Trump V2: Tariffs, American Dynamism, Higher Ed | Byrne Hobart

Trump V2: Tariffs, American Dynamism, Higher Ed | Byrne Hobart

Released Sunday, 20th April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Trump V2: Tariffs, American Dynamism, Higher Ed | Byrne Hobart

Trump V2: Tariffs, American Dynamism, Higher Ed | Byrne Hobart

Trump V2: Tariffs, American Dynamism, Higher Ed | Byrne Hobart

Trump V2: Tariffs, American Dynamism, Higher Ed | Byrne Hobart

Sunday, 20th April 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:00

upstream listeners, today we're sharing my

0:02

conversation with Byrne Hobart, recorded earlier

0:04

this week. We explore the economic

0:06

consequences of Trump's tariffs, examine

0:08

open AI's latest innovations and their implications

0:10

for AI's future, and discuss

0:12

the potential transformation of white collar

0:14

work. Please enjoy. Last

0:31

week we didn't get to discuss the

0:33

market and the economy shifting rapidly

0:35

as a result of Trump's tariffs even

0:37

though we discussed them before at

0:40

a high level. What do

0:42

you make of the last couple weeks of

0:44

market activity and what if anything should

0:46

we learn from it in terms of what

0:48

it means going forward? Yeah, so I

0:50

think that part of what we learned is

0:52

that there's this weird You know,

0:54

I think one of the first ways to look

0:56

at this is to compare the first and second

0:58

Trump administrations because one the things that was going

1:01

on in the first Trump administration was that between

1:03

non -Trumpie Republicans and just Democrats, it was

1:05

really hard for Trump to do a lot

1:07

of the things that he kind of

1:09

impulsively wanted to do. And there

1:11

was also just not a ton

1:13

of long -term planning from the

1:16

Trump Republicans on exactly what they

1:18

wanted to do. So there

1:20

was just a natural level

1:22

of ambient chaos throughout that first

1:24

administration, and my assumption was

1:26

that we'd see pretty much the

1:28

same thing the second time.

1:30

But it turns out that a

1:32

lot of people spent the

1:34

years from about 2021 to early 2025

1:36

figuring out exactly what it is

1:38

that they'd want to do. And

1:40

so you had this spree of

1:43

executive orders right at the beginning,

1:45

and a lot of them were just getting

1:47

the high notes on things that Trump

1:49

had always said he wanted to do and

1:52

had really gotten around to doing and

1:54

kind of looked like, you know, just from

1:56

the neutral standpoint of does this administration

1:58

have its act together? Do they have coherent

2:00

goals that they're actually trying to pursue

2:02

in a way that makes sense? It

2:04

kind of looked like they really scaled

2:06

things up. And then the tariffs were

2:08

one of the first cases where it

2:10

was just this kind of last minute

2:13

sort of spontaneous decision. And

2:15

one of the reasons we know that is

2:17

that there were a couple blow -by -blow

2:19

articles in different publications. New York

2:21

Times, Wall Street Journal, I think Politico also

2:23

had one that just talks through, here's

2:25

how this process actually came about, that Trump

2:27

had other options. He went with the

2:30

most aggressive and kind of bluntest one. And,

2:32

you know, one of the things that

2:34

stood out there was just this administration is

2:36

suddenly as leaky as the first Trump

2:38

administration. So in some ways, it is like

2:40

this high watermark for state capacity Trumpism.

2:42

in that he did actually implement this tariff

2:45

thing that he'd been talking about for

2:47

decades. And at another

2:49

level, it was the last gas

2:51

of state capacity Trumpism because... that

2:53

some of the earlier Trump moves

2:55

seemed to work was that some

2:57

very smart heterodox right -wing person from

2:59

the think tank world was coming

3:01

up with exactly the plan that

3:03

they would use on immigration or

3:06

on, you know, how higher education

3:08

is funded or whatever. And then

3:10

they just implemented day one and

3:12

it's a shock and awe thing.

3:14

And then with tariffs, presumably

3:16

there were such glands, they

3:18

all apparently got torn up and

3:20

discarded. And now the administration

3:22

is trying to negotiate other deals.

3:25

But what it looks like is that

3:27

Trump does react when the market goes

3:29

down, if it goes down enough. And

3:31

he has enough people in his orbit

3:33

to tell him this is actually a

3:35

disaster and that the only reason the

3:37

market's not down more is that everyone

3:39

thinks that he'll back down. And one

3:41

of the problems is this actually creates

3:43

a really strong incentive for China in

3:45

particular to do things that make the

3:47

US equity market go down. So that's

3:49

not good. We now have this. this

3:51

situation where, you know, one country that

3:54

is much more centralized, much more top

3:56

down and has far weaker checks and

3:58

balances is able to deploy its economic

4:00

power in order to make things difficult

4:02

for the US. And the US just

4:04

doesn't have the same capacity to reciprocate,

4:06

although there is a lot that we

4:08

can do. So yeah, that that kind

4:10

of setup is just not good. And

4:12

then yeah, you look at the market

4:14

and you kind of see roughly what

4:16

you would expect to see given that

4:19

there was general bad news expected and

4:21

the specific bad news was worse than

4:23

expected where stocks go down volatility goes

4:25

up. And one of the things that

4:27

you saw at that time, which there

4:29

are a couple explanations for is that

4:32

treasury rates went up. And so In

4:34

general, since about 1998, it has been

4:36

very reliable that when stocks are down, treasuries

4:38

outperform, and that if you want to

4:40

have a more balanced, you know, a kind

4:42

of safe and not perfectly cyclical portfolio,

4:44

you have a mix of stocks and bonds,

4:46

and usually one of those trades is

4:48

winning when the other one isn't, which as

4:50

we were kind of reminded of, like

4:52

this was always theoretically true, but it was

4:54

good to get a bracing reminder of

4:56

this in 2022, that only works if inflation

4:58

is low. Because when inflation is low,

5:01

that means that when the economy slows down,

5:03

central banks just want to eject a

5:05

lot of liquidity to speed things up. And

5:07

that tends to push rates down. But

5:09

when inflation is high, they can't automatically

5:11

always do that. They have to consider

5:13

whether they're actually pushing price levels up

5:15

more than they're pushing growth up. So

5:18

it that weakens the correlation. And there

5:20

is a level at which tariffs are

5:22

just inflationary. They are a tax their

5:24

tax that shows up in terms of

5:26

higher prices paid by consumers. So straightforwardly

5:28

inflationary. If you offset that tax with

5:30

a tax cut, you now have higher

5:33

consumer prices and a little bit less

5:35

revenue for the federal government because of

5:37

the deadweight loss. And so to keep

5:39

US standards of living flat, you actually

5:41

do need to do some inflationary things.

5:43

But then the other piece is that

5:45

There's a narrative that the US dollar

5:48

will no longer be the reserve currency.

5:50

I think that to the extent that

5:52

that's true, it is just, it takes

5:54

way, way longer than frankly, than one

5:56

president's term to actually put that into

5:58

effect. But also that, that doesn't seem

6:01

to be the big driver of treasuries

6:03

moving. You know, we'll have to see

6:05

as, as different data from different countries

6:07

comes out, but it doesn't seem like

6:09

there are that many countries that are

6:11

just mass panic liquidating treasuries. Because again,

6:13

they seem to think, and they're probably

6:15

right, that a lot of this tariff

6:17

stuff will be reversed and that they

6:19

shouldn't make these long -term changes to their

6:21

plans just based on short -term tariff

6:23

considerations. But one of the things to

6:25

consider is that if Trump gets his

6:27

way, then countries that were

6:29

running a trade surplus with the US

6:31

will have to buy American made goods

6:33

to offset that. And what they bought

6:35

instead was treasuries. And so even if

6:37

Trump does actually negotiate the deal of

6:40

his dreams with all of these countries

6:42

and they're all buying American gas turbines

6:44

and medical equipment and planes and weapons

6:46

and LNG and soybeans and whatever else,

6:48

that means they're not buying our treasury

6:50

bonds. So in that case, treasuries should

6:52

go down. And also if Trump just

6:55

does a tariff and offsets some of

6:57

the impact with attacks, that's also inflationary.

6:59

So treasuries go down. The scenario

7:01

where treasuries actually outperform right now is

7:03

one where Tariffs are mostly completely or

7:05

completely unwound. We do mostly return to

7:07

the status quo, but we return to

7:09

the status quo having gone through this

7:11

very disruptive period where markets went down

7:14

and a lot of capital expenditure plans,

7:16

both in the corporate sector, the private

7:18

sector were deferred and everyone's a bit

7:20

more nervous. So they're saving a bit

7:22

more money. In other words, the,

7:24

if there's a recession, but it's kind

7:27

of a, it's a sort of separation

7:29

of powers recession where one way it

7:31

would happen, because I don't think it's

7:33

that likely that Trump just completely blanks

7:35

and says, Yeah, I accidentally made a

7:37

series of gigantic mistakes over the last

7:39

several weeks and they're all my fault.

