BITCOIN & THE MONETARY REVOLUTION w/ Josh Hendrickson & William Luther

BITCOIN & THE MONETARY REVOLUTION w/ Josh Hendrickson & William Luther

Released Thursday, 6th March 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
BITCOIN & THE MONETARY REVOLUTION w/ Josh Hendrickson & William Luther

BITCOIN & THE MONETARY REVOLUTION w/ Josh Hendrickson & William Luther

BITCOIN & THE MONETARY REVOLUTION w/ Josh Hendrickson & William Luther

BITCOIN & THE MONETARY REVOLUTION w/ Josh Hendrickson & William Luther

Thursday, 6th March 2025
Good episode? Give it some love!
Rate Episode

Episode Transcript

Transcripts are displayed as originally observed. Some content, including advertisements may have changed.

Use Ctrl + F to search

0:02

What are these things that no one

0:04

thought would be would be something significant

0:06

for Bitcoin's future that now suddenly look

0:08

like super significant for for how everything

0:10

plays out? And I think that's the

0:12

big thing that we tend to miss.

0:14

And I think that's the thing that

0:17

actually makes it really, really hard. What

0:21

Bitcoin did is brought to you by

0:23

our lead sponsor and massive legends, Iron.

0:26

the largest NASDAQ -listed Bitcoin miner using

0:28

100 % renewable energy. IRON

0:30

are not just powering the Bitcoin network,

0:32

they also provide cutting -edge computing resources

0:34

for AI all backed by renewable energy.

0:37

So whether you're interested in mining Bitcoin or harnessing

0:40

AI compute power, IRON is setting the

0:42

standard. Visit IRON.com to

0:44

learn more, which is

0:46

IREN.com. Okay, Will, Josh, good

0:48

to see you both. Good

0:50

to be here. Yeah, good to see you. So Josh. You've

0:53

been on the show before it's been a little

0:55

while and it was over two years ago now

0:57

so we should do a bit of an introduction

0:59

but will this is the first time on the

1:01

show so. Do you want to give a bit

1:03

of a background who you are and what you do. Yeah

1:07

my name is William Luther I'm an

1:09

associate professor of economics at Florida Atlantic

1:11

University. I also direct the

1:13

sound money project at the American Institute

1:16

for Economic Research and I'm a

1:18

fellow or maybe a senior fellow

1:20

I don't know. at the

1:22

Bitcoin Policy Institute. All

1:25

right, perfect. And Josh? Yeah,

1:27

so I'm a professor of economics

1:29

and chair of the Department of

1:31

Economics at the University of Mississippi.

1:34

I am a senior fellow

1:37

at both the Sound Money Project

1:39

with Will and a senior fellow

1:41

at the Bitcoin Policy Institute. Love

1:44

it. So, two economics professors

1:46

here. I want to get into

1:49

some of the really, like, big hot button topics

1:51

in Bitcoin with you. But before we do,

1:53

I've got to ask you the question that you're probably

1:55

sick of hearing. So

1:57

there's a meme in Bitcoin, which is

1:59

Bitcoin is so simple, you have to have

2:01

an economics degree to not understand it. Now,

2:04

obviously, you two are exceptions to that rule.

2:06

But why do you think so many well

2:09

-known, well -respected economists have never quite got

2:11

their head around Bitcoin? I

2:13

think it's a couple of things. So

2:16

one is that we have to remember

2:18

that even among most economics

2:20

professors they're not monetary economists so they don't

2:22

actually spend a lot of time. You

2:25

know thinking about money thinking

2:27

about you know the monetary

2:29

system thinking about alternative. Monetary

2:33

regimes and things like that and so. For

2:36

many of them like sort of what they know

2:38

is kind of like whatever they learned in class

2:40

and they're not really thinking about it very much.

2:44

And in that respect, you know,

2:46

our profession really kind of actually does

2:48

a bad job of teaching people about

2:50

economic history and about alternative

2:53

regimes, how the gold standard worked, those

2:56

kinds of things. They tend

2:58

to do an okay job telling you

3:00

kind of like why those things no

3:02

longer exist or at least providing some

3:05

justification. But most

3:08

people just don't spend time really thinking about

3:10

it. I think the other thing is that

3:15

We're in the US and in the

3:17

US, I think there's just a bias

3:19

to not understand why this would be

3:21

a useful technology. Like we have the

3:23

dollar and the dollar is, you know,

3:25

very dominant, both, you

3:28

know, in the US and throughout the world. And so I

3:30

think to a large extent, there are people who just

3:32

look at this and go, well, why do we need this? Like what

3:34

is this? What is this for? What

3:36

is it actually accomplished? And they're not thinking

3:38

about the issues that people in other countries

3:40

face on a daily basis. Yeah,

3:42

I think I would second all of

3:45

that. And certainly,

3:47

if you see me out and you

3:49

buy me a beer, I will lament

3:52

about the state of the economics profession.

3:55

But I want to come to

3:57

at least a partial defense of

3:59

my monetary economist brethren.

4:03

I think there's also

4:06

a large group of monetary

4:08

economists who actually do

4:11

understand, certainly

4:13

monetary theory reasonably well. Some

4:17

subset of them also understand

4:19

monetary history reasonably well. And

4:23

with those

4:25

two tools,

4:28

monetary history and monetary theory, they actually have

4:30

a pretty good sense of what Bitcoin is

4:32

and how it works. They're

4:35

just not persuaded, right? And I

4:37

think that's okay. I

4:39

think they're not persuaded for a

4:41

few reasons. They may have some

4:43

different value judgments. Some

4:46

economists have more faith in governments

4:48

than I do and they want

4:50

to have a government that can

4:53

conduct monetary policy and can

4:55

monitor payments. And

4:59

so, all right, we have different value judgments there.

5:01

It's not that they don't understand how Bitcoin works,

5:03

it's just that they don't like it. Other

5:06

monetary economists, I think, they

5:09

see what are somewhat,

5:11

maybe somewhat being too generous,

5:15

but they see what are extreme, really

5:18

extreme views in the Bitcoin community. And

5:21

they think that that is, you

5:24

know, the position that they would

5:26

need to defend in order to

5:28

be a quote on quote supporter

5:30

of Bitcoin. And maybe

5:33

they're more inclined to think that

5:35

Bitcoin will serve a niche role

5:37

in payments or has some relatively

5:39

small use, but they don't see

5:42

it overtaking the world or replacing

5:44

the US dollar. And

5:46

rather than trying to explain that at

5:48

length, they just kind of brush this

5:51

aside. And so

5:53

I think that those are

5:55

reasonable positions to hold. We

5:57

might disagree with them, but it's not, those

6:00

views are not always held

6:03

out of complete ignorance, right?

6:05

They could be held out

6:07

of different preferences or different

6:09

assessments of the relevant factors,

6:11

not because someone necessarily doesn't

6:14

understand monetary theory or monetary

6:16

history. There's plenty of that

6:18

too, don't get me wrong,

6:20

but at least some of

6:23

them are... well

6:25

-informed opposers or at

6:27

least non -supporters of

6:29

Bitcoin. So you

6:31

think the Bitcoin community puts some people

6:34

off rather than necessarily Bitcoin the technology?

6:36

Sure, yeah. I think that's an easy

6:39

yes for me. I'm a fan of

6:41

Bitcoin and sometimes I'm put off by

6:43

the Bitcoin community. Yeah,

6:45

that's fair. So I want

6:47

to get a bit of a better

6:50

understanding about the economics that you two

6:52

teach. So I think people really readily

6:54

try and put people into two buckets

6:56

of either like Keynesian or Austrian, especially

6:59

in Bitcoin. So, but what is it that

7:01

you teach? What would be also a

7:03

brand of economics? You

7:05

know, Milton Friedman has this great quip

7:08

where he says there's only good economics

7:10

and bad economics, and I do good

7:12

economics. And I

7:14

would definitely put myself in the

7:16

good economics camp. I think these

7:18

terms, Keynesian economics, Austrian economics, they

7:20

get thrown a lot and they're

7:22

most useful in the context of

7:24

the history of economic thought. You

7:27

know, if we go back to the 1930s

7:29

or the 1940s, right, we can think about

7:31

whether someone was a Keynesian or an Austrian.

7:35

And it doesn't, to me

7:37

at least, it doesn't make too much sense to do

7:39

that in a modern context. A

7:41

lot of the good ideas

7:43

that Austrians have advanced, not

7:46

all of the good ideas that

7:48

Austrians have advanced, but a lot

7:51

of those good ideas, certainly things

7:53

like marginal analysis, have been incorporated

7:55

to some degree and to the

7:58

mainstream. And

8:00

likewise, some of the

8:02

bad ideas of Keynesian

8:05

economics, ideas like we

8:07

don't need to think about individuals

8:09

making decisions in our models, we

8:12

can just have these aggregates A

8:15

lot of those ideas have been

8:17

rejected by modern economists. And

8:20

so certainly there are still folks

8:22

that I think everyone would say

8:24

that person's an Austrian or that

8:26

person's a Keynesian, but most modern

8:28

economists wouldn't put themselves in either

8:30

of those categories. They would

8:32

just see themselves as economists. When

8:34

people ask me what sort of

8:37

group I fit into, I usually

8:39

just say I'm just not a

8:41

Keynesian. Because I guess that's the

8:43

only real objection that I have

8:45

is that Keynesian economics really just

8:47

kind of dispensed with what's actually

8:49

interesting about economics, which is understanding

8:51

how people make decisions and thinking

8:53

about how markets function, how prices

8:56

work to correct shortages and surpluses

8:58

and all these kinds of things.

