44
under so many different challenges.
47:47
And so America faces some challenges today. It
47:49
faced different challenges 10 years ago. You know,
47:51
faced different challenges in 10 years. And,
47:54
you know, I want to bet
47:56
on it because it's worked. Yeah.
47:58
Do you worry, you know, in
48:00
a kind of Trump 2 .0
48:03
or Trump second term, one
48:05
of the things that I think he
48:07
recognized in a way that, you know,
48:09
say, Hillary Clinton didn't quite as explicitly
48:12
is that we were kind of post
48:14
hegemon or you know he he recognized
48:16
that people were feeling anxious about the
48:18
current time in the future and you
48:21
know he talked about he you know
48:23
that he we could go back to
48:25
a time when you know a single
48:27
you know one male income
48:29
earner could have an industrial job and,
48:31
you know, have, you know, 50 children
48:33
and buy steak every week and all
48:35
of this kind of stuff. It's a
48:37
false vision of the past, but he
48:40
recognized there's a lot of anxiety. And
48:42
we're in a very economically uncertain time.
48:44
Do you feel like when you say
48:46
it's good to bet on America, it
48:48
seems in a lot of ways, people
48:50
don't share that kind of optimism anymore?
48:52
What, what do you do you think
48:54
Trump is the solution going forward or
48:58
you know, where
49:00
do we go to regain our optimism
49:02
more broadly, I guess? Tough
49:05
question. I'm not sure I have a
49:07
great answer for it. I think, you
49:09
know, it's, innovation's gotten
49:12
harder over time. And there's been a
49:14
lot written about this, about, you know,
49:16
the difficulties in finding the next breakthrough,
49:18
right? And so, you know, how much
49:20
of that rise in incomes, which is
49:22
a rise in quality of life that
49:24
happened in the 20th century was picking
49:26
the low hanging fruit. of
49:28
innovations. Because at the end
49:30
of the day, a society can
49:32
only consume what it produces over
49:35
the long term. And so productivity
49:37
and innovation are key to that.
49:40
And if that's getting harder,
49:42
then quality of life gains decrease
49:45
just broadly. It doesn't matter who
49:47
the president is or which party
49:49
is in charge. And
49:52
I think this is where you
49:54
know, tech and, you know, there's all these
49:56
great advancements or promises of next generation
49:58
of technology you know, the
50:00
real chance to greatly
50:02
improve quality of life
50:04
for people. I think you
50:06
know, one potential outcome.
50:09
You can imagine different outcomes
50:11
from the It might end
50:13
up you know, meeting expectations
50:15
and kind of being you know,
50:17
gains, but not transformative
50:19
gains. And I think that's
50:21
the big question is, you know, especially you
50:23
look at the U financial situation and
50:25
U .S. demographics, if
50:27
you spend too much time looking at
50:30
that, it's hard to walk away and
50:32
say, I want to on America because we're
50:34
facing a lot of headwinds. then
50:36
question is, can technology and
50:39
innovation make up for that?
50:41
Well, I guess that's why I
50:43
think you're optimistic because you're not
50:45
saying and you know AI or next technology is
50:48
to destroy us all It's probably
50:50
going to be at least marge along John
50:52
Arnold. thanks so much for talking reason
50:54
been great meeting you.
Podchaser is the ultimate destination for podcast data, search, and discovery. Learn More