7:41

The main way that that happens is

7:43

through Congress of the courts, which means

7:45

that in the end, treasuries are actually

7:47

this really interesting bet on the future

7:49

constitutional structure of the US. So if

7:52

you are a believer in a strong

7:54

executive branch, for better or for worse,

7:56

then you think that treasury yields go

7:58

up. And if you are a believer

8:00

in separation of powers, then you probably

8:02

expect a recession, but it's kind of

8:04

a dash to bullet recession and you

8:06

expect Treasury, Treasury yields to go down.

8:08

So that's where we are on that

8:10

side. Another piece of the Treasury market,

8:12

though, is that one of the big

8:14

trades that a number of large hedge

8:17

funds do is the Treasury basis trade,

8:19

which is basically betting on the gap

8:21

between Treasury futures and the actual bonds

8:23

themselves. And In some ways, this is

8:25

just the simplest possible trade because you

8:27

can look at the value of treasuries

8:29

applied by futures, you look at the

8:31

value of treasuries that you actually buy,

8:33

you look at how much you have

8:35

to pay to finance them, how much

8:37

capital you have to put up, and

8:39

you can calculate very straightforwardly what your

8:42

return is on buy the treasury, sell

8:44

the future, and then either exit that

8:46

trade at some point if the price

8:48

is converged or just when the futures

8:50

reach their expiration date, you have either

8:52

rolled onto the next set of futures

8:54

or you just exit the trade, like

8:56

you deliver your futures to close out

8:58

the short, or you deliver your bond

9:00

to close out the short futures position.

9:02

And this trade, it is kind of

9:04

like a, at one level, really, really

9:07

simple trade. At another level, you can

9:09

do some more complicated things with it

9:11

because not all bonds are created equal.

9:13

And there are different times when you

9:15

might adjust your position size, et cetera.

9:17

So there's like, there's room to do

9:19

interesting stuff there, but The main way

9:21

that it seems to work is that

9:23

if you are a gigantic hedge fund

9:25

and you do a lot of business

9:27

with every major bank and you are

9:29

constantly negotiating the terms of what you

9:32

borrow from them, what you

9:34

would often want to do is be able

9:36

to borrow larger amounts of money than

9:38

you really need and on better terms than

9:40

you really need, you know, have a

9:42

lot of essentially dry powder. And if you

9:44

have that dry powder, why not put

9:46

it into a very a trade that can

9:48

be very straightforward, like the basis trade

9:50

and just take advantage of that. So some

9:52

of what could be happening is that

9:54

some of the funds that have been doing

9:56

that, they have other ways they can

9:58

use their liquidity. So they are gradually reducing

10:00

their exposure to that trade. I don't

10:02

know for sure, but it is a plausible

10:04

explanation for how rates are moving right

10:06

now. So that is another piece. And then

10:08

we can finally move to what everyone

10:10

means when they talk about the market, which

10:12

is the stock market. So stocks had

10:14

some of their worst three -day stretches in

10:16

a very long time, their worst one -day

10:18

performances in a really long time. And

10:21

I thought the most interesting

10:23

thing there was anytime any kind

10:25

of asset moves a lot,

10:27

people will make jokes about how

10:29

the market's not efficient. And

10:31

these jokes have varying levels of

10:33

seriousness. And I think pretty

10:35

much anyone who's discussing market efficiency in

10:37

a serious way is discussing it as this

10:39

sort of directionally true thing, but not

10:41

as this completely ironclad principle where every price

10:43

is always and everywhere the exact value

10:45

of the asset in question. Because, you know,

10:48

you can always just create any fake

10:50

trade and immediately prove that that's not true.

10:52

Like you can log into your brokerage

10:54

account and look at something we traded company

10:56

wait till the market is closed. So

10:58

it has a wide bid as spread and

11:00

then You could if you felt like

11:02

it buy 100 shares at some price that

11:04

is well wildly off the market. And

11:06

then obviously that price is not the efficient

11:08

market price like that the valuation for

11:10

that company based on your 100 share trade

11:12

is not the true worth of that

11:14

company. So it's never strictly true but I

11:16

think. I think it is actually worth

11:18

talking about what market efficiency means in different

11:20

dimensions when you look at a really

11:22

volatile period like this. And especially when you

11:25

look at things like market rallying on

11:27

the rumor of a 90 day pause and

11:29

then market ripping on the fact of

11:31

a 90 day pause and then market being

11:33

choppy as that pause kind of gets

11:35

gets squished around a little bit in terms

11:37

of what it actually means and to

11:39

whom it applies. And as people

11:41

also digest the possibility that the

11:43

US will not in fact be able

11:45

to negotiate dozens of bilateral trade

11:48

agreements in a three month period, given

11:50

that those agreements typically take many

11:52

years of negotiation to actually get right

11:54

instead. And so the

11:56

way that I look at that volatility

11:58

and especially the volatility around things

12:00

like there's a rumor stocks rip, you

12:02

know, the value of the S &P

12:04

rises by several trillion dollars and

12:06

immediately comes back down. The way I'd

12:08

look at that is that when

12:10

the market is volatile, the price of

12:12

liquidity is higher. And one

12:14

of the measures of the price of liquidity

12:16

is how much stocks move when you

12:19

buy a given amount. So in a market

12:21

that is efficient with respect to prices,

12:23

you would not actually expect these huge swings

12:25

in volatility, or you'd expect smaller swings

12:27

in volatility because the world is more uncertain,

12:29

but it's not, it's not, you know,

12:31

trillions of dollars of intraday fluctuations more uncertain,

12:33

just. more uncertain than usual. But if

12:35

you think of volatility as something for which

12:37

there's a market and that volatility or

12:39

if you think of liquidity as something for

12:41

which there's a market and that liquidity

12:44

is expensive when the situation is really uncertain

12:46

and when whoever takes the other side

12:48

of your trade knows that there could be

12:50

some huge news story that they got

12:52

a fraction of a second too late and

12:54

that they try not to make a

12:56

bad trade. In a case like that, stocks

12:58

should actually move pretty massively on fairly

13:00

small, fairly insignificant news flow. So I wrote

13:02

a couple pieces kind of touching on

13:04

that from different angles over the last week

13:07

or two, including just one look at

13:09

kind of why the markets crash a lot

13:11

faster than they rise. Because if you

13:13

go back and look at the best single

13:15

day updates in the S &P 500's history,

13:17

They are not good times. They're not

13:19

times that you associate with, it was a

13:21

great time to own stocks. Like a

13:23

lot of the best days in the S

13:25

&P history are in the 1930s, early 1930s,

13:27

when everything was falling apart. Some of

13:30

them are in spring of 2020. Again, things

13:32

were falling apart somewhere in 2008. And

13:34

then you have one, I think from 1987,

13:36

a couple of days after the crash.

13:38

So pretty much anytime someone is fully invested

13:40

on one of the best days in

13:42

S &P history, it's because they were fully

13:44

invested on one of the worst days in

13:46

S &P history too. That's

13:49

just that is another reflection of

13:51

volatility gets really really high and that

13:53

means that whereas like if you

13:55

look at Periods where the market just

13:57

generally did well like the 1950s

13:59

You don't have a lot of crazy

14:01

days in part because just the

14:04

flow of news during good during a

14:06

good economy is Things are always

14:08

just slightly like things were always looking

14:10

good and they're always looking slightly

14:12

better like the the big positive news

14:14

1955 will be something like Ford

14:16

made a slightly larger, slightly more expensive

14:18

car and fortunately gas prices are

14:20

extremely stable and therefore people will buy

14:23

this slightly more expensive car. So

14:25

this is slightly good news, but

14:27

it's not world -changingly good. The world -changing

14:29

news is almost always really bad

14:31

news, especially for large publicly traded companies.