9:00

And a lot of Keynesianism just

9:02

denies that those price effects. exist

9:04

or that we need to think

9:06

about those things at the individual

9:08

level or that we can just

9:10

think about macroeconomic phenomenon completely independent

9:12

of what's going on at the

9:14

micro level. And I think

9:17

that to the extent that anybody is doing

9:19

that where they're just focusing on the aggregate

9:21

at the expense of the individual and at

9:23

the expense of the price system, like you're

9:25

doing what we'll just call bad economics. That's

9:29

not what anybody should be doing. And

9:31

I don't think that you actually learn

9:33

much from that. potentially,

9:36

you know, identify some correlations

9:38

between aggregate data and maybe those are

9:41

reliable correlations. But at the end of

9:43

the day, do you really understand why

9:45

the data was generated the way that

9:47

it was and how the individual decision

9:49

-making process led to those outcomes? Like,

9:52

I think that's actually where economics is

9:54

really interesting and useful. And if you're

9:56

not doing that, then you're not doing

9:58

good economics. That actually

10:00

leads perfectly to my next question, which is,

10:03

do you think that Modern economics has lent

10:05

too heavily into kind of the stat side

10:07

of things rather than the human action side

10:09

of things. I guess it depends on what

10:12

you mean by modern economics. Sometimes

10:14

this term is used to describe,

10:17

you know, like post 1970s economics

10:19

and certainly in the macro side

10:22

of things, the big things that

10:24

happened in the 1970s and 1980s

10:26

was very theory driven, right? Theory

10:29

was king. You needed to specify

10:31

why it was that individuals were

10:33

making decisions. What were the ends

10:36

they were trying to achieve with

10:38

these means? You

10:41

know, we got things like the Lucas

10:43

critique, which said, you can't just do

10:45

empirical analysis and historical data and expect

10:48

those relationships to hold because those relationships

10:50

are the outcomes of choices that people

10:52

are making. And if you change the

10:54

rules of the game, people are going

10:57

to change the choices that they make,

10:59

and those relationships will break down. If

11:02

by modern economics, you mean in

11:05

the last decade or so, then

11:07

yeah, I think there has been

11:09

kind of a cycle back towards

11:12

what I would call naive empiricism,

11:14

where we're just gonna let the

11:16

data do the talking, whatever that

11:18

means. And we're

11:21

gonna try to identify very precisely

11:23

what the causal effect of this

11:25

or that is, even if we're

11:28

not particularly concerned with this or

11:30

that, just because, well, this is

11:32

something we can identify. And

11:35

so from that perspective, yeah,

11:38

I think there's been a

11:40

move towards naive empiricism. Yeah,

11:43

I mean, I think that we've kind

11:45

of, I mean, one of the main

11:47

issues is actually that we, yeah,

11:50

in like the last decade or two, as

11:53

a profession, things really have

11:55

moved in the direction of like

11:57

trying to demonstrate causal effects of

11:59

things. Like how do we prove

12:01

that this policy actually, you know,

12:04

resulted in this change or something

12:06

like that? And the issue is

12:08

that a lot of that stuff

12:10

has become completely detached from economic

12:12

theory. It's also become completely

12:14

detached from things that we know from

12:16

economic history or things that we know

12:18

from previous literatures. And I think one

12:20

of the major problems actually with this

12:22

approach is that, I

12:25

mean, as Will said, data do

12:27

not speak. So we can't just

12:29

estimate things and then just assume

12:32

that we understand why we got

12:34

those estimates. But

12:37

I think economics is fundamentally about

12:39

the study of human behavior,

12:41

right? That's really what we should

12:43

be focused on. And when you're

12:46

so focused on making sure

12:48

that you're identifying these causal effects,

12:50

you start to... You

12:53

start to lose curiosity, frankly, right? Because even

12:55

when they get surprising results, like they basically

12:58

just view that as a challenge to the

13:00

rest of the profession to figure out why

13:02

they got this challenging result rather than seeing

13:04

that challenging result themselves and going, well, what

13:06

would I have to believe about human behavior

13:08

for this to be true? And

13:21

while you're waiting for the perfect buying opportunity,

13:23

River lets you earn daily interest on your

13:25

cash balance paid in Bitcoin, which

13:27

outperforms most high -yield savings accounts. What

13:30

really sets River apart is their unmatched dedication

13:32

to security. You have peace

13:34

of mind knowing that River has monthly proof of

13:37

reserves and holds all Bitcoin in multi -sig cold

13:39

storage. And with US -based phone

13:41

support, you'll always have someone ready to help. To

13:43

open an account, go to river.com/WBD and

13:46

earn up to $100 in Bitcoin when

13:48

you buy. That's R -I -V -E

13:50

-r.com/W -B -D. This episode is brought

13:52

to you by Ankerwatch. The thing that

13:54

keeps me up at night is the

13:56

idea of a critical error with my

13:59

Bitcoin cold storage. This is where Ankerwatch

14:01

comes in. With Ankerwatch, you're

14:03

protected by their time -locked multi -sig

14:05

vault and with your own A -plus

14:07

rated Lloyds of London backed insurance policy.

14:09

You get to hold your keys, Ankerwatch holds the

14:12

risk. Whether you're worried

14:14

about inheritance planning, wrench attacks, natural disasters,

14:16

or your own mistakes, you're protected by

14:18

Ankerwatch. Rates for fully insured custody start

14:21

as low as 0 .55 % and

14:23

are available for individual and commercial customers

14:25

located in the US. Speak

14:27

to AnchorWatch for a quote and for more

14:29

details about your security options and coverage. Visit

14:32

AnchorWatch.com today, which is

14:35

AnchorWatch.com. So Will, just

14:37

before you jumped on this call, I was speaking to Josh a

14:39

little bit and he was telling me that you've been in Bitcoin

14:41

for a very long time. I'd be

14:43

really curious to know when it was you first

14:46

kind of outed yourself to the people who

14:48

you work with, your colleagues. and how like that

14:50

opinion on Bitcoin has changed over the time. And

14:52

maybe you should give a bit of a

14:54

background on when you actually did get into Bitcoin.

14:57

Yeah, I guess I'll tell this embarrassing story.

15:01

So, my dissertation

15:03

advisor at George Mason

15:05

University was a guy

15:07

named Larry White, very

15:10

well -respected monetary historian, and

15:13

in many respects, a

15:16

proto -Bitcoiner. If you go

15:19

back to the 90s and

15:21

check out copies of Entropy

15:23

Magazine, you'll have a hard time

15:26

finding those, but if you email me, I will

15:28

send you copies because this is the kind of

15:30

thing nerdy academics keep. You

15:32

will see Larry and

15:35

his first student, George

15:37

Seljan, engaged in conversations

15:39

with folks like Hal

15:41

Finney and Nick Sabo.

15:43

because Larry and George

15:45

were really interested in

15:48

private monies from an

15:50

economic perspective. And

15:52

of course, folks like Hal Finney

15:54

and Nick Sabo were interested in private

15:56

monies from more of a computer science

15:58

perspective. And so they were

16:01

having these conversations before Bitcoin was

16:03

a thing. And so

16:05

in 2010, I was in

16:07

a research group at GMU.

16:10

And one of the graduate students

16:12

in our research group presented a

16:15

paper on Bitcoin. And

16:18

I said something to him

16:20

like, Chuck, you know, this is

16:22

very interesting, but I don't think this is ever going to catch

16:24

on. And so, you know,

16:27

you shouldn't waste too much time

16:29

on this. Just send it out,

16:31

get it published, and then move

16:33

on to something more productive. And

16:36

then... I hope you just listen to

16:38

you. I hope

16:40

he didn't as well. In

16:43

2012, I had finished

16:45

my PhD, I had

16:47

accepted a position at

16:49

Kenyon College. And

16:52

my friend Eli Dorado was working

16:54

at the Mercatus Center at the

16:56

time. And he reached out to

16:59

me and he asked me to

17:01

write a white paper for Mercatus

17:04

on Bitcoin. And it

17:06

just so happened that One

17:09

of my students was working on

17:11

a paper on Bitcoin for the

17:13

honors monetary economics seminar I was

17:16

teaching that semester. And

17:18

I had thought about this

17:20

other idea that might be

17:22

interesting to pursue in the

17:24

context of Bitcoin. And

17:26

so I agreed to write this

17:28

white paper for Mercatus and then

17:30

another paper with my student basically

17:32

because I thought it would be

17:34

weird. If I just had one

17:36

paper on my CV about Bitcoin

17:38

and then the rest of it

17:40

was on other monetary stuff, like,

17:42

why did he write this paper

17:44

on Bitcoin? And

17:47

so by the end of that year, the

17:49

price of Bitcoin, the end of 2013, the

17:51

price of Bitcoin hit $1 ,000. And

17:54

a bunch of journalists were trying to

17:56

figure out who they could talk to

17:59

about Bitcoin. And at the time, there

18:01

were only four papers on Bitcoin on

18:03

the social science research network. and just

18:05

by happenstance, two of them were mine.

18:09

So suddenly I was very interested

18:11

in Bitcoin because other people were

18:13

very interested in Bitcoin and I

18:15

had by chance spent a little

18:18

bit more time thinking about it

18:20

than most other economists had. And

18:22

so after that, Josh and I

18:24

began working on some papers together

18:27

about Bitcoin. We talked about it

18:29

previously, I believe, but we began

18:31

working more formally on how to

18:33

model the

18:36

competitive monetary environment.

18:39

So we put a couple of

18:41

papers out on that. And yeah,

18:43

I guess luck. That's how I

18:45

get into Bitcoin. I

18:47

think in Bitcoin, we have some

18:50

amazing economists, people like Pierre Rashard,

18:52

Saferdine, Alan Farrington. I think

18:54

Max Hillerbrand is an amazing Austrian. And

18:57

these are people that have thought about the

18:59

problems that Bitcoin potentially fixes very deeply and

19:01

they have like really sound reasoning as to

19:04

why they hold their ideas. But

19:06

I also think there's a lot of Bitcoiners and

19:08

I'd include myself in this because I had never

19:10

really read anything about economics before Bitcoin. That

19:13

hear or read what these people say and

19:15

then we'll say the same thing without necessarily

19:17

having the deep understanding of why they're saying

19:19

it. So I kind of wanted to go

19:21

through some of the really sort of hot

19:23

button topics in Bitcoin. and try and get

19:25

like a really holistic view from the two

19:27

of you on each of those topics. Does

19:29

that sound good? Yep. Sure.

19:31

All right, let's do it. So let's start with the

19:34

big one. Is fiat

19:36

currency a Ponzi? I

19:39

think actually in economics, there is

19:41

a little bit of a sense

19:43

of where we define fiat money

19:45

as sort of like what we

19:47

would call a bubble. in the

19:49

sense that it's just something that

19:51

has positive value even though there's

19:53

not really any other use for

19:55

it other than as money. I

19:59

mean, it characteristics that can

20:01

make it seem sort of

20:04

Ponzi -ish. But to me,

20:07

Ponzi is a different, it's a

20:10

different concept. But I

20:12

guess like where I would say

20:14

maybe I can describe the similarities

20:16

and then I can make I'll

20:18

be good cop and we'll be

20:20

bad cop. How about that? I'm

20:22

looking forward to it. So the

20:24

similarities are is that like in

20:26

every sort of monetary model that

20:28

you write down of fiat money,

20:30

there's generally two equilibria. There's one

20:32

equilibria where it has positive value

20:34

and everybody, you know, or at

20:36

least some fraction of people use it. And then there's

20:38

another equilibria where it's just worthless. And

20:41

so in and so in those

20:43

models, Essentially,

20:45

all that's necessary to get things

20:48

up and running is that you

20:50

have a big enough network effect

20:53

to get people to accept the

20:55

fiat money. And then if there's

20:57

a big enough network effect, then

21:00

it has positive value and people

21:02

use it. But at the

21:04

same time, that positive value

21:06

equilibrium tends to be unstable.

21:09

And what I mean by that is if

21:11

there's a big enough shock to the system,

21:13

you might end up in the other equilibrium

21:15

where it's zero. And, you know, to put

21:17

this differently, that would be what we would

21:19

call hyperinflation, right? So if you get some

21:21

sort of big enough shock that pushes you

21:23

out of that instance, you can get that.

21:25

And to some extent, that can even be

21:27

self -fulfilling where people think that the currency

21:29

isn't worth anything and so people stop using

21:32

it and then just sort of self -perpetuates.