14:33

So if you look at something

14:35

like AI, it is good

14:37

news for just the economy and

14:39

for human flourishing in general that we

14:42

can offload a lot of intelligence

14:44

to machines. It's also really, really

14:46

bad news for any company where they

14:48

have like this implicit balance sheet position of

14:50

we have a lot of people together,

14:52

we have built all these tools for coordinating

14:54

them and getting them to do fairly

14:56

low value added white collar work and now

14:58

that work can be done. Orders of

15:01

magnitude more cheaply and more quickly and we

15:03

can check the work more easily, etc. So

15:05

it often means like it's good news

15:08

for the world and then. the profits

15:10

of the public companies that are a

15:12

large proportion of the market are sometimes

15:14

impaired. We're actually just very fortunate that

15:16

this is a case where there's a

15:18

labor saving technology that is primarily being

15:20

built and deployed by very large cap

15:22

companies that are very profitable and that

15:24

are able to convince their investors that

15:26

this will be profitable too. You could

15:28

totally imagine a case where there is

15:30

an AI driven bear market because we

15:32

just have a slightly different configuration of

15:34

what companies are large cap companies and

15:36

what companies aren't. We'll

15:39

continue our interview in a moment after a word

15:41

from our sponsors. Well,

15:58

if you act by May 31st,

16:00

Oracle Cloud Infrastructure can help you do

16:02

just that. OCI is

16:04

the next generation cloud design for

16:06

every workload, where you can run

16:08

any application, including any AI projects,

16:10

faster and more securely for less. In

16:13

fact, Oracle has a special promotion where you

16:15

can cut your cloud bill in half when you

16:17

switch to OCI. The savings are

16:19

real. On average, OCI costs

16:21

50 % less for compute, 70 %

16:24

less for storage, and 80 %

16:26

less for networking. Join

16:28

Modal, SkyGavs Animation, and

16:30

today's innovative AI tech companies

16:32

who upgrade OCI and saved. Offer

16:35

only for new US customers

16:37

with a minimum financial commitment.

16:39

See if you qualify for

16:41

half off at oracle .com slash

16:43

turpentine. That's oracle .com slash

16:45

turpentine. In

16:50

an age of AI and big data,

16:53

your personal information has become one of the

16:55

most valuable commodities. Data brokers are

16:57

the silent players in this new economy,

16:59

building detailed profiles of your digital life and

17:01

selling them to the highest bidder. But

17:03

data breaches happening frequently, these profiles

17:05

aren't just fueling spam, they're

17:07

enabling identity theft and putting your financial

17:10

security at risk. But what if

17:12

there's a way you could opt out of that system entirely? Incogny

17:14

is a service that ensures your personal data

17:17

remains private and secure. They

17:19

handle everything from sending removal requests to

17:21

managing any pushback from data brokers. What

17:24

I trust most about Incogny is how

17:26

it provides ongoing protection. Once you're

17:28

set up, it continuously monitors and ensures

17:30

your information stays off the market. Want

17:32

to extend that peace of mind to your loved ones?

17:35

Incogny's family and friends plan lets you

17:37

protect up to four additional people under

17:39

one subscription. Take control of

17:41

your digital privacy today. Use

17:43

code upstream at the link below

17:45

and get 60 % off an annual

17:47

plan. Again, that's in Cogni .com

17:50

slash Upstreet. It's

17:55

fascinating. There seems to be

17:57

some, you know, as euphemism, you

17:59

know, confused messaging over whether

18:02

the goal is to improve our

18:04

negotiating position in order to

18:06

have more free trade. Actually, you

18:08

know, tariffs in support of

18:10

having other countries block their preexisting

18:12

tariffs. which is a different

18:14

argument than saying, no, we actually

18:16

need these tariffs to last because

18:18

we either need the revenue or

18:21

we need to reindustrialize. And

18:23

so supporters of the sort of

18:25

policies are basically explaining both arguments,

18:27

even though they seem to be

18:29

somewhat contradictory. And that's perhaps,

18:31

I'm assuming that there are people in Trump's

18:33

camp and you alluded to a, or

18:35

linked to a Tanner Greer post about sort

18:37

of different factions in Trump's camp. who

18:40

think differently. Yeah. So I think one

18:42

piece of this is just that to the

18:44

extent that tariffs are actually negotiating tool. It

18:46

is just going to like anytime you do

18:48

that you you open yourself up to some

18:50

level of embarrassment because you if you are

18:52

a good negotiator you do not get what

18:54

you said you wanted. Like that is the

18:56

whole point of being a good negotiator is

18:58

that you got what you did secretly want

19:00

but the other side feels like you compromised

19:02

and that you you actually met them halfway.

19:05

So yeah to the extent that

19:07

Trump is actually doing a

19:09

really, really clever five -dimensional chess

19:11

thing here, then yeah, he's not going

19:13

to get all the things he says he wanted. And

19:16

I think that some of the messaging just, like

19:18

it is in Trump's interest regardless

19:20

of what the end goal is for

19:22

the stated, for the implied end

19:24

goal to be that the US is

19:26

manufacturing a lot more stuff and

19:29

that China in particular is manufacturing a

19:31

lot less. Now, there are

19:33

plenty of configurations of the world where

19:35

that doesn't happen or happens to only

19:37

a very small degree or the

19:39

US shifts what it manufactures but doesn't

19:41

actually increase manufacturing up with that much

19:43

in the aggregate and the US

19:45

still ends up better off. But some

19:47

of that, you know, some of these

19:49

goals, it is again, like if I'm

19:51

sure that there were really sophisticated

19:53

plans for particular parts of particular supply

19:55

chains that could realistically be moved to

19:58

the US and other parts that

20:00

could be moved to US aligned companies.

20:02

and other things that we could do

20:04

to sort of box China in

20:06

where we find different countries or collections

20:08

of countries. that can in the aggregate

20:10

mimic some of China's comparative advantages. And

20:13

in some cases we just won't like

20:15

it is you just can't really mimic the

20:17

density of the the social network that

20:19

is Shenzhen in addition to all of the

20:21

all of the equipment and all of

20:23

the people and all of the infrastructure. Like

20:25

that part just has to get built

20:27

over time. And if not everything is co

20:29

-located in the same city or the same

20:31

set of cities, then it is going

20:34

to run less efficiently. And in that case,

20:36

what we're doing is basically buying insurance. So

20:38

if we take a supply chain

20:40

that was all China and move it

20:42

to, it's 80 % not China. And

20:45

you have four or five different countries

20:47

that each have a big chunk of it,

20:49

but nobody has a majority of it.

20:51

then that's just a world where a lot

20:53

more intermediate goods spend a lot more

20:55

time on ships. And there a lot

20:57

more cases where people are trying to coordinate something,

20:59

but they all speak different languages. And

21:02

so there are miscommunications and things like

21:04

there, there is a lot of noise and

21:06

friction in that. And one difference between

21:08

that world and the, the continued reliance on

21:10

China status quo world is that in

21:12

the latter. You can have situations where the

21:14

US can no longer buy drones or

21:16

the US can no longer buy GPUs There

21:18

are there are a lot of things

21:21

you know the GPU supply chain like you

21:23

know We don't directly buy them from

21:25

China But we buy them from places that

21:27

are very close to China and at

21:29

places that are if you look at a

21:31

map in China that are part of

21:33

China so definitely There is definitely a case

21:35

for saying that if the US were

21:37

spending a little bit more on some of

21:39

its strategically important imports, but also

21:42

knew that those imports would still be

21:44

available if there were conflict with China,

21:46

that the US would be better off.

21:48

And also a conflict with China would

21:50

be less likely in a scenario where

21:52

China can't actually, can't immediately remove the

21:54

US's access to some critical inputs. But

21:57

yeah, we'll we'll see how the

21:59

how the tariff regime and how

22:02

the negotiations evolve to get us

22:04

either in that direction or maybe

22:06

back to the status quo or

22:08

maybe to some world where there

22:10

are more barriers to trade and

22:12

The US out of necessity is

22:14

manufacturing more but I think in

22:16

that world There's also the question

22:18

of which companies would actually want

22:20

to invest in the US and

22:22

we we do know that there

22:24

is a set of policies that

22:26

can get companies to invest in

22:28

the US because private sector spending

22:30

on fixed capital did actually rocket

22:33

over the last couple of years,

22:35

partly because of AI -induced demand,

22:37

but also because of this targeted

22:39

subsidies for particular strategic industries. Some

22:41

more strategic than others, but it

22:43

did work. And I think that

22:45

it's actually harder to credibly engage

22:47

in a strategy like that. If

22:49

you wanted something like the IRA

22:51

or CHIPS Act, but just targeting,

22:53

say, defense and dual use technologies

22:55

that could be applied to defense. I

22:58

think people would be telling you like

23:00

we want cash upfront before we build

23:02

our drone factory in Texas. We don't

23:04

want the promise of future subsidies because

23:06

you had just promised this great trade

23:08

rearrangement and then you unpromised it and

23:11

then repromise parts of it and so

23:13

on. So we just can't really underwrite

23:15

a long -term investment in the US

23:17

on the basis of the strategy that

23:19

changes day to day. There's

23:21

a level of subsidies where you can underwrite

23:23

that, but that's also a level of

23:25

subsidies where you are subsidizing grift. So if

23:28

you pay people upfront enough money that

23:30

it is worthwhile to build a drone factory

23:32

in the US, there are people who

23:34

are going to take the money and do

23:36

other things with it. And this is

23:38

actually a problem that China had too. They

23:40

had this massive scandal with chipfab in

23:42

Wuhan, actually, where a lot of the money

23:44

seems to have just disappeared, as well

23:46

as some of the people involved. And it's

23:49

unclear if they disappeared themselves or got

23:51

disappeared. But either way, when there is aggressive

23:53

industrial policy that tries to pay upfront

23:55

because there's some policy expectation and stability, it

23:57

does select for some fraud. All

24:00

in past week, had a fascinating debate

24:02

between sacks and Chamath in one

24:04

hand and Ezra Klein and Larry Summers.