21:34

So I would say like, that's the similarity

21:36

to a Ponzi and then maybe Will can

21:39

be the bad guy. Yeah, so let me

21:41

think about this a couple different ways. So

21:43

first, let's think about why people call fiat

21:45

monies a Ponzi. I think the idea there

21:48

is that you receive this thing and you

21:50

value it because you believe you're going to

21:52

be able to pass this off to someone

21:54

else and they will value it and they

21:57

accept it and give it and attribute value

21:59

to it because they believe they'll be able

22:01

to pass it off to someone else and

22:03

so on and so forth. And so it's

22:06

this. much like a

22:08

Ponzi scheme, this belief that you're

22:10

going to be able to pass

22:12

it on to someone else that

22:14

lets the system work. I

22:18

think that Bitcoiners should be very

22:20

careful calling fiat monies a Ponzi

22:22

on these grounds because the same

22:24

thing is true of Bitcoin, right?

22:28

That is, what's the alternative use

22:30

for Bitcoin? Now, I

22:32

don't mean the opportunity cost. There's often

22:34

some confusion about this. So some Bitcoiners

22:36

will say, well, Bitcoin is different because

22:38

it's costly to produce. Well,

22:41

that's true, but that cost

22:43

of production doesn't generate value.

22:47

Value is ultimately determined

22:49

by usefulness. And

22:51

traditionally, I'm sure when Josh teaches his

22:54

class, and certainly in my money and

22:56

financial markets class, when we make a

22:58

distinction between, say, a commodity money and

23:01

a fiat money, Commodity monies have some

23:03

alternative use. Some use apart from their

23:05

role as a medium of exchange. Some

23:08

non -money role. You

23:11

can use gold for

23:13

jewelry or to fill

23:15

cavities. Salt, historical money

23:18

can be used to preserve

23:20

food. These items

23:22

have alternative uses. Dollars

23:25

on the other hand, fiat monies,

23:27

no alternative use. And

23:29

so one big difference between commodities and

23:31

fiat monies is that alternative use that

23:33

commodities have in fiat lacks. In this

23:36

regard, Bitcoin looks a lot more like

23:38

fiat monies than commodity monies. Now,

23:41

another big difference between commodity

23:43

monies and fiat monies is

23:45

this limited supply, in the

23:48

case of commodity monies, because

23:50

of the cost of producing

23:52

those commodities, right? In

23:54

this case, Bitcoin looks much more

23:57

like commodity monies than fiat monies

23:59

because they're costly to produce and

24:01

there's a limited supply. But

24:04

on the value side, which is what

24:06

folks seem to be invoking when they're

24:08

calling fiat monies a Ponzi scheme, they're

24:11

opening themselves up for the same

24:13

criticism. So I would

24:16

say there are lots of

24:18

reasons to dislike fiat monies,

24:20

chief of which is that

24:22

their supplies might not be

24:24

managed very well. Right, but

24:26

we want to be careful

24:28

to you know, not to

24:30

not to throw the Use

24:32

value baby out with the

24:35

fiat money bath there Because

24:37

because Bitcoin has a very

24:39

similar use value which depends

24:41

on other people wanting to

24:43

use this item for what

24:45

are ultimately monetary purposes No,

24:48

I think that's a good point. I mean, one of

24:50

the ways that I kind of think about this and

24:52

talk about this with students is how does, I

24:54

think about this in terms of what you

24:57

would call like the last period problem. Like,

24:59

so suppose that there's a period, there's some

25:01

period in the future where nobody's willing to

25:03

accept this stuff. Like, you

25:07

know, then you wouldn't, then if they're not

25:09

willing to accept it then, then you shouldn't

25:11

accept it the period before that. But if

25:13

you shouldn't accept it the period before that,

25:15

then whoever was trying to give it to

25:17

you shouldn't have accepted it the period before

25:19

that. Right. And so like through backward induction,

25:21

like you just shouldn't accept the stuff today.

25:23

And that to me is like the real,

25:25

um, interesting question to try to explain when

25:27

it comes to fiat money is why, why

25:29

does fiat money actually, um,

25:33

persist given the fact that it really doesn't solve

25:35

that last period problem. Right. If we're all using

25:37

gold coins and then all a sudden nobody wants

25:39

to use gold coins anymore. Well, oh, well, like

25:42

if I have a bunch of gold coins, well,

25:44

I just have like this pile of gold. And

25:46

so I can sell that to somebody who wants

25:48

to use gold for industrial use, right? And so

25:50

I can still get something out of that. With

25:53

fiat money, there is nothing. I

25:55

think what people tend to appeal to is

25:57

they say, well, at the end of the

25:59

day, you can always pay your taxes with

26:01

the money. So the government will always take

26:03

the money. I mean, I

26:05

actually think a really interesting aspect of

26:08

Bitcoin is that There's

26:10

this old paper by a guy named

26:12

Ben Klein who asked if we could

26:14

ever have like a competitive fiat regime.

26:16

And so he was writing in the

26:18

1970s and he was really trying to

26:20

think about, okay,

26:23

our currency is no longer tied

26:26

to gold. Central banks are

26:28

in charge. Maybe we

26:30

need competition to limit things, but if it's

26:32

fiat, how can you trust people not to

26:34

just print up a bunch of money? And

26:36

kind of the main lesson from that paper

26:38

is, is that you could in theory have

26:40

like a competitive fiat system. But the issue

26:43

is, is like you would have to trust

26:45

the issuer not to just wake up one

26:47

morning and secretly print a bunch of the

26:49

money and then go out and spend it

26:51

before everybody else knows about it. And

26:55

so, and so that brings us

26:57

back to that last period problem, right? You're

26:59

always worried that there's going to be some

27:01

future period where Somebody just

27:03

prints up a bunch of money and transfers

27:05

a bunch of wealth to themselves by spending

27:07

it before everybody else knows about it. And

27:10

then the interesting thing about Bitcoin is that

27:12

Bitcoin sort of solves that trust problem with

27:14

its fixed supply. And not

27:16

just with its fixed supply, but the

27:18

way that Bitcoin works through consensus is

27:21

what matters, right? Because it's not just

27:23

that the supply is fixed, it's that

27:25

no one who's using Bitcoin actually has

27:28

an incentive to change that in the

27:30

way that the issuer of a competitive

27:32

fiat system would have. And

27:34

so when we think about all of these

27:36

issues, like I tend to think about it,

27:38

yeah, in terms of like the last period problem.

27:40

And so then the question is like, how

27:42

do you resolve that? And so with Bitcoin,

27:45

since there's no incentive to create more,

27:48

that's the thing that helps to generate

27:50

the network effect and the willingness of

27:52

people to accept it now, knowing

27:55

that, you know, the value in the future

27:57

could be uncertain. Yeah.

27:59

And also, back to your point, Will,

28:02

when comparing like Fiat and Bitcoin in

28:05

that sense, is there not a difference

28:07

because Fiat is propped up by this

28:09

debt, which is only sustainable with more

28:11

money printing or more money creation? Well,

28:14

I'm not, I'm not sure. I

28:17

mean, certainly when, you know, one

28:19

big reason why governments want to

28:21

control the issuance of money is

28:24

because they want to have access

28:26

to cheap credit, right? Central banks.

28:28

will directly or indirectly purchase government

28:31

bonds and bid the prices of

28:33

those bonds up and correspondingly the

28:35

rates on those bonds down. But

28:38

to say that all

28:41

of the debt is

28:43

only possible because we're

28:45

using fiat monies I

28:47

think is not so

28:49

clear. You

28:52

might argue that some of the

28:54

government debt wouldn't be issued in

28:56

the absence of fiat money because

28:59

the government would get worse, governments

29:01

would get worse terms for their

29:03

debt and maybe some of that

29:06

borrowing would no longer be worthwhile.

29:09

But even there, governments are

29:11

able to borrow not only

29:14

because they controlled the money

29:16

printer, in fact, In some

29:18

countries, like Argentina, the control of the

29:20

money printer makes it very difficult for

29:23

that government to borrow, at least in

29:25

their own currency, right? Because

29:27

people just expect that they're going to

29:29

run that money printer and the, you

29:32

know, peso -denominated debt is not actually

29:34

going to be worth all that much.

29:37

But the reason that

29:39

governments, I should say

29:41

one big reason that governments are able to take

29:43

on so much debt is because They

29:46

control armies, right? They can

29:48

confiscate property. Sometimes

29:50

we use euphemisms like taxes, right?

29:53

But ultimately, they are able to

29:55

extract wealth in one way or

29:57

another and that wealth to compensate

29:59

the folks holding their bonds should

30:02

they need to do that. And

30:04

just having the power to do

30:06

that often means that they don't

30:08

need to do that. I

30:12

think money printing contributes to that

30:14

power. It's one more tool of

30:16

extracting wealth, but it's

30:18

not the sum total of

30:21

that power. So even

30:23

if you got rid of fiat money,

30:25

you would still have government borrowing, right?

30:27

Governments were borrowing before we were using

30:30

fiat monies. Yeah, I

30:32

think the big issue

30:34

here is that... If

30:38

we think about how the

30:41

current monetary system works, there

30:43

are ways in which it's unique

30:45

in comparison to historical circumstances, but

30:47

there's also ways in which it's

30:49

actually just the same. And

30:52

so what I mean by that is if

30:54

you think about the current monetary system, yeah,

30:57

the US dollar is a global reserve

30:59

currency, the US Treasury security is the

31:02

global reserve asset, and because of those

31:04

things, You know,

31:06

the United States is able to do things

31:09

that it would never be able to do

31:11

in the absence of that system, right? So

31:13

one reason that the United States is able

31:15

to run up so much government debt is

31:17

that there are central banks around the world

31:20

who just passively, you know, buy and sit

31:22

on that debt. And so if

31:24

that's going to be the case, those

31:27

aren't exactly like price sensitive

31:29

buyers. And so when

31:31

you're running up debt, like you're not necessarily

31:33

paying the full cost that you would. without

31:36

those kinds of buyers. And

31:39

so, but I also think it's important

31:41

to understand like why this system exists.

31:43

I mean, like this system exists because

31:45

the United States wants this system to

31:47

exist, right? Like the United States wants

31:49

the ability to conduct emergency financing when

31:52

the United States wants to spend a

31:54

bunch of money. They don't want to

31:56

have to desperately search for creditors. What

31:58

they wanna do is they wanna be

32:00

able to issue more

32:02

debt without even necessarily incurring

32:04

higher borrowing costs. And

32:06

that's what this system allows them to do,

32:09

right? When the United States goes to war

32:11

or when the United States just supports somebody

32:13

else who's going to war by sending them

32:15

money, you know, they're just borrowing

32:17

that money and they're sending it, but their borrowing

32:19

costs really don't change all that much because wars

32:21

tend to be temporary and there's lots of passive

32:23

buyers for this debt. And so

32:26

prices don't really adjust all that much. And

32:29

so there are characteristics of this system

32:32

that are bizarre because never before in

32:34

world history have we ever had like

32:36

a sovereign debt instrument serve as like

32:38

the reserve asset of the world. And

32:41

so that's kind of a bizarre

32:43

set of circumstances. But the

32:45

reason that that that were in

32:47

that position is the same motivation

32:49

that states have always had, right?

32:52

So even under the gold standard,

32:54

you know, states, you know,

32:56

I mean, going back to ancient Greece, right, like

32:58

they're manipulating the value of

33:00

gold coins and things like that. And

33:02

not just manipulating the value, I mean,

33:04

one of the things when you look

33:07

at this historically is it's not just

33:09

like they're debasing the currency. I

33:11

mean, what they would do is

33:13

they would debase the currency during

33:16

wartime, and then at least in

33:18

the successful countries, then during peacetime,

33:20

like they would revalue the currency

33:22

as a commitment mechanism. And

33:24

so this tended to be really costly

33:26

because wars were inflationary and then the

33:28

aftermath of wars were deflationary. And none

33:30

of that was really, you know, market

33:32

factors that were driving those things. It

33:35

was government policy that was driving those

33:37

things. And so that tended to impose

33:39

costs on people. But

33:41

they were doing that because that gave

33:43

them access to the ability to finance

33:45

wars and emergencies and things like that.

33:48

Even the Bank of England, you know,

33:50

used to suspend the convertibility of gold.

33:52

during times of war, but then they

33:55

would resume convertibility after the war at

33:57

the previous parity of the pound. And

33:59

the reason for that was it was

34:02

creating a commitment device where basically they

34:04

could print a bunch of money during

34:06

the war to help finance things. They

34:09

could use the central bank as a

34:11

source of credit. And

34:13

then after the war, they knew that their

34:15

spending would decline and they wouldn't have as

34:17

much need for that anymore. And so they

34:19

could return. But like without that commitment mechanism,

34:22

you would destroy the value of your currency,

34:24

right? If you suspended convertibility into gold and

34:26

with no commitment and just were spending and

34:28

spending and spending like people would just give

34:30

up on the pound. And

34:33

so all of this is to say

34:35

that yes, there's like some characteristics of

34:37

the system that are kind of bizarre

34:39

and are kind of like debt based

34:41

and debt driven. But

34:43

there are, but there are also characteristics

34:45

of the system that are perfectly predictable

34:48

from just understanding what states do, right?

34:50

Like states want to finance war. And,

34:52

and even if we were to replace like

34:55

Fiat with, with Bitcoin, that's not going

34:57

to necessarily remove the state's desire to

34:59

do these things. And so one of

35:01

the things I mean, we can only

35:03

speculate about how they would try to

35:05

manipulate things, but I mean, they manipulated the

35:07

gold standard. So we would expect them

35:09

to try to manipulate, you know, a Bitcoin

35:11

standard. I mean, we don't know how

35:13

they would do it or precisely what

35:15

they would do, but we can imagine that

35:18

they would try. Right. And so

35:20

I think all of these things are important to

35:22

keep in mind when we're talking about these big

35:24

picture issues. Yeah, let me just

35:26

add one thing that one thing that

35:28

I think that would

35:31

serve Bitcoiners well, non -economist Bitcoiners,

35:33

is just to make a distinction

35:35

between private debt and public debt.

35:38

So in thinking about how

35:41

fiat money may enable the

35:43

government to issue more debt

35:46

than it otherwise would, we're

35:48

talking about the issuer of

35:50

that money issuing debt. But

35:53

think about what's happening in private debt

35:56

markets. Think about a long

35:58

-term contract. in dollars, right? One of the

36:00

things that you're very much concerned about is

36:02

the purchasing power of those dollars that you're

36:04

going to be paid back in the future

36:06

or the purchasing power of those dollars that

36:08

you're going to be repaying in the future.

36:10

You need to form some expectation about what

36:12

those dollars are going to be worth well

36:14

in the future. And you

36:16

can imagine if we have say

36:19

a commodity money like the classical

36:21

gold standard, right on the classical

36:23

gold standard, the supply of money

36:26

automatically adjusted to offset

36:29

changes in demand over the longer term.

36:31

And as a consequence, the purchasing power

36:33

of money on the classical gold standard

36:36

was relatively stable. So

36:39

when you entered into a long

36:41

-term contract or issued a long

36:43

-term bond, you had a very

36:45

good sense of what that money

36:48

would be worth when you're paying

36:50

it back in 10 years, 20

36:52

years, 30 years, 100 years. And

36:54

that makes that contract much less

36:57

risky than it is today. We

36:59

don't we don't see 100 year

37:01

bonds today, right? And the

37:03

reason we don't see 100 year

37:05

bonds today, except in in, you

37:07

know, marketing cases like a sleeping

37:09

beauty bond or something like that.

37:11

The reason we don't see that

37:14

today is because those long term

37:16

contracts are incredibly risky. It's much

37:18

harder to predict what the future

37:20

purchasing power of the dollar will

37:22

be in 20 years, 30 years,

37:24

40 years, 50 years, 100 years,

37:26

right? And so that contract that

37:28

otherwise would have been viable is

37:30

not viable in a world where

37:32

you have this unconstrained fiat money.

37:34

And as a consequence of that,

37:36

some of those long -term debt

37:38

contracts just don't take place. Now,

37:41

we're talking about private debt markets. The

37:44

uncertainty of the dollar eliminates

37:46

the prospect of some long

37:48

-term debt contracts, which means

37:51

we may be getting less

37:53

private sector debt than we otherwise

37:56

would. So we can quibble about

37:58

the aggregate level of debt, whether

38:01

it's greater or lower or more

38:03

or less unchanged. But

38:05

I think at a minimum, we want to

38:07

make a distinction between what's going on with

38:10

public debt issuance and what's going on with

38:12

private debt issuance. Okay, interesting. I do just

38:14

want to go back to something you said

38:16

earlier, Josh. You gave the

38:18

analogy of the Bank of England, Paul's inconversibility

38:20

during wartime, and then resuming that at the

38:22

previous rate. And you said if they didn't

38:25

do that, then people would lose all faith

38:27

in the pan that would fail. But is

38:29

that not the world we live in now?

38:33

Well, I mean, it's very similar

38:35

to the world that we live

38:37

in now. But I think that

38:39

the issue here is that the

38:41

question is, where do people go?

38:43

Right? Like, where do people go

38:45

to get away from that kind

38:47

of system? I mean, to some

38:50

extent, we do see that. We

38:53

don't see it necessarily completely because

38:56

what you have is, you know,

38:58

most central banks still have some

39:00

kind of inflation target. And whether

39:02

you believe that they're targeting the

39:04

right rate of inflation or whether

39:06

you believe that they are... measuring

39:09

it accurately or what have you,

39:11

like that does place an anchor,

39:14

right? Even if I have an

39:16

incredibly misleading measure of inflation, as

39:18

long as the degree to which

39:20

it's misleading isn't changing over time,

39:22

like if it's always wrong, like

39:24

by the same factor, right? Like

39:26

then they're still kind of committing

39:28

to some stability, even if they

39:30

might, you know, even

39:32

if we disagree about whether or not they're doing

39:34

what they say they're doing. I think that But

39:37

I think that that is actually

39:40

motivated by the same thing. I

39:42

mean, the reason why these central

39:44

banks commit to things like inflation

39:46

targeting is for the same reason

39:48

that the Bank of England would

39:50

commit to restore the previous parity

39:52

into gold is that it's providing

39:54

some kind of commitment mechanism. Now,

39:56

of course, they deviate from that

39:59

commitment at times. Like we just

40:01

saw like a pretty large deviation

40:03

from that commitment post pandemic. But

40:07

for the most part, they've

40:09

tried to replace that commitment

40:11

to gold with just the

40:13

vague commitment to price stability.

40:16

And so as long as

40:18

they maintain that commitment, it

40:20

provides at least some anchor

40:22

onto the system that wouldn't

40:24

exist if you didn't have

40:26

any kind of commitment. Jim

40:29

Grant has this nice quip where

40:31

he says that we've replaced the...

40:35

commodity standard, right? The gold

40:37

standard with the PhD standard.

40:39

Or we just rely on

40:41

PhD economists to advise central

40:44

bankers on how to conduct

40:46

monetary policy. And, you

40:48

know, Grant, of course, is saying this in the

40:50

context of look at the loss of constraint that

40:52

we're getting. But the flip

40:54

side of that is that there's

40:56

still some constraint, right? It's not

40:58

totally unconstrained, even if not constrained,

41:00

perhaps the way we would like

41:03

it or to the degree

41:05

that we would like it. This episode is

41:07

brought to you by Casa, the leading Bitcoin

41:09

self -custody solution. I've been

41:11

using Casa since 2019 and I can't recommend

41:13

them enough. Casa have options for

41:16

all Bitcoiners from a two of three multi

41:18

-sig to a three of five and a

41:20

private client option for absolute best in class

41:22

security. Casa also do inheritance

41:24

which I very recently set up and

41:26

it really couldn't be easier. My inheritance

41:28

plan has gone from a vague treasure

41:30

map for my wife to a rock

41:32

solid security plan that I have total

41:34

confidence in. To find out more about

41:36

CASA, go to CASA .io, which is

41:39

CASA .io. This episode is also brought

41:41

to you by Ledger. If

41:43

you're serious about protecting your Bitcoin, Ledger has the

41:45

solution you need. Their hardware

41:47

wallets give you complete control over your private

41:49

keys, ensuring that your Bitcoins stay safe from

41:52

hacks, phishing, and malware. With Ledger's easy -to

41:54

-use devices and the Ledger Live app, managing

41:56

your Bitcoin has never been more convenient. Whether

41:59

you're a long -time holder or new to the world of Bitcoin,

42:02

Ledger makes it simple to keep your assets protected.

42:05

If you want to find out more, visit

42:07

ledger.com and secure your Bitcoin today. That's

42:09

L -E -D -G -E -R dot com.

42:13

And well, that kind of leads on well to

42:15

the next question is that a lot of Bitcoiners

42:17

would have is, do you think all fiat currencies

42:19

are doomed to fail? I

42:25

guess in some abstract sense, everything

42:27

is doomed to fail, right? The

42:29

second law of thermodynamics or something

42:32

like that. I

42:34

think that with fiat monies

42:36

there, as Josh was mentioning

42:38

earlier, there is this difficulty

42:40

where you have both supply

42:42

side problems and demand side

42:44

problems, right? On the supply

42:46

side, a government

42:49

has to... be

42:52

in a position to commit

42:54

not to take advantage of

42:56

its position, right? Otherwise,

42:59

it just prints a bunch of

43:01

money and the value of that

43:04

money goes to zero and people

43:06

eventually abandon it. On

43:08

the demand side, right? It's

43:11

at least conceivable that people

43:13

abandon this money and that

43:16

would also cause its value

43:18

to fall to zero. So

43:21

there is this sort

43:23

of tenuous nature of

43:25

fiat money, both because

43:28

there's always this incentive

43:30

for a less than

43:32

benevolent government to exploit

43:35

its position, and also

43:37

because the introduction of

43:39

alternatives and people switching

43:42

to superior alternatives could

43:44

potentially cause that situation

43:46

to unravel and demand

43:48

to collapse. Bitcoin,

43:51

I think, is

43:54

interesting and

43:58

perhaps unique,

44:02

though at least now there

44:04

are alternatives that mimic this

44:06

to varying degrees. But it's

44:08

interesting because it removes that

44:10

supply side problem. But

44:13

it still faces a demand side

44:15

problem. People can suddenly decide that

44:18

They don't want this anymore. They

44:20

want something else. And

44:22

if that's the case, it goes

44:24

to zero. So

44:27

are fiat monies dooms

44:29

to failure? I think

44:31

that's a cumulative probability

44:33

approaches one. But over

44:35

what time horizon, I'm

44:37

not so confident. I

44:39

would rephrase your question.