24:06

On the other hand, it was

24:08

kind of, you know, sort of a

24:10

representative of a broader debate. It

24:12

seems like, you know, most people can

24:14

agree that this has been handled

24:16

not super well from an execution perspective,

24:18

but, you know, but people on

24:21

the writers saying, Hey, directionally,

24:23

something like this or some

24:25

people had to happen. because

24:27

the current situation was

24:29

untenable, and this is

24:31

short -term pain for

24:33

long -term gain, either as

24:35

it relates to our

24:37

need to reindustrialize, or

24:39

they make some economic arguments.

24:42

My guess is that the

24:44

geopolitical foreign policy arguments are

24:46

stronger than the economic arguments,

24:48

but I'm curious to hear

24:50

your reaction. curious to hear

24:52

your take on the idea

24:54

of... something like this directly

24:56

need to happen or did

24:58

Larry Summers position of, hey,

25:02

free trade is actually this sort of

25:04

error that we had was actually

25:06

very successful for us. But he would

25:08

dispute the Zeyhan idea that we

25:10

were sort of subsidizing an order that

25:12

didn't make sense for us anymore.

25:14

Well, I think that there are there

25:16

are definitely parts of the free

25:18

trade system that like absolutely, you know,

25:20

the free trade system works really

25:22

well for the US in terms of

25:24

GDP growth, and it worked really,

25:26

really well for a lot of the

25:28

developing world also in terms of

25:31

GDP growth and. The question is more

25:33

about what is like, is there

25:35

a long term goal where everything kind

25:37

of equilibriates and equilibriates at US

25:39

standards of living or equilibriates at some

25:41

other standard of living and are,

25:43

is the US willing to defer consumption

25:45

in order to preserve its, in

25:47

order to preserve industries that are high

25:49

value, high margin, have a high

25:51

upfront cost and a lot of uncertainty

25:53

and that probably just don't come

25:55

back if we lose them. And I

25:57

think that's That's the piece where

25:59

it gets trickier, where if you have

26:02

a planned economy, but with some

26:04

capitalist characteristics and the level of capitalism,

26:06

the economy can fluctuate opportunistically, but

26:08

the state is still able to direct

26:10

a lot of resources towards the

26:12

goals that it cares about, then they

26:14

can do catch up growth very

26:16

straightforwardly. And that was the story for

26:18

a lot of the East Asian

26:20

economic miracle countries like Japan and then

26:22

later Korea, much less Taiwan, but

26:24

they were kind of attached to Japan

26:26

in a way that let them

26:28

sort of free ride on some of

26:30

what Japan was doing. But part

26:33

of the approach in both Japan and

26:35

Korea was we're going to subsidize

26:37

industries that lower the cost and increase

26:39

the pace of iteration in higher

26:41

value added industries. So we know that

26:43

if we dump enough resources into

26:45

steel, we'll have really cheap steel, we'll

26:47

be able to make cars, we'll

26:49

be able to make low cost export

26:51

goods. utensils and just

26:53

like steel, you know, simple steel

26:55

components and simple, you know, simple industrial

26:57

components, but we can also move

26:59

up the value chain once we've built

27:01

that. And anytime they're doing that,

27:03

you can, you can have this period

27:05

where a US manufacturer who used

27:08

to produce goods for many different levels

27:10

of that value chain, you know,

27:12

some really low margin commoditized stuff, some

27:14

really high margin, very specialized stuff.

27:16

as they, as they're able to outsource

27:18

some of that or as they

27:20

stop producing some low margin stuff because

27:22

there is overseas competition, they actually

27:24

end up with a higher margin business

27:26

that has more, more competitive defensibility

27:28

on its own. But then they can

27:30

end up in a case where

27:32

it turns out that it was actually

27:34

valuable for them to have some

27:36

of this lower margin, lower value added

27:38

stuff, specifically because it just increased

27:40

their overall economic footprint, meant that more

27:42

people were working with the company,

27:44

the company was working with more suppliers,

27:46

it had more scale advantages, was

27:48

able to promote more talent internally. It

27:51

is really hard to have

27:53

this fluid way to promote

27:55

a lot of really smart

27:57

people within smart and effective

27:59

people within a given organization

28:01

if that organization's main job

28:03

is to slowly shrink into

28:05

its highest margin activities rather

28:07

than continuously growing at all

28:09

levels. So you can

28:11

kind of look at Amazon as

28:13

a sort of like taking Japanese industrial

28:15

policy and just doing it on

28:18

a private sector basis. within one

28:20

company where they do think very long

28:22

term, they are very happy to find something

28:24

where the only limitation is their willingness

28:26

to put a lot of capital into something

28:28

and lose money for a while. And

28:30

then they just continuously scale it and try

28:32

to ramp up the quality to whatever

28:34

the acceptable level is and then ramp up

28:36

the monetization continuously beyond that. And as

28:39

long as what they're doing after that is

28:41

reinvesting that in more of the same,

28:43

then they're able to sustain that growth

28:45

for a very long time. But as they do

28:47

that, they end up having a very strong negotiating

28:49

position with respect to many of the companies they

28:51

do business with. And it's just, you

28:53

know, over the last 20 years, it's always been

28:55

better in the long run to be Amazon than

28:57

to be someone who was doing business with Amazon.

29:00

In any case, where Amazon was the

29:02

main dependency and the bigger they

29:04

get, the more they are the main

29:06

dependency for other other companies. So

29:08

I think that that's, you know, that.

29:10

in that framework, you basically want

29:12

to have some way for either companies

29:14

or countries to subsidize some low

29:16

value added compliments to the high value

29:18

added stuff that they can export

29:20

competitively globally. And if you lose

29:23

that, it is just much more likely that

29:25

you end up eventually losing the high margin,

29:27

high return on equity things that were just

29:29

that last layer because someone else has done

29:31

the entire process that you did to get

29:33

up to that point. And they also know

29:35

what that point looks like. And they also

29:37

know what the prices for those products are.

29:39

And as they get closer to being able

29:41

to build them, they also know more about

29:43

the margins. So I think

29:46

for free trade to be this really,

29:48

for people to be very long

29:50

-term optimistic on free trade with

29:52

sort of protectionist characteristics on

29:54

the part of other countries, you

29:56

have to be optimistic that

29:58

the US will just have some

30:00

natural advantage in doing in

30:03

doing high margin things and that we don't

30:05

actually need a lot of expertise in the

30:07

lower margin stuff in order to achieve that.

30:10

And I think there's a kind of

30:12

coherent model of the world where

30:14

that is actually true and where as

30:16

the US does less manufacturing, we

30:18

get more and more specialized in other

30:20

things and because we're more specialized

30:22

in those things and we have critical

30:24

mass. It's hard for anyone to

30:26

compete with us. And it does seem

30:28

to be true for both consumer -facing

30:30

software and business -facing software. It is

30:32

just really hard for other countries

30:34

to build and scale companies the way

30:36

that you can in the US.

30:38

But that also means that those same

30:40

companies are vulnerable to a world

30:42

where they're tightly integrated hardware and software

30:44

bundles. And at that point, the

30:46

companies that are good at the capital

30:48

-intensive, operationally -messing world of hardware They

30:51

already know how to do that,

30:53

and U .S. companies would have

30:55

to re -learn it. Let's get deeper

30:57

into that. This is a big

30:59

bet on American dynamism. Say more

31:01

about what you foresee as to

31:03

our opportunities and challenges in sort

31:05

of reindustrializing and what are you

31:07

predicting or expecting in terms of

31:09

how it's going to play out.

31:11

Yeah, so I think the US,

31:14

we have like our general disadvantage in

31:16

all of this is very high labor

31:18

costs, and there's an ambiguous disadvantage in

31:20

terms of regulatory uncertainty where the old

31:22

regulatory uncertainty was micro level, which is

31:24

you want to build something, you have

31:27

no idea how long it will take,

31:29

you have no idea how much money

31:31

you will spend dealing with every single

31:33

holdout, and we give a lot of

31:35

people veto power and the power to

31:37

delay things. We have some

31:40

rules that I think were very

31:42

well intended, but are

31:44

open themselves up to being manipulated. So

31:46

I'm just a piece of the New York Times a couple

31:48

of months back talking about endangered species. And

31:51

there is this kind of dark model

31:53

where if you take a species

31:55

that's not endangered, and then you figure

31:57

out, you find two subpopulations, you

31:59

split it up into subpopulations based on

32:01

some unique trait. And you're able

32:03

to get each one of those classified

32:05

as a species well now you

32:07

have two species and they both have

32:09

smaller populations and so if you

32:11

divide them finally enough you can eventually

32:13

get your way you can define

32:15

your way to an endangered species and

32:17

then someone can't build the factory

32:19

of the dam or whatever they want

32:21

to build. And there there seems

32:23

to be some appeal to doing that.

32:25

So the US had that that

32:27

kind of that kind of obstacle to

32:29

reindustrializing that actually seems to be

32:31

going away under Trump. And it has

32:33

been seamlessly replaced with the macro

32:35

uncertainty of we just have no idea.

32:37

how US products will be priced

32:39

relative to products made elsewhere in the

32:41

world, because we just don't know

32:43

what the tariff situation will look like.

32:45

But I think there are some

32:47

categories. Like in drones, it is just

32:49

kind of weird that for military

32:51

purposes, the US does do drones. But

32:53

for law enforcement purposes, there's

32:55

a lot less of the US presence. And

32:57

that seems like a straightforward place where

32:59

we can look at what's going on in

33:01

Ukraine and say that drones are going

33:03

to be a pretty important part of the

33:05

world, we can look at just the

33:07

general history of military equipment and say that

33:09

it is good to have dual use

33:11

producers. It is good to have companies that

33:14

can, from year to year, make a

33:16

lot of money selling passenger planes and can

33:18

occasionally scale up their production of military

33:20

aircraft. Or we look at the US auto

33:22

industry, which got huge over the course

33:24

of the 1920s and say that it was

33:26

actually, from the perspective of a country

33:28

that needed to produce a lot of tanks

33:30

and jeeps, it was really, really convenient

33:32

that... we had a lot of people who

33:34

were in the business of putting tires

33:36

on things that move and getting them off

33:38

the assembly line as quickly and cheaply

33:40

as possible. So I think

33:42

that something like drones, drones makes a

33:45

lot of sense. I think that going

33:47

through the list of inputs for like

33:49

going through the list of raw materials

33:51

inputs is probably more of like a

33:53

check the box thing. And it

33:55

is still, it is annoying to me that China

33:57

is able to disrupt supply of rare because

33:59

They are, and I think this is

34:01

more widely known than it was a few

34:03

years ago, like they're not actually rare.

34:05

That's more a branding thing. What is rare

34:07

is the facilities to process them, and

34:09

China has invested in that. And that seems

34:11

like this is actually a case study

34:13

in why controlling your supply chain is strategic,

34:15

is that China can just tell the

34:18

US that you don't get any rare earths

34:20

for a while. There

34:22

have been a couple inputs like

34:24

that that got disrupted during Russia's invasion

34:26

of Ukraine. And it turned out

34:28

that a lot of the companies that

34:30

depended on those inputs were actually

34:32

reading the headlines and knew that this

34:34

was a risk and had done

34:36

some stockpiling beforehand and did think of

34:38

alternative sources. But on a country

34:40

level, it actually seems like a very

34:42

useful thing to do. So I

34:44

think that looking at it from the

34:46

perspective of we take our currently

34:48

locally competitive products. So planes, medical equipment,

34:50

LNG, and gas turbines,

34:52

and some other kind of

34:54

industrial capital goods. And we

34:56

start iterating through the supply chain for

34:58

those and look at one, what are

35:00

the cases where we depend a lot

35:03

on imports from one country, which is

35:05

usually going to be China, and then

35:07

look at where else we could depend

35:09

on imports from or whether or not

35:11

we could onshore that. And if it

35:13

is the case that on ensuring that

35:15

it requires some subsidies, but not immense

35:17

subsidies. And you want to

35:19

subsidize the factory so that the return

35:21

on investment goes from 5 % to 10

35:23

% and not you want to subsidize

35:25

it. The return goes from negative 50 %

35:27

to 10%. If we find cases where

35:29

it is that incremental subsidy that actually

35:31

makes it worth doing, then we can

35:34

look at what else is downstream from

35:36

that input and then look. Again, is

35:38

there a case where it is almost

35:40

profitable for the US to build this?

35:42

And if so, we might want to

35:44

subsidize it so we can build it.

35:46

And I think that exercise actually gets

35:48

continuously easier over time as you iterate

35:50

over it because you get more used

35:53

to underwriting this kind of thing and

35:55

you also just get more visibility into

35:57

the overall supply chain as more of

35:59

it is located within the US or

36:01

at least being carefully looked at from

36:03

kind of a national security standpoint. So

36:06

I would say that I think another

36:08

piece of this is just the US

36:10

annoyingly does actually have an advantage in

36:12

just natural resource extraction. We whether whether

36:14

it is drilling oil out of the

36:16

ground or growing corn out of the

36:18

ground, you know, things that come out

36:20

of the ground, we just we have

36:22

good ground for that. So there there's

36:24

there's a different set of supply chains

36:26

there where oil oil is a very

36:28

complicated industry with a lot of very

36:30

specialized equipment, some of that is manufactured

36:32

domestically, some of that is not. And

36:34

Again, knowing what the dependencies

36:37

are, knowing which countries could

36:39

be, which countries if they are blockaded mean

36:41

that the US is impaired in its

36:43

ability to supply a lot of oil and

36:45

natural gas. It's useful stuff to know.

36:47

On the shipping side, Trump has talked about

36:49

the US ship, bringing about the US

36:51

shipbuilding industry that would be very hard to

36:54

do. China makes a lot of ships

36:56

and it takes a long time to scale

36:58

such an industry. And the US does

37:00

have allies that also produce ships. So I

37:02

think if I were if I were

37:04

building out high level industrial policy, I would

37:06

probably say we should continue outsourcing that

37:09

to countries that are actually capable of doing

37:11

it. And there may be a category

37:13

of ships like maybe your maybe a fully

37:15

autonomous ship is just such a different

37:17

design question from a ship that is crude

37:19

that you could actually just build that

37:21

supply chain from the beginning in the US.

37:24

And I think that is a case where

37:26

we should be looking at What is

37:28

the next step that hasn't scaled yet and

37:30

trying to scale that domestically? Because it's

37:33

just a whole lot easier to maintain high

37:35

market share in something than to get

37:37

the market share from zero to non -zero,

37:39

especially if someone else has already as part

37:41

of their industrial policy subsidized the early

37:43

stages of it. I think people have been

37:45

debating about related to this are who's

37:47

negatively affected more? The US or China or

37:49

who has more leverage here? Some people

37:51

say that the country with the deficits is

37:53

the one that has more of the

37:56

leverage. Who can withstand? this

37:58

sort of where we're at right now

38:00

for longer. How do you think about

38:02

this? So I think that just in

38:04

terms of the accounting, it does look

38:06

like China has the advantage in the

38:08

sense of they are not any worse

38:10

off if they sell, if they build

38:12

the same amount of stuff and instead

38:14

of buying treasury bonds, they just don't,

38:17

you know, they just dump it in

38:19

the ocean or something. Like they still

38:21

have the same level of employment. They

38:23

still have the same scaling for their

38:25

manufacturing base. And, you know, it's kind

38:27

of dumb to do that because the

38:29

Treasury bonds are a claim on future

38:31

output, future dollar denominated economic output, but

38:33

it is something where it would not

38:36

day to day affect anyone's life in

38:38

China if they were not actually selling

38:40

these goods to the US and were

38:42

just building them and throwing them away.

38:45

On the other hand, longer term, the

38:47

U .S. does have more population growth

38:49

ahead of it. The U .S. does,

38:51

you know, you can debate a

38:53

lot of the nuances on the military

38:55

stuff, and certainly the alliances that

38:57

the U .S. has are more afraid

38:59

than before. But the U .S. seems

39:01

at least positioned to survive a military

39:04

conflict with China long enough to... the

39:06

parts of its industrial base that it

39:08

needs to actually be competitive. So, you know,

39:10

in the really extreme worst case scenarios,

39:12

I think the US does okay. It's just

39:14

a really dicey situation for a while. And

39:17

China is, you know,

39:19

there was always that debate over, will

39:21

they get rich before they get

39:23

old? And they are getting old and

39:25

they're no longer getting rich at

39:27

nearly the same pace. So in some

39:29

ways, China does need to wring

39:31

what it can out of the current

39:33

system before that system. just doesn't

39:35

really serve China's interests. And they did

39:37

take their time in opening up

39:40

their financial system enough that they could

39:42

kind of globalize their own efforts

39:44

to buy claims on foreign assets in

39:46

order to pay for the livelihoods

39:48

of people who are living in China

39:50

and are at retirement age and thus

39:52

no longer working, no longer contributing

39:54

directly to the economy. And there are

39:56

a lot of those people. So

39:58

I think that China's China's it kind

40:00

of has a wobbly sort of

40:02

dominance in that sense, where they they

40:04

in the short term rely less

40:06

on the US than than the US

40:08

relies on them in terms of

40:10

standard of living. But over longer periods,

40:12

I think they are just more

40:14

dependent on there being an end market

40:16

for the kinds of goods that

40:18

a middle income country could produce because

40:20

they're not a high income country.