44:44

One of my frustrations when people talk

44:46

about the monetary system, and this is

44:48

just in general, whether it's Bitcoiners, whether

44:51

it's people in our profession, whatever.

44:55

People in our profession, for example, seem

44:57

to just assume the status quo just

45:00

will kind of last forever. Whatever the

45:02

status quo is, that's just the way

45:04

the world works, and that's the way

45:06

it will work. Bitcoiners

45:09

have the opposite thing where they're like, no,

45:11

the status quo is unsustainable, so it won't

45:13

last. I mean, if I

45:15

had to choose, I mean,

45:17

I guess it would depend on which time horizon

45:20

that you're giving me. But I mean, the current

45:22

system will end. And

45:24

there's actually a good chance that the

45:26

current system, at least as it is

45:28

constructed with the US dollar being sort

45:30

of the dominant world currency, there is,

45:33

I would argue that there's probably

45:35

a decent likelihood that that doesn't

45:37

last my entire lifetime. I

45:40

mean, I think that, I mean, all

45:42

we have to do is actually just

45:44

look at monetary history, right?

45:46

The classical gold standard lasted for

45:49

about 40 years, right?

45:51

So the classical gold standard, which we think

45:53

is like this long period of price stability,

45:55

it was only 40 years. And then we

45:57

had this kind of weird interwar period. And

45:59

then we had the Bretton Woods system, but

46:01

you know, the Bretton Woods system only lasted,

46:03

you know, you know, the

46:06

Bretton Woods system lasted less than

46:08

40 years. Okay, and so the

46:10

current system that we are that we

46:12

are in has actually lasted longer than

46:14

both of those systems, right? So I

46:17

mean, we're now, you know, 50

46:19

years into Whatever we're calling this dollar

46:21

based system But the thing is is

46:23

to think that that is that that

46:26

we've just reached the end point

46:28

I think is extremely naive and when

46:30

you start to look at things I

46:32

mean you're starting to see policymakers recognize

46:35

this I mean, you know The

46:37

Trump administration very much thinks that

46:39

the international monetary system is unsustainable

46:42

without some kind of significant reform.

46:44

And yes, they want to continue to

46:46

have the dollar be the sort of

46:48

primary global currency, you know, because of

46:50

course they do. That's what states want,

46:53

as I just talked about. But,

46:55

but they clearly see that like the system

46:57

or they clearly believe that the system like

46:59

as it is now is just not sustainable.

47:02

It's leading to. you

47:04

know, persistent trade deficits that tend

47:06

to overvalue the dollar and deplete

47:08

your manufacturing capacity, which turns out

47:10

to be very important for a

47:12

variety of reasons, right? They

47:15

see that this system tends to

47:17

give politicians, you know, politicians

47:19

access to very cheap credit. And what

47:21

do politicians do with very cheap credit?

47:23

They borrow. So we

47:25

have these very, very high

47:27

levels of debt. We've seen

47:30

you know, the we've seen our industrial capacity

47:32

get hollowed out. And they're looking at this

47:35

and saying, hey, you know what, this system

47:37

doesn't really doesn't really work. We want to

47:39

keep the benefits and we want to get

47:41

rid of the costs. Now, that is what

47:43

most people want out of life is to

47:45

increase the benefits and reduce the cost. And

47:47

so it will it'll depend on how they

47:49

go about this and what they what they

47:51

try to do. But there's

47:54

at least certainly a sense that people

47:56

are recognizing that the system isn't

47:58

perfect, even though for the US,

48:00

it works to the US government's

48:02

advantage, even the US government, where

48:04

this is working primarily to their

48:06

advantage, seems to think that this is

48:08

becoming unsustainable. And so I think

48:10

that when we look at it

48:12

from that perspective, given

48:15

that broad sort of historical perspective, I

48:17

mean, I think it would be

48:19

naive to think that the status

48:21

quo was just gonna, inevitably

48:25

continue. Of course, you know, the

48:28

harder question though is what comes next, right? Because what comes

48:30

next might look a lot like the system that we're in,

48:32

or it might look very, very different. So

48:35

in that, what comes next? As

48:37

Bitcoiners, we like to bring up Gresham's law all the time

48:39

and say that good money is going to drive out the

48:41

bad. Do you think it's

48:43

realistic to think that we may end up on

48:45

a Bitcoin standard? And I mean that in sort

48:48

of the fullest sense of the word, where it's

48:50

not just the reserve currency, it's like a unit

48:52

of account and a medium of exchange. Well,

48:55

how about I take on the

48:57

Gresham's Law first and then I

48:59

make Josh answer the harder question.

49:01

Okay. I owe

49:04

him for sticking me with the hard

49:06

question earlier. So

49:08

first, let's, you know, we have

49:10

this like pithy phrase for Gresham's

49:12

Law that, you know, bad money

49:14

drives out good or what have

49:16

you. But

49:19

what we really mean is that legally

49:21

overvalued money drives out legally undervalued money,

49:23

right? And so that really only works

49:25

if we're talking. explain that a bit

49:27

more? I don't know if I fully

49:29

understand what that means. Yeah,

49:31

okay. So suppose that the government says

49:33

that, well, eggs are popular right now,

49:35

right? And so there are two coins,

49:38

right? There's a red coin and a

49:40

blue coin. And the red

49:42

coin will get you a dozen

49:44

eggs and the blue coin will

49:47

get you a dozen eggs, right?

49:50

If in the market, the purchasing

49:52

power of the blue coin is

49:54

actually lower than the purchasing power

49:56

of the red coin, right? So

49:59

red coins are very valuable. They're

50:01

legally overvalued. Blue coins are very

50:03

cheap. Well, we're gonna use the

50:05

blue coins to purchase the eggs, right?

50:08

Everyone wants to use the blue

50:10

coins to purchase the eggs because

50:12

there's this fixed exchange and you

50:15

get a better deal if you're

50:17

using the blue coins. And so

50:19

people... least in egg transactions, they

50:21

hoard those red coins and they

50:23

spend those blue coins, right?

50:26

Now, if you have some kind

50:28

of a fixed exchange rate more

50:31

broadly, right, this is what's gonna

50:33

happen. They're gonna hoard the red

50:35

coins and spend the blue coins

50:38

because the red coins are legally

50:40

overvalued and the blue coins are

50:42

legally undervalued. You saw this, for

50:45

example, a very good, modern example

50:47

of this in Zimbabwe. So Zimbabwe

50:49

was technically dollarized, and

50:51

yet they somehow still managed to

50:53

experience really high rates of inflation.

50:56

That's very odd, right? Because the

50:58

whole reason why a country adopts

51:00

the dollar is to constrain its

51:03

hands, basically to outsource monetary policy.

51:05

Inflation in Zimbabwe should be roughly

51:08

equal to inflation in the US,

51:10

right? They were using the dollar.

51:12

So what happened? Well, what happened

51:15

was that the Zimbabwean government issued

51:17

these bond notes, right? And those

51:19

bond notes were valued one for

51:22

one with the dollar. But one

51:24

of the ways that they issued

51:26

these bond notes was basically as

51:29

a subsidy. And so

51:31

the government would essentially give these

51:33

bond notes away and not get

51:35

anything in exchange for them. So

51:38

they've necessarily issued more bond notes

51:40

than they're in a position to

51:42

redeem one for one. with the

51:45

US dollar. And people

51:47

aren't stupid, right? They understand that the

51:49

Zimbabwean government has done this and these

51:51

bond notes are actually worth less than

51:53

one dollar. So what do they do?

51:55

Well, when they go to the market,

51:58

the law says that you cannot

52:00

discriminate between the bond notes and

52:02

the real McCoy, right? And so

52:05

people spend the bond notes and

52:07

they hoard the real dollars, right?

52:09

Because those bond notes are legally

52:12

undervalued, right? And

52:14

so you can cheaply pay

52:16

with the bond notes and

52:19

it would be expensive to

52:21

pay with the dollars. So

52:24

I think I'm gonna tie my answer back

52:26

to your previous question because one way that

52:28

you can talk about, you know, our fiat

52:31

money is going to die is actually to

52:33

cheat a little bit and point out that

52:35

there are probably way too many fiat currencies

52:37

that actually exist, right? Like there are just

52:39

certain countries that it's not actually clear why

52:41

they have their own currency, like you can't.

52:43

necessarily use it in trade, you

52:46

know, that's very poorly managed. Their

52:49

own citizens would clearly prefer other things.

52:51

You know, I mean, as much as

52:53

we complain about the Federal Reserve or

52:55

the Bank of England or the ECB,

52:58

there are many, many worse places in

53:00

the world and many, many worse central

53:02

banks. When we think about it that

53:04

way, it

53:07

seems almost inevitable that there would

53:09

have to be some consolidation here,

53:11

because yes, states desire this authority,

53:14

yes, states want to control their

53:16

currency, but some states, it doesn't

53:19

seem to make sense why their

53:21

currency exists anyway, right?

53:24

And when they're engaged in international

53:26

trade, they're not even using their

53:28

own currency, and they're mismanaging at

53:31

home. So I think that, if

53:35

you're going to get a Bitcoin standard,

53:38

I think that those places are ripe

53:40

for the change because something like Bitcoin

53:42

could come in and serve that role.

53:44

Now, of course, something like the euro

53:46

or the dollar or the pound or

53:48

something could also serve that role. We

53:50

don't know what they're going to adopt.

53:53

But I think that this is

53:56

actually one of the things that

53:58

we mentioned earlier is that I

54:00

don't think we spend enough time

54:03

thinking about how

54:05

much people are struggling in developing

54:07

countries with their central banks and

54:10

with their currencies and to the

54:12

extent that we recognize the costs

54:14

associated with fiat currencies, they're much,

54:16

much higher there. But

54:19

like I said, I mean, it's

54:22

really, really hard to predict what's

54:24

gonna happen in the future. I

54:26

mean, even if Bitcoin succeeds, however

54:28

we wanna define that, right? What

54:31

does that look like i mean it could

54:33

just be that you know you in the

54:36

u .s. people have dollars and they have

54:38

bitcoin and they can spend either one and

54:40

you know maybe. And so you

54:42

know maybe they hold some of one and some of

54:44

the other and it just depends like maybe it's just

54:46

kind of like you know there are certain places where

54:48

you go where they only take a cash they only

54:50

take cash or they only take. a

54:53

credit card or something like that. Maybe

54:55

there will be certain places that only take dollars

54:58

and then other places that only take Bitcoin and

55:00

other places that take both. I

55:03

think a separate question is then

55:05

whether or not somebody actually redefines

55:07

their unit of account in terms

55:09

of Bitcoin. So they already

55:11

have some existing unit of account,

55:13

but instead of that just being

55:16

some random name for their fiat

55:18

currency, it actually becomes some particular

55:20

amount of Bitcoin. because

55:22

then that's a very, very different scenario because

55:24

there, even if the

55:26

unit of account technically isn't Bitcoin,

55:29

Bitcoin is the medium of account.