40:22

And it doesn't seem like they're really

40:24

on the path to being a

40:26

high income country. I think that that

40:28

is another component of US industrial

40:30

policy is that we can basically make

40:32

a list of things that are done

40:34

by Chinese companies where if you

40:36

didn't know better, you would assume that

40:38

an American or European company would

40:40

be dominant in that sector. So

40:42

I think things like very popular

40:45

consumer facing social media apps that are

40:47

used outside of China or telecom

40:49

equipment, for example. And I

40:51

think in cases like that, having a

40:53

more explicitly defensive industrial policy and saying

40:55

that These are things where we, A,

40:58

want to make sure that there are

41:00

domestic producers, and B, want to limit

41:02

the ability of China to sell these

41:04

globally. I think it does

41:06

actually make sense. That does all it

41:08

makes sense. We'll continue our

41:10

interview in a moment after a word from

41:12

our sponsors. Hey, everyone. Eric

41:15

here. In this environment, founders

41:17

need to become profitable faster and do

41:19

more with smaller teams, especially when it comes

41:21

to engineering. That's

41:23

why Sean Lanahan started Squad. a

41:25

specialized global talent firm for top engineers

41:27

that will seamlessly integrate with your org.

41:31

Squad offers rigorously vetted top 1 %

41:33

talent that will actually work hard for

41:35

you every day. Their engineers

41:37

work in your time zone, follow your processes,

41:39

and use your tools. Squad

41:41

has front -end engineers excelling in TypeScript

41:43

and React, and Next .js ready to

41:45

onboard to your team today. For

41:47

back -end, Squad engineers are experts

41:49

at Node .js, Python, Java, and a

41:51

range of other languages and frameworks. While

41:54

it may cost more than the freelancer on Upwork,

41:56

billing you for 40 hours, but working only two,

41:59

Squad offers premium quality at a fraction of the

42:01

typical cost without the headache of assessing for

42:03

skills and culture fit. Squad takes

42:05

care of sourcing, legal compliance and local

42:07

HR for global talent. Increase

42:09

your velocity without amping up burn. Visit

42:12

chewsquad .com and mention Turpentine to

42:14

skip the wait list. I

42:18

think we've been talking a lot about tariffs. I want

42:20

to make sure we get to a couple other topics

42:22

here that I'm sure will return back

42:24

to it. Open AI,

42:26

there have been some developments with the company you've

42:28

written about them. We've written about the company

42:30

a few times in the past couple of weeks.

42:33

One of them was that Sam Altman has

42:35

hinted that they are in fact going to go

42:37

open source or release an open source version. Any

42:40

commentary on this or just broader

42:42

sort of open AI developments? Of

42:44

course, they had their fundraise. You

42:46

wrote about their cap table. What

42:49

else should we talk about as opposed to open AI?

42:51

Yeah. So there's an interesting, you know,

42:53

you can look at the economics of open source

42:55

software in a couple of different ways. And as

42:57

with a lot of things, you sort of have

42:59

to, if you vary your level of cynicism, you

43:01

get to very different answers because one version of

43:03

the open source model is we're going to build

43:05

something really, really great. And we will understand, we

43:07

will build something everyone wants to use. We will

43:10

understand it really well. And therefore we will make

43:12

our money from helping other people implement our wonderful

43:14

open source thing. And that

43:16

was kind of a popular model for people

43:18

who did want to build software and share

43:21

it and also pay their rent to pay

43:23

their mortgage. But it turned out to be

43:25

a model where you are limiting a lot

43:27

of your economic upside and you're also running

43:29

what ends up being a very headcount -centric kind

43:31

of organization. So if you are in the

43:33

business of helping companies use Linux and Linux

43:35

is all free and open source, so it's

43:38

hard to directly charge for it, but you

43:40

can charge for developer hours, installing Linux and

43:42

maintaining it and so on. then you tend

43:44

to be running a company that just has

43:46

a lot of people and only grows by

43:48

hiring more of them. And I think for

43:50

some open source people, this was actually kind

43:52

of utopia, which it was basically, we have

43:55

a guaranteed job for all of our favorite

43:57

developers who also love the software we built.

43:59

And we get to spend all of our

44:01

time thinking about how to make Linux better

44:03

and how it can solve more people's problems,

44:05

et cetera. So that kind

44:07

of model did work, but another model

44:09

that is a somewhat more cynical

44:11

one, but a lot more effective is

44:13

that you build a free product

44:15

that anyone can use and then you

44:17

build a very similar product that

44:19

is paid that has better features. And

44:22

you continuously advance the quality of

44:24

the free product such that it continues

44:26

to be widely deployed. You also

44:28

continue to advance the features of the

44:30

paid product and you always you

44:32

because you can see that you just

44:34

have a lot of information on

44:36

how the product is used. You can

44:38

kind of see or at least

44:40

infer what parts of it you can

44:42

charge for. And that model seems

44:44

to work pretty well. And

44:46

if more interactions between people are

44:48

mediated by AI, then

44:50

very cheap, open models where you're

44:52

basically paying a tiny markup on just

44:55

the cost of the hardware required

44:57

to run it, those models will end

44:59

up getting used very, very widely,

45:01

especially in low value added tasks like

45:03

customer service, but also scams. Well,

45:06

once they are, if there is a slightly

45:08

better version of that same model and a

45:10

model that is built in such a way

45:12

that it understands some of the limitations and

45:14

deficiencies of the open model, then

45:16

the proliferation of that open

45:19

model ends up being a subsidy

45:21

to the closed model. And

45:23

I think this probably works a lot

45:25

better in cases where it's a domain

45:27

-specific model because you just have a

45:29

lot more control over how it gets

45:32

used and how it gets deployed. So

45:34

if you imagine someone creates an

45:36

open -weight Hagelbot. And Hagelbot's job

45:38

is that if you are

45:40

selling some product on Facebook Marketplace,

45:42

Hagelbot will handle the negotiation

45:44

for you and help you get

45:46

the best price possible. Well,

45:49

in that case, if someone buys

45:51

Hagelbot Pro at Hagelbot Pro

45:53

specifically designed to out Hagel Hagelbot,

45:55

then the fact that everyone

45:57

uses Hagelbot means that Hagelbot Pro

45:59

has this built -in locked -in

46:01

market. I would be pretty ambitious

46:04

to do that in a totally open,

46:06

you know, general purpose model kind of

46:08

way. But it does, it does seem

46:10

like that's kind of the shape of

46:12

things where it is just a lot easier

46:14

to produce a huge stream of tokens

46:16

that are all customized for the recipient. And

46:18

that means there's a much higher premium

46:20

on being able to ingest and summarize

46:22

a lot of data and to do

46:24

so in a way that's helpful to one

46:26

specific person. So it kind of ties

46:28

into their other recent feature, which is

46:30

improving memory. And this is

46:33

just a great thing for lock -in

46:35

because once you, because whichever LLM

46:37

you have the most user hours or

46:39

the most user tokens exchanged with,

46:41

that LLM knows you better. And so

46:43

it's actually able to give better

46:45

answers to your specific questions than other

46:48

LLMs. So, for example, let's

46:50

say you sometimes use LLMs to figure

46:52

out what restaurant to go to when you're

46:54

visiting a new city. If you previously

46:56

mentioned to chat GPT that you're a vegan

46:58

or your carnivore or your

47:00

kosher or whatever, then then it

47:03

will always just know that and you

47:05

won't be explaining these details or if you

47:07

have other idiosyncratic references that it's slowly

47:09

picked up on, you won't be repeatedly explaining

47:11

those details. So you end up defaulting

47:13

to whichever LLM you've used the most and

47:15

then you are, of course, when you

47:17

default to that, you're giving it more data.

47:19

And if the data is actually proving

47:21

it, then you probably end up using it

47:23

more than you otherwise kind of actually

47:25

would have. And then I forget

47:27

who pointed this out on Twitter, but

47:29

someone pointed out recently that it is possible

47:31

that this can be tied in with

47:34

a login with open AI button. And at

47:36

that point, what that means is that

47:38

it can port a lot of your preferences

47:40

over to whatever new app you're using. So

47:43

if we have that example of

47:45

you've used open it, you've used

47:47

chat GPT a lot of times

47:49

to figure out where to eat

47:51

when you're visiting a particular city.