55:31

And so at that point, all

55:33

the prices that you observe are

55:35

gonna be entirely determined by the

55:38

demand for Bitcoin. But

55:40

that's a very, very different system than if

55:42

people are kind of using both. But I

55:44

mean, we can imagine a variety of these

55:47

systems, but I also think that, you know,

55:50

I also think it's naive to think that

55:53

a lot of these fiat currencies in some

55:55

of these small developing countries should actually exist

55:57

at all. And even

55:59

beyond developing countries, right? And

56:02

so the question is, what

56:04

do they get replaced with? Do

56:07

they just get replaced with other

56:09

fiat currencies? Do they move back

56:11

towards something like gold or silver?

56:13

Do they move towards Bitcoin? These

56:15

are interesting questions, but I don't

56:18

think that those... currencies really need

56:20

to exist at all, even in

56:22

the current world, without Bitcoin, without

56:24

gold, without any alternative. I still

56:27

don't think that a lot of

56:29

those should exist. What do

56:31

you think Bitcoin is best suited for? What

56:33

role do you think it's best suited for?

56:35

Is it as just a reserve currency or

56:37

why do you think it fits? I

56:40

think that there are lots of

56:42

margins where this might be a

56:44

preferred money. Particularly if

56:47

you're in a place that doesn't have

56:49

a money that has a supply that's

56:51

managed very well. If

56:55

you're making say cross -border payments

56:57

and you don't have access to

56:59

the kind of banking system we

57:01

have here in the US that's

57:03

very well connected. Bitcoin

57:06

is perhaps much easier to get

57:09

for you and much easier to

57:11

transfer. Those

57:14

margins where Bitcoin looks the

57:17

most different from the available

57:19

alternatives are likely to be

57:22

the margins that matter for

57:24

their use case. And

57:27

so things like that

57:29

fixed supply, the

57:32

ease of transfer, the

57:34

not being confined by geographic

57:36

borders. Those are areas where

57:38

Bitcoin looks very different from

57:40

the kind of monies that

57:43

most people use. And

57:45

so I would expect that those are

57:47

the kind of things that are going

57:49

to drive use. It's

57:51

kind of hard to

57:53

predict where it's going

57:55

to go because I have

57:58

spent most of my

58:00

time thinking about how

58:02

governments would try to

58:04

stop Bitcoin. Right. Like, essentially

58:06

every early paper that

58:08

Will and I wrote

58:11

were the bad things governments

58:13

can do. Right. It was

58:15

governments are trying to do this, you know, can

58:17

it work? Governments are trying to do that. Can

58:20

it work? What other things can they do that

58:22

they would, you know, what other things might they

58:24

try? And so now, like,

58:26

you know, you we find ourselves in

58:28

a situation where you've got countries talking

58:30

about, you know, strategic Bitcoin reserves and

58:32

things like that, which is something that.

58:35

you know, we never would have thought

58:37

of. Super weird. You

58:39

know, several years ago, like you

58:41

would think that states would be

58:43

more opposed to this kind of

58:45

a thing. I

58:47

mean, I think in part this is

58:49

actually related to the conversation earlier. I

58:52

mean, I think one of the reasons

58:54

that maybe certain politicians in the US

58:56

have changed is that, you know, if

58:59

you're looking at the system and you're

59:01

seeing that it's unsustainable, you

59:04

get a lot of benefits from the

59:06

system even though there are also some

59:08

costs. And so what

59:11

the United States government really fears

59:13

is they fear that there's going

59:15

to be some other state that

59:17

will capture those benefits, right? That

59:19

somebody will start using a different

59:21

currency instead of the dollar and

59:23

that all of the benefits that

59:26

the US gets from the dollar

59:28

being the global reserve currency will

59:30

just transfer to this other

59:32

country that's issuing this alternative. And

59:35

I think that if you are concerned

59:38

about that thing, then one of the

59:40

things that you might want to do

59:42

is you might want to encourage countries

59:44

to buy more neutral assets, to buy

59:47

things like gold and to buy things

59:49

like Bitcoin to hold and reserve, because

59:51

you're not transferring any of the benefits

59:54

of the dollar system to those things,

59:56

at least not the benefits that go

59:58

to the United States government, right? by

1:00:01

shifting them towards neutral assets, yes, maybe you're

1:00:03

losing a little bit of power, but you're

1:00:06

not losing it at the, you know, relative

1:00:08

to some, you know, to someone else, like

1:00:10

someone else is gaining at your, yeah, they're

1:00:12

not, they're not gaining at your expense. And

1:00:15

so, and so I think

1:00:17

that partially explains these attitudes, but I also

1:00:19

think that that's important to think about because

1:00:21

I think when we're thinking about the path,

1:00:23

so many times like what we do is

1:00:26

we think about, okay, What are the possible

1:00:28

paths? How would we get there? What's this

1:00:30

going to look like? But we tend to

1:00:32

focus on the characteristics of Bitcoin in determining

1:00:35

these things. We tend to look at, OK,

1:00:38

is it going to be useful as

1:00:40

a medium of exchange? Is everybody going

1:00:42

to be able to transact on the

1:00:44

base layer? Those are

1:00:46

the things that we focus on and think

1:00:48

about. But I think that we ignore

1:00:51

all of these geopolitical concerns because

1:00:53

I think that the changing attitude

1:00:56

about Bitcoin is to a large

1:00:58

extent driven by, you know, um,

1:01:01

changes in geopolitical circumstances. And so those

1:01:03

changes force people to think about things

1:01:05

differently. And so now, um,

1:01:08

whatever you were predicting five years ago

1:01:10

about the future of Bitcoin, um,

1:01:12

it's almost certainly different than what you would predict

1:01:14

now because you've seen how that plays out. And

1:01:16

so I think it's important to us to. So

1:01:18

I guess what I'm saying is so many times

1:01:21

we just focus on Bitcoin itself and what it

1:01:23

does. and how it compares to

1:01:25

the alternatives and what that means about the

1:01:27

future. But one of the

1:01:29

things that we don't spend enough time

1:01:31

is like, what are the things like

1:01:34

completely detached from Bitcoin that somehow end

1:01:36

up relating to Bitcoin in the long

1:01:38

run, right? What are these things that

1:01:40

no one thought would be, would be

1:01:42

something significant for Bitcoin's future that now

1:01:45

suddenly look like super significant for how

1:01:47

everything plays out? And I think, that's

1:01:49

the big thing that we tend to

1:01:51

miss. And I think that's the thing

1:01:53

that actually makes it really, really hard.

1:01:56

All the technological stuff, like, my

1:01:58

basic view is all the technological

1:02:00

problems that people are worried about,

1:02:02

like, I tend

1:02:04

to think that, you know, those technological problems,

1:02:07

to the extent they can be solved, they'll

1:02:09

be solved. Like, because there's an incentive to

1:02:11

solve them in private markets, tend to figure

1:02:13

out things, right? When people want things, entrepreneurs

1:02:16

tend to figure out ways to

1:02:18

deliver them. It's those

1:02:20

external things. outside of Bitcoin that suddenly

1:02:22

are super important to Bitcoin that are

1:02:25

the hardest to predict. And that's what

1:02:27

makes it hardest to kind of forecast

1:02:29

like where is this going to be

1:02:32

in five years, let alone 50 years.

1:02:35

And that's like the game theory of Bitcoin

1:02:37

playing out, I guess, because if the push

1:02:39

is to move people to a neutral asset,

1:02:41

like the US already owns more gold than

1:02:43

anyone else. So the theory here

1:02:45

is that they then also have to own more Bitcoin

1:02:47

than anyone else if that's going to be. the

1:02:50

kind of neutral reserve asset. Well,

1:02:54

in part of what you're doing, if

1:02:56

you if you created a strategic Bitcoin

1:02:58

reserve, for example, is like what you

1:03:00

would be doing is yes, like potentially

1:03:03

if you if you bought Bitcoin now

1:03:05

and then Bitcoin became more, you know,

1:03:07

became incredibly successful and became, you know,

1:03:09

a significant part of our global financial

1:03:12

system, then yes, you would also then

1:03:14

the United States government would also profit

1:03:16

from that. But beyond that, I think

1:03:19

one like

1:03:21

overlooked aspect when it comes to that thing is

1:03:23

like, it just provides a signal, right? Like there

1:03:25

are lots of people out there who know what

1:03:27

Bitcoin is, but they don't understand it, they don't

1:03:29

look into it, they don't, they're certainly not gonna

1:03:32

buy it, right? Like, but they know what it

1:03:34

is, they just think maybe, okay, this thing is

1:03:36

like this weird internet money, maybe it's kind of

1:03:38

sketchy, like who are these people? Like, I don't

1:03:40

understand, what do you mean nobody's in charge, right?

1:03:42

Like this kind of stuff, but like, if somebody

1:03:44

like the United States government comes along and says,

1:03:46

hey, we're gonna buy this, well, suddenly there are

1:03:49

gonna be a lot of people that are just

1:03:51

kind of like, ah, well, it must not be

1:03:53

that bad, right? Like, oh, it must be okay

1:03:55

to use. And so it kind of creates a

1:03:57

permission structure for people to start adopting. And

1:04:00

that's true at both the individual

1:04:02

level, but then also other states,

1:04:04

right? And so if you're trying

1:04:06

to use this for geopolitical purposes,

1:04:08

sending that signal to other states

1:04:10

could potentially Um, you know,

1:04:13

it becomes a self -fulfilling prophecy, right? Like

1:04:15

we need people to do this other thing.

1:04:17

And so we're going to buy some to

1:04:19

signal that that they should buy it. And

1:04:22

so then they buy it because we bought

1:04:24

it, right? Like it becomes a sort of

1:04:26

self -fulfilling thing. And I think that, um,

1:04:28

all of these geopolitical, you know, considerations are

1:04:30

something that, um, you know, I

1:04:33

think maybe Bitcoiners would say, Hey, we always

1:04:35

predicted there would be the, you know, Bitcoin

1:04:37

would be, um, important

1:04:40

geopolitically. I don't know how many of them

1:04:42

had 2025 as the year when that would

1:04:44

happen, right? So, yeah. So

1:04:47

I think that that's probably

1:04:49

the most surprising and interesting

1:04:51

thing that's going on right

1:04:53

now is just how much

1:04:55

that narrative has changed. Definitely.

1:04:58

And there's a few other things I want to get into.

1:05:00

Will, are you okay for time or do you need to

1:05:02

run? Yeah, I

1:05:04

need to go in about six minutes. 5 minutes. Sorry,

1:05:07

Will. I didn't realize you had a hard stop there.

1:05:09

No, it's okay. Thank you very much for coming on

1:05:11

for this bit and we'll carry on without you. In

1:05:13

fact, before you go, Will, though, is there any way

1:05:15

you want to send anyone if they want to follow

1:05:17

your work or anything you're doing? I'm

1:05:20

on X at William J.