47:53

If you log into TripAdvisor with OpenAI,

47:55

then maybe either OpenAI shares a

47:58

bunch of references with TripAdvisor, or maybe

48:00

that's a privacy violation. What actually

48:02

happens is that when you interact with

48:04

TripAdvisor, you're actually interacting with an

48:06

OpenAI layer on top of TripAdvisor, where

48:08

TripAdvisor is just the kind of

48:10

dumb API play, and it's piping in

48:12

a bunch of data. the LLM is analyzing

48:14

that data for you and then it's giving

48:16

you your rank list based on your preferences and

48:19

TripAdvisor does not actually even know what the

48:21

ranking was and what the final output was. They

48:23

just provided the data. So it

48:25

does become a way to make LLMs

48:27

more of an interface and more of

48:29

a default way for interacting with other

48:31

services. And I think that for a

48:33

lot of companies, that's just, that's something

48:35

they have to think about is that

48:37

for now, If they have some service

48:39

where the idea is they can answer

48:41

complicated questions in some specific domain because

48:43

they have a lot of the data,

48:45

which does describe, you know, describe TripAdvisor.

48:47

That's also LinkedIn. That's also GitHub, et

48:49

cetera. They do want to

48:51

have a natural language interface because that is

48:53

a way that people are now looking

48:55

for that information. But they also probably want

48:57

to think about what their business model

48:59

looks like if they are purely providing. outputs

49:01

by API as their default and that

49:03

the actual front end for the site is

49:05

basically a demo version that you would

49:07

use to learn what TripAdvisor is so that

49:09

you can now use the data that

49:12

they have collected and filtered through your LLM

49:14

choice. So I think

49:16

that that will I'm sure some companies

49:18

will just make that transition pretty

49:20

seamlessly to pure purely providing data or

49:22

almost purely providing data to LLMs

49:24

rather than providing data to end users.

49:26

And then other companies will probably

49:28

just get run over and they will

49:30

die. But all the data

49:32

they gathered will live on forever in

49:34

the weights of all the models that

49:36

come after this. You wrote a blog

49:38

post I wanted to get into asking

49:40

if white collar workers will experience a

49:42

blue collar. economic recovery. Well, why don't

49:44

you unpack that? Yeah. So there was

49:46

this period in the early 20th century

49:48

where the US economy was growing and

49:50

it was growing because it was industrializing.

49:53

And then there's this period in roughly

49:55

the mid 20th century where the economy

49:57

is growing and manufacturing is not actually

49:59

growing with it. And then there's this

50:01

period starting pretty much 1990 or so

50:03

is about when the inflection happens in

50:05

the chart. So whatever the real forces

50:07

behind that work happened earlier. And that's

50:09

the period where the economy is growing

50:11

and manufacturing, at least in terms of

50:13

manufacturing employment is shrinking. And that is,

50:15

you know, actual manufacturing output still looks

50:17

pretty good. There are some weird price

50:19

level adjustments that, that end up being

50:21

made on that, that make those numbers

50:23

a little bit hard to compare over

50:25

long periods. But, you know, the US

50:27

does still make stuff, still makes a

50:29

lot of stuff. And China, China has

50:32

surpassed us, but it's a fairly recent

50:34

phenomenon. But the actual US manufacturing employment

50:36

has not really recovered from that peak.

50:38

And it does not seem likely to

50:40

ever recover from that peak. It will,

50:42

there will probably be bounces up and

50:44

down, but the US, it, the US

50:46

has more of a comparative advantage in

50:48

the kind of manufacturing where you have

50:50

a lot of really expensive equipment. You

50:52

have very specialized people who have some

50:54

combination of, you know, theoretical knowledge that

50:56

you learn from a textbook and practical

50:58

knowledge that you get from using machine.

51:00

According to its instruction manual, realizing the

51:02

instruction manual has missed in nuances that

51:04

you have been able to pick up

51:06

and then. you know, slowly, slowly

51:09

accumulating that kind of expertise. So

51:11

like we probably will just have this

51:13

increasingly small, more, more skilled up

51:15

manufacturing labor force. But one of my

51:17

questions on this was what happens?

51:19

What if white collar labor actually goes

51:21

through the same transition? Because when

51:23

we look at this industrial cycle and

51:25

how it affected employment was when

51:27

manufacturers were doing well, they would upgrade

51:29

a lot of their equipment. And

51:32

when they do that, that means that

51:34

they are basically increasing the amount of capital

51:36

versus the amount of labor as inputs

51:38

into what they do. And then when there's

51:40

a downturn, they can lay some people

51:42

off. They still have this equipment and they

51:44

can rehire some people, but. they

51:46

are still profitable operating at less

51:48

than full capacity, they probably

51:50

operate at less than full capacity. So

51:52

they can kind of take their time

51:54

on hiring people. They have these efficiency gains

51:57

from having enough equipment to service peak

51:59

demand. And then when they're at sub -peak

52:01

demand, they just don't have as many

52:03

people employed. And for a long

52:05

time, it's been hard to automate white collar

52:07

workers in the same way, but that

52:09

is getting easier. You could

52:11

imagine a lot of companies where they

52:13

maybe made a decision to spend a

52:16

lot on AI customer service tool or

52:18

on building a model out of their

52:20

building a model trained on their internal

52:22

source code or whatever the thing was.

52:24

And that they underwrote this based on

52:26

the level of demand for their

52:28

product that they saw. A few months

52:30

ago, that demand is no longer here,

52:32

but they have actually made the investment

52:35

already. So now their output per software

52:37

engineer, their output per customer service agent

52:39

is a lot higher. And they

52:41

may just find that they don't need

52:43

to staff up that much in the

52:45

next round. And also, as they're building

52:47

more of these specialized in -house tools,

52:49

you have to know more about how

52:51

an individual company operates in order to

52:54

function effectively there. So it actually becomes

52:56

more expensive to hire people. There's a

52:58

higher opportunity cost to interviewing them and

53:00

training them. And then there's also a

53:02

higher cost to letting them leave. So

53:04

you actually end up with this

53:06

more static workforce after a while. And

53:09

it seems like in some cases, what

53:11

the blue collar workforce did was they retired

53:13

earlier than they otherwise would have with

53:15

a lower standard of living. But they did

53:17

okay, just not as well as they

53:19

might have. And then in other cases, you

53:21

have people who downshifted from they had

53:23

a union job at the steel plant, now

53:26

there's no union and no steel plant.

53:28

So they spend the last couple of years

53:30

before retirement delivering pizzas or driving a

53:32

truck or something. And that is definitely not

53:34

what they wanted, but it is, you

53:36

know, they still need to work and it's

53:38

better than nothing. And I

53:41

think for a lot of workers, they

53:43

just end up in kind of a

53:45

less structured, less formal employment environment where

53:47

it is a lot more gig -based,

53:49

a lot more variable, etc. And

53:51

also the cost of that kind of

53:53

gig work has gone down because of LMS,

53:55

too. So you can have a 24 -7

53:57

live support chatbot that you just pay

53:59

for that speaks a natural language, can understand

54:02

natural language queries in a variety of

54:04

natural languages. And you can get some sleep.

54:06

You don't actually have to scale your

54:08

business to the point where you can have

54:10

full -time 24 -7 customer service. So you

54:12

can have a lot more just kind of

54:14

gig work in the white collar space. And

54:17

if the transaction costs for working

54:19

with a more random assortment of partner

54:21

companies goes down, again, because of

54:23

all of them, then maybe there is

54:25

kind of an afterlife for steady

54:27

white collar jobs that exist in that

54:29

more informal sector. And I'm still,

54:31

I'm not, I didn't write that because

54:33

I was convinced it would happen.

54:35

I wrote that because I was kind

54:37

of speculating that it is more

54:39

likely than it was years ago. Then

54:41

I still think there's a completely

54:43

coherent view of the world where the

54:45

higher productivity of software engineers who

54:47

are using LLMs means that we write

54:49

a whole lot more software. A

54:51

lot of that software interacts with other

54:53

software and there's just not indefinitely

54:56

forever more demand, but there is more

54:58

demand for a very long time.

55:00

But it's not the only outcome that

55:02

we can see. That makes sense

55:04

as an overview. You also

55:06

wrote about Harvard, and you

55:08

wrote about them borrowing. And I'm curious

55:10

just to ask you the broader question

55:12

of where are the Ivy League schools

55:14

in the state of them right now

55:16

with what Trump is planning to do

55:18

with their own sort of economic position

55:20

separate from Trump and sort of lost

55:22

popularity for a bunch of reasons, both

55:24

structural and political, and share what

55:26

value they offer in perspective. What

55:29

is the state of higher education?

55:31

You know, that's one where I think

55:33

I should actually punt on it

55:35

because what I would love to know

55:37

and don't have handy is, what

55:39

is their actual annual operating expense? What

55:41

is that operating expense? What is

55:43

their operating income, inclusive of and exclusive

55:45

of federal subsidies? And then how

55:48

big is the endowment and what's the

55:50

expected return on that? My,

55:52

my understanding, like the annoying thing about

55:54

talking about Harvard is that Harvard is like,

55:56

it is a great way to refer

55:58

to, it is a great bit of them

56:00

for just high status, high prestige school,

56:02

but actually a lot of the rules that

56:05

apply to those schools, a lot of

56:07

the generalizations that apply to them do not

56:09

apply as strong at Harvard because it

56:11

is just very far ahead of many of

56:13

its peers in terms of things like

56:15

having a very large and very well run

56:17

historically endowment fund. And having enough of

56:20

a brand name that if people are choosing

56:22

among, if someone has their choice of

56:24

elite schools, they will often choose Harvard above

56:26

the other options. So Harvard actually can

56:28

save itself from some of the difficult trade

56:30

-offs that other places have. But there's no

56:32

free lunch. You always just have a

56:34

different set of trade -offs because now you

56:37

are much more deeply symbolic. And you also

56:39

just have a bigger responsibility to actually

56:41

pick the right students, get them.

56:43

well -educated, get them well -networked, get them into

56:45

important jobs, and then make sure that

56:47

they actually do good things in those jobs.

56:50

So that's one that I want to

56:52

look into. It does seem like Harvard

56:54

just is probably, you know, they are

56:56

fine without federal funding. They would obviously

56:58

prefer to have more money than less,

57:00

but they will do okay. And I

57:02

think that's part of the purpose of

57:04

Endowment Fund is that you want to

57:07

be in a position where you don't

57:09

have to suddenly change your priorities because

57:11

somebody else did. And if you're Harvard,

57:13

you can just keep on going. And

57:15

then there are these other interesting open

57:17

questions on just what is the social

57:19

utility of having various investment vehicles that

57:21

have an indefinite time horizon and are

57:23

attached to institutions that are literally older

57:26

than the United States of America itself.

57:28

And I think it is probably prosocial.

57:30

It's probably useful to have at least

57:32

some organization where it literally makes sense

57:34

for someone to ask if we had

57:36

an investment where we think that the

57:38

payoff happens in a century, what is

57:40

the price at which it's worth doing

57:42

that today? because pretty much any other

57:45

organization just doesn't have that kind of

57:47

timeframe and shouldn't have that timeframe. Like

57:49

it's a silly exercise for someone at

57:51

KKR to ask about the 100 year

57:53

return on anything unless it is something

57:55

where it actually has cash flow between

57:57

now and that point 100 years in

57:59

the future. But at Harvard, they at

58:01

least can put a discount rate on

58:04

it and ask if it's worth doing

58:06

because they probably will be around once

58:08

the payoff actually hits. And then

58:10

the specific thing that I read about them

58:12

was just that partly in response to that

58:14

Shakir fund raising, the Shakir funding situation, they

58:16

were borrowing some money and they announced this

58:18

plan at a time when markets were pretty

58:20

choppy and they would have gotten much better

58:22

terms if they had decided to borrow a

58:24

few weeks earlier. And there was some speculation

58:26

online that, hey, maybe this means Harvard is

58:28

financially distressed. But I think what it actually

58:30

means is that Harvard is a relative safe

58:32

haven and they're just very, very unlikely to

58:34

default on their debts. But they're also a

58:36

large investor. They try to invest in riskier

58:38

assets. You know, they're trying to earn positive

58:40

carry if they borrow money. So they are

58:42

lending to people who are going to pay

58:44

them more than they're paying. And that probably

58:46

the rates that those people are paying have

58:48

gone up more than the rates Harvard is

58:50

paying. So in the event that Harvard does

58:52

need to move more money from its endowment

58:54

to the operating budget because that budget is

58:56

not going to be covered by the federal

58:58

government. it does actually make sense

59:00

for them to borrow money to do

59:02

that because the alternative is sell things that

59:05

are sell things at a more distressed

59:07

price and forgo some long term gains. So

59:09

again, if you if you had a

59:11

shorter outlook then indefinitely maybe you would choose

59:13

something different but If Harvard is an

59:15

exception to be around forever, and if the

59:17

Endowment Fund makes it very likely that

59:19

they will, in fact, be around forever, then

59:22

I think they are in the

59:24

privileged position to take those long -term

59:26

contrarian bets when they have the opportunity.

59:29

Speaking of privileged position, we'll close on this.

59:31

You know, some people are saying, hey,

59:33

is there going to be mass capital fly?

59:35

And we alluded to this earlier, but

59:37

you wrote a piece basically suggesting how, or

59:39

talking about how sticky the reserve currency

59:41

is. Yeah. And one of the elements of

59:43

that is just that anything that actually weekends,

59:46

the US status as the issuer of

59:48

reserve currency is so bad macroeconomically for

59:50

the rest of the world that people

59:52

get really cautious. They go into low

59:54

risk assets or just they try to

59:56

get liquidity in order to pay off

59:59

the payoff liabilities that they might otherwise

1:00:01

have difficulty paying off. And that often

1:00:03

means that it's a flight to dollars.

1:00:05

So When the US has a financial

1:00:07

crisis, dollar goes up because people have

1:00:09

borrowed in dollars and they're worried that

1:00:11

they won't be able to source dollars

1:00:13

by selling goods and services to Americans.

1:00:15

So they have to source dollars by

1:00:17

selling assets for dollars instead. So that

1:00:19

means that reserve currencies have this weird

1:00:22

self healing characteristic where anything that's bad

1:00:24

for the issuer is actually good for

1:00:26

the reserve currency in the short term.

1:00:28

And we also, because one of the

1:00:30

things associated with having a reserve currency

1:00:32

is having a large financial sector. And

1:00:34

those financial sectors are really good at

1:00:36

reallocating capital, but they're always kind of

1:00:38

built around whatever the previous status quo

1:00:40

was. And that means they are incredibly

1:00:42

good at snapping back to that previous

1:00:45

status quo. So financial markets are just

1:00:47

unbelievably good at pretending that the last

1:00:49

big market break did not happen and

1:00:51

that things that worked a year ago

1:00:53

and, you know, temporarily seemed to stop

1:00:55

working, but then slightly recovered. They're very

1:00:57

good at pretending that those things will

1:00:59

just work just fine indefinitely. So you

1:01:01

do have anything that hurts the US's

1:01:03

status as a reserve currency, that reserve

1:01:05

status tends to direct things back to

1:01:08

normal. And then anything that

1:01:10

helps recover that status, the US

1:01:12

financial markets tend to really push strongly

1:01:14

in that exact direction. That

1:01:16

plus just, it's hard

1:01:18

to overestimate how much the world

1:01:20

just thinks in terms of dollars and

1:01:22

how much of a global default

1:01:24

dollars are for a lot of transactions.

1:01:26

This is something that, you know,

1:01:28

I look for evidence that this is

1:01:30

not true and I will definitely

1:01:32

start paying attention if large multinationals have

1:01:35

debt that was denominated in dollars,

1:01:37

it's rolling over and now they're issuing

1:01:39

euro or yen bonds because those

1:01:41

are the better deal. Did they view

1:01:43

those as the better deal long

1:01:45

term? But my suspicion is that a

1:01:47

lot of dollar to nominated debt

1:01:49

will be rolled over in dollars and

1:01:51

that the financial system will remain

1:01:53

dollarized by default. And I think what

1:01:55

a lot of people are calculating

1:01:57

is that whatever Trump does, it is

1:01:59

very hard to undo

1:02:01

the dollar as a global default and

1:02:03

to completely unwind that effect over the

1:02:05

space of four years, and that the

1:02:07

closer gets to doing that, the less

1:02:10

likely it is that anything even remotely

1:02:12

Trump will be a viable policy direction

1:02:14

for the US. And so, you

1:02:16

know, you're sort think if you're

1:02:18

thinking about reserve status, you have to

1:02:20

ask yourself not just what could

1:02:22

be done to the US reserve currency

1:02:24

issuer over long periods, but literally

1:02:26

what could get down between now and

1:02:28

the midterms because midterms will not

1:02:31

be friendly to such strategies if those

1:02:33

strategies start to actually hurt US

1:02:35

standards of living. where that makes sense.

1:02:37

We're a time zone be mindful, but,

1:02:39

But Bern, as always, this is a

1:02:42

great, great wide -ranging discussion. Until next

1:02:44

time. Already. next time. Tornberg"]

1:02:50

Upstream with Eric Tornberg is a

1:02:52

show from Turpentine, the podcast network behind

1:02:54

Moment of Zen and Cognitive Revolution.

1:02:56

If you like the episode, please leave

1:02:59

a review in the Apple Store.

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features