1:05:22

Luther. I

1:05:25

write pretty regularly at the American Institute

1:05:27

for Economic Research. So

1:05:29

feel free to follow along. Perfect.

1:05:32

Thank you, Will. And we can do this again. Yeah,

1:05:34

sounds good. All right. Sorry,

1:05:36

Josh. This is, there's too much in

1:05:39

this. But so the next

1:05:41

thing, we were just never going to get through

1:05:43

the next part in five minutes. So rather than

1:05:45

cut it short, the next

1:05:47

thing I wanted to talk about

1:05:50

was deflationary money. And

1:05:52

one of the things that a lot

1:05:54

of economists have sort of criticized Bitcoin

1:05:56

for is the fact that deflationary money

1:05:58

may not work in reality. So what's

1:06:00

your take on that? And I think

1:06:03

probably that perspective comes from thinking people

1:06:05

are going to hoard money rather than spend it and

1:06:07

what that does to the economy. Yeah,

1:06:10

so there's actually like this

1:06:12

is actually one thing that

1:06:14

economic historians and monetary economists

1:06:16

are I think are actually

1:06:18

good at, which is there's

1:06:20

a lot of stuff that

1:06:22

they've written about deflation because

1:06:24

the bad rap of deflation

1:06:26

seems to come from the

1:06:28

Great Depression. So we have

1:06:30

this horrible recession, which also

1:06:32

corresponds with this dramatic deflation.

1:06:34

And so it must be

1:06:36

that deflation is bad. But

1:06:40

that story is

1:06:42

at least partially

1:06:44

wrong. And

1:06:46

the reason for that is

1:06:49

we can really kind of

1:06:51

classify deflation as having two

1:06:53

causes. There's like supply side

1:06:55

causes and there's demand side

1:06:57

causes. But demand side causes

1:07:00

are actually really policy induced

1:07:02

causes, right? So demand side

1:07:04

causes tend to be like, if you get

1:07:06

deflation from the demand side, it's generally because

1:07:08

you have really, really bad policy. Okay,

1:07:11

so there's some kind of policy that's

1:07:14

being imposed on society by, you know,

1:07:16

the central bank that's causing this deflation.

1:07:18

And that's very, very different from a

1:07:20

supply driven deflation. So

1:07:23

supply driven deflations, first of

1:07:25

all, we've experienced them. you

1:07:27

know, historically actually quite a

1:07:29

bit. And they're not

1:07:32

associated with recessions. In fact, they're

1:07:34

associated with boom periods because periods

1:07:36

of periods of high productivity are

1:07:38

periods when things are going well,

1:07:40

right? But when when's the like

1:07:42

recent example of that? Well,

1:07:45

there are, I mean, recent examples,

1:07:47

we live in an inflationary world.

1:07:49

So I mean, But if you

1:07:51

go back to like the classical

1:07:54

gold standard era, like there are

1:07:56

prolonged periods where you have deflation

1:07:58

and where it's not costly. And

1:08:01

it makes sense because if you think about

1:08:03

it, right, what's

1:08:06

happening is that if

1:08:08

you have growing productivity

1:08:10

and that growing productivity

1:08:13

is driving down prices,

1:08:15

it's effectively increasing the real

1:08:18

value of wages for people,

1:08:20

right? And so that productivity

1:08:22

is reflected in your wage,

1:08:24

even though maybe your nominal

1:08:26

wage isn't changing, what

1:08:29

that wage buys you is changing, right?

1:08:31

So now you can afford a lot

1:08:33

more stuff. And so

1:08:35

kind of the idea here

1:08:37

is that these productivity changes,

1:08:40

the supply side, driven

1:08:43

deflations are actually very, very

1:08:45

positive. These are boom

1:08:48

periods. These are periods when things

1:08:50

are going well. And

1:08:52

there's no fundamental problem with

1:08:55

deflation, right? Because

1:08:57

since prices are falling, your real

1:09:00

wages are going up. In contrast,

1:09:02

when you have these demand -side

1:09:04

deflations where this is policy -induced,

1:09:08

The reason these tend to be so costly

1:09:10

is it's not based on real economic factors,

1:09:12

right? It's not that we just have a

1:09:14

bunch more stuff to sell with the same

1:09:16

amount of demand, right? It's that there is,

1:09:20

it's that these changes have

1:09:22

been caused by policymakers making

1:09:24

bad choices. And so

1:09:27

because of that, these events are

1:09:29

unexpected and unexpected deflation could be

1:09:31

really costly because we have nominal

1:09:34

debt contracts, right? So if I

1:09:36

agree, if I borrow $1 ,000

1:09:38

from you. And

1:09:41

so let's say my day job is as

1:09:43

a farmer and I borrow $1 ,000 from

1:09:45

you and then over the course of the

1:09:47

next year, unexpectedly, the prices of my crops

1:09:50

all start to fall. Well, it becomes a

1:09:52

lot harder for me to pay back that

1:09:54

$1 ,000. But if

1:09:56

that decline in... prices was caused

1:09:59

by productivity, it wouldn't be any

1:10:01

harder for me to pay you

1:10:03

back because the reason that the

1:10:05

price is down is because I'm

1:10:07

producing more stuff. Right.

1:10:09

And so, um, and so what really matters

1:10:11

is like what I am, how much I'm

1:10:13

selling, what I'm bringing in. And

1:10:15

so, um, and so

1:10:18

in other words, supply driven deflation

1:10:20

is very, very positive demand driven

1:10:22

deflation is policy driven deflation. And

1:10:24

yes, those do seem to be

1:10:26

costly, but that's the result of

1:10:28

policymakers making bad choices. That's not

1:10:30

like an inherent evil of deflation.

1:10:33

And so if we have a

1:10:35

productivity induced deflation, that's generally a

1:10:37

good thing. So deflation,

1:10:39

is deflation impossible in the fiat system

1:10:41

that we're in now in this positive

1:10:44

deflation? I mean, technically

1:10:46

no. I mean, if, but it would

1:10:48

take it would require central banks to

1:10:50

do something, you know, much, much different.

1:10:53

So I mean, you could You

1:10:55

can imagine this scenario. I mean, it's not ever

1:10:58

going to happen, but I can conjure it up

1:11:00

and I can tell you about it. I mean,

1:11:03

suppose the Federal Reserve came out tomorrow

1:11:05

and said, we're just going to make

1:11:07

sure that nominal spending in the United

1:11:09

States is just constant, right? So the

1:11:12

dollar value of spending is constant. And

1:11:14

we're just gonna, and because it's nominal,

1:11:16

we can adjust the money supply. to

1:11:19

keep it constant. So if it ever starts to rise,

1:11:21

we can pull money out of the system. If it ever

1:11:23

starts to fall, we can add money to the system.

1:11:26

Okay, so imagine they did that, and imagine they did

1:11:29

that well. Okay, well, if

1:11:31

you think about what would happen in that sort of a

1:11:33

system, if nominal spending

1:11:35

can never change, as

1:11:37

the economy grows, prices would have to

1:11:39

fall in conjunction with that growth in

1:11:41

the economy, right? Because real GDP would

1:11:43

be going up, even though nominal GDP

1:11:45

would be constant. And so the only

1:11:47

way that nominal GDP could be constant

1:11:49

is that that economic growth, those productivity

1:11:51

improvements would have to be passed on

1:11:53

through prices. The challenge

1:11:56

to doing something like that is

1:11:58

number one, like there's just this

1:12:00

kind of irrational hatred of deflation

1:12:02

that that we see. So, you

1:12:04

know, central bankers would not be

1:12:06

inclined to adopt that sort of

1:12:08

thing. But also

1:12:10

like central bankers don't They

1:12:12

don't tend to focus on

1:12:14

things like nominal spending or

1:12:16

nominal income or something like

1:12:18

that. They tend to try

1:12:21

to focus on inflation rates

1:12:23

and things like that. And

1:12:25

actually, Will mentioned George

1:12:27

Seljan. George Seljan had a lot

1:12:29

of work on this where he

1:12:31

basically had argued that, and this

1:12:33

is actually not original to George.

1:12:35

I mean, this was part of

1:12:38

an earlier tradition in economics that

1:12:40

kind of died with Keynesianism. which

1:12:42

was that, you know, actually maintaining stable

1:12:45

prices through monetary policy might actually be

1:12:47

distortionary because in order to do that,

1:12:49

you might be forcing prices that otherwise

1:12:51

would have gone down to go up,

1:12:54

right? In the same way that you're

1:12:56

forcing prices that would have gone up

1:12:58

to come down. And so you can

1:13:01

potentially end up distorting relative prices because

1:13:03

you're not allowing relative prices to reflect

1:13:05

relative scarcity of these goods. I see.

1:13:07

And George Sheldon was, he's a big

1:13:10

proponent of free banking, I think, isn't

1:13:12

he? Yes. So I assume he thinks

1:13:14

that central banks shouldn't exist. A lot

1:13:16

of Bitcoiners think that central banks shouldn't

1:13:19

exist. Do you think that is something

1:13:21

that's likely at any point in the

1:13:23

future, or like relatively near future, 10,

1:13:26

20, 30 years? I mean,

1:13:28

I think the biggest challenge to this, right,

1:13:30

is what we talked about with respect to...

1:13:33

You know why states want a monopoly

1:13:35

on money to begin with right like

1:13:37

they want the monopoly on money because

1:13:39

they want access to credit from the

1:13:42

central bank They want to be able

1:13:44

to pay for things They want to

1:13:46

be able to finance wars without worrying

1:13:48

about where the money is gonna come

1:13:50

from and things like that and so

1:13:52

I Think it would be really really

1:13:54

hard to To get rid of central

1:13:57

banks in that sense. I mean it

1:13:59

would take I'm

1:14:01

not saying that it's impossible,

1:14:03

it's just difficult, because it

1:14:06

would also take a substantial

1:14:08

rethinking and reeducation of a

1:14:11

lot of people, right? Because

1:14:13

typically, you know, when

1:14:15

I look at how a lot of

1:14:17

introductory textbooks, you know, to economics are

1:14:19

framed, especially sort of like the Keynesian

1:14:21

leaning textbooks, right? Like the... chapter on

1:14:24

central banking is kind of like, well,

1:14:26

of course, we have to have a

1:14:28

central bank because who's going to manage

1:14:30

the currency and we don't want another

1:14:32

great depression. You know, forgetting the fact

1:14:34

that like we all had central banks

1:14:36

other than Canada, we all had central

1:14:38

banks during the Great Depression. So, you

1:14:40

know, that that actually didn't seem to

1:14:42

help very much. If anything,

1:14:45

it actually seemed to make things worse. But

1:14:47

but the point is, is like those are

1:14:49

the kinds of arguments that you get is

1:14:51

like, well, of course, we have to have

1:14:53

somebody do this and, you know, and and.

1:14:55

You know, I mean,

1:14:57

I write about this actually all the

1:15:00

time is that to me, one

1:15:02

of the weirdest things about economics is

1:15:04

that when you take economics classes,

1:15:06

what gets drilled into your head is

1:15:08

that what's good is competition, right?

1:15:10

Competition is good. We like competition. Competition

1:15:13

leads to efficient outcomes. We're

1:15:15

not wasting resources, right? These

1:15:17

kinds of things. And what's bad? are

1:15:21

monopolies, right? Like monopolies don't

1:15:23

efficiently use resources. Monopolies, you

1:15:25

know, have this power that

1:15:27

this market power that allows them to

1:15:29

charge a price above marginal costs, you

1:15:31

know. And central

1:15:33

banking good. Yeah. And so

1:15:36

and then from that, then they immediately

1:15:38

jump to, well, of course, we need

1:15:40

a monopoly over currency, right? So and

1:15:42

so to me, it's kind of bizarre.

1:15:45

And I mean, and And

1:15:47

to me, I think that I understand why

1:15:49

I think it's actually all of these these

1:15:51

political concerns and geopolitical concerns that are the

1:15:53

reason that central banks actually exist. And I

1:15:55

think that's the thing that makes them hardest to

1:15:57

change or get rid of. But

1:16:00

those but that's often not how we teach

1:16:02

it. And in fact, arguably, I guess if

1:16:04

you taught if everybody taught it the way

1:16:06

that I teach it and everybody taught, you

1:16:08

know, the sort of political

1:16:11

and geopolitical aspects to this, then I don't

1:16:13

know, maybe that would actually arose support for

1:16:15

these things is like, well, wait a second,

1:16:17

if we just need this for geopolitical purposes,

1:16:20

surely there's some alternative here, right? But

1:16:23

yeah, I mean, a lot of it is

1:16:25

just the way it's presented. And then the

1:16:27

role that it plays for the state, that

1:16:30

makes it very, very hard to get rid

1:16:32

of. If you could just

1:16:34

click your fingers and have your perfectly

1:16:36

designed economic system, would the be central

1:16:38

banks? It's a

1:16:40

hard question for me to

1:16:43

answer because as an individual

1:16:45

the answer is obvious. It's

1:16:47

no but like my hesitancy

1:16:49

in just saying no completely

1:16:51

is that It's hard to

1:16:54

imagine what this world looks

1:16:56

looks like in geopolitical like

1:16:58

concerns right like so I

1:17:00

Don't like that. I personally

1:17:02

do not like the extent

1:17:05

to which the United States

1:17:07

involves itself in foreign conflicts

1:17:10

Okay. But I

1:17:12

do like the fact that the United States doesn't

1:17:14

have to worry about, you know, how much it's

1:17:16

spending in the event that we go to war.

1:17:18

I don't have to worry that, like, we're going

1:17:20

to lose because we run out of money. I

1:17:24

mean, this was a very, very

1:17:26

common thing, you know, in an

1:17:28

earlier era. I mean, people forget

1:17:30

that the Swedes had an entire

1:17:32

Baltic Empire. And, you

1:17:34

know, Sweden was a military power.

1:17:37

And the reason that they really lost

1:17:39

this military power is that they couldn't,

1:17:41

they couldn't finance their military, right?

1:17:44

Like they just, they actually just ran out of

1:17:46

funding to the point where there are stories

1:17:48

of soldiers out in the field, like picking up

1:17:50

the musket balls that have just been fired at

1:17:52

them and then loading them into their guns

1:17:54

so they can shoot back, right? And

1:17:57

so the thing is, is

1:18:00

like the question is, can

1:18:02

the place that you live

1:18:05

provide adequate defense? without

1:18:08

something like a central bank. And if the answer

1:18:10

is no, then this becomes a really hard question

1:18:12

to answer because on the one hand, if they

1:18:15

can't do it without it, well, then your safety

1:18:17

and security and wealth is under threat, right? But

1:18:20

at the same time, if they can, they,

1:18:22

you know, some of them do really bad

1:18:24

things with that, with that power and some

1:18:26

of them get involved in things that they

1:18:28

shouldn't get involved in. And so it's very

1:18:30

hard to assess that. But I mean, if

1:18:32

I'm just thinking about it purely in monetary

1:18:34

terms and not thinking about any of these

1:18:36

geopolitical concerns. I think the answer is obvious,

1:18:38

like, no, we don't want these things. To

1:18:41

the extent that we have to think

1:18:43

about these geopolitical concerns, we can possibly

1:18:46

get rid of central banks, but there's

1:18:48

probably going to be something else that

1:18:50

states would do as an alternative. And

1:18:52

the fact that they haven't done that

1:18:54

already suggests that maybe there's not an

1:18:56

obvious better alternative. So it needs,

1:18:59

it can't just be that the US gets rid of the Fed

1:19:01

is every central bank needs to go at the same time for

1:19:03

it to be sustainable. Yeah, because I

1:19:05

mean, like if you think about it, like if

1:19:08

they're really providing this source of funding, you

1:19:10

know, that was one, I mean, that

1:19:12

was one reason why you, you know,

1:19:14

but that was one reason to attack

1:19:16

like the neighboring Prince, right? In Europe,

1:19:18

you know, 400 years ago is like

1:19:20

he has no money. So like now's

1:19:23

the time I could take that land.

1:19:25

Yeah. And so, and so the thing

1:19:28

is, it's like, you know, we're

1:19:30

sort of stuck in

1:19:32

this particular equilibrium. where

1:19:35

if none of us had this stuff, then it wouldn't

1:19:37

matter. But because all of us have this stuff, nobody

1:19:39

has an incentive to go first. Yeah,

1:19:42

that makes sense. Okay, last big

1:19:44

question in this future Bitcoin world,

1:19:46

what do you think credit will

1:19:48

look like? So

1:19:51

I guess it kind of depends. I think

1:19:53

that you're asking me this because a lot

1:19:55

of people kind of argue like, oh, well,

1:19:57

nobody would want to borrow because you have

1:19:59

a deflationary currency. So why would you want

1:20:01

to borrow? But I think that that is

1:20:03

based on thinking about

1:20:05

borrowing and lending purely in

1:20:07

terms of nominal interest rates.

1:20:11

When we should be thinking about it in terms

1:20:13

of real interest rates. And so what I mean

1:20:15

is, is like, okay, if I

1:20:17

come to you and I say, hey, I

1:20:19

need to borrow a thousand dollars and you

1:20:22

say, okay, just pay me back, you know,

1:20:24

a thousand and fifty dollars a year from

1:20:26

now and we'll call it even. Well,

1:20:29

what really matters. is what

1:20:31

the purchasing power of $1 ,050 is

1:20:34

a year from now, right? So if

1:20:36

over the next year we have 5

1:20:38

% inflation, well, then

1:20:40

I got a really good deal because

1:20:42

all of the purchasing power that I'm

1:20:45

transferring to you has been, you know,

1:20:47

is gone, right? Like you, you're getting

1:20:49

no additional purchasing power relative to that

1:20:52

initial $1 ,000. And

1:20:54

so implicitly, we don't always think

1:20:56

about it this way, but implicitly,

1:20:58

we're always thinking about real interest

1:21:01

rates. So we're thinking about what

1:21:03

the interest rate is adjusted for

1:21:05

inflation on these loans. And

1:21:08

so that's the fundamental

1:21:11

thing that really matters.

1:21:15

Now, because we live in an inflationary

1:21:17

world, if I'm willing to pay you

1:21:19

5 % real interest and the inflation

1:21:21

rate is going to be like, and

1:21:24

we both expect the inflation rate to

1:21:26

say be 2 % over the next

1:21:28

year, Then the nominal interest

1:21:30

rate on that loan would be 7%.

1:21:32

But that's just a matter of we

1:21:34

agree that that's like the likely inflation

1:21:37

rate and I'm willing to borrow at

1:21:39

5%, you're willing to lend at 5

1:21:41

% in real terms. If

1:21:45

we move to a deflationary system, the

1:21:47

real interest rate is still the thing that

1:21:50

matters. And so because the real interest

1:21:52

rate is still the thing that matters, nominal interest rates

1:21:54

would be very, very different. So if

1:21:56

we're in a deflationary environment, And

1:21:58

maybe deflation is, you know, so

1:22:01

maybe, you know, the inflation rate

1:22:03

is negative 2 % a year.

1:22:05

Well, then now the nominal interest

1:22:07

rate instead of being 7 %

1:22:10

is going to be 3%. But

1:22:12

in real terms, it's costing me

1:22:14

5%. And so the deflation would

1:22:16

tend to drive nominal interest rates

1:22:18

down. And by driving nominal interest

1:22:21

rates down, the question is, does

1:22:23

anything about this actually change? the

1:22:25

real interest rate. Because if it

1:22:27

doesn't change the real interest rate,

1:22:29

then we're not going to see

1:22:32

any sort of change in borrowing

1:22:34

activity because nominal interest rates would

1:22:36

just change, but real interest rates

1:22:38

would all be the same. Now,

1:22:41

there is reason to believe that real interest

1:22:43

rates might change in that sort of environment.

1:22:45

And the reason is, is that in economics,

1:22:48

there's this thing called the Tobin effect. And

1:22:50

what the Tobin effect describes is that There

1:22:52

are certain things that we hold in our

1:22:54

portfolio that we also use for productive purposes,

1:22:57

right? And so, um, and

1:23:00

so what happens, like so, you know,

1:23:02

like an obvious example for an individual

1:23:04

will be their house, right? Like you're

1:23:06

not just investing in your house, you

1:23:08

live in it. Okay. But it's part

1:23:10

of your portfolio of assets. Well, if

1:23:12

you live in a world where inflation

1:23:14

starts rising, what do you do? Um,

1:23:16

well, you tend to by more housing,

1:23:18

right? So either you buy a second

1:23:21

home or you buy a bigger house

1:23:23

than you would have bought otherwise or

1:23:25

something like that. And what that tends

1:23:27

to do is that tends to raise

1:23:29

the real value of those assets, but

1:23:31

it tends to reduce the real rate

1:23:33

of return on those assets relative to

1:23:35

what they were before the inflation. So

1:23:38

what then happens is that in

1:23:40

that scenario, in an inflationary environment,

1:23:42

inflation is actually lowering real interest

1:23:45

rates. which makes borrowing more likely,

1:23:48

right? And so if you were to

1:23:50

eliminate inflation or actually move to a

1:23:52

deflationary system, then what would happen is

1:23:54

like these real asset values would decline,

1:23:56

but their real rates of return would

1:23:59

rise. And so then you would be

1:24:01

less likely to borrow because real interest

1:24:03

rates are going to be higher in

1:24:05

that in that world. But

1:24:07

it's not going to eliminate all borrowing.

1:24:09

But that's also because if your money

1:24:12

isn't constantly being eroded over time through

1:24:14

inflation, then you don't need to constantly

1:24:16

look for other investments. Right,

1:24:19

right. So, like an inflationary

1:24:21

system, you do tend

1:24:23

to drive real interest rates down to

1:24:26

some extent because people try to avoid

1:24:28

inflation by buying real assets, right? Things

1:24:30

that they think are going to appreciate

1:24:32

over the longer term and that or

1:24:34

at least maintain their purchasing power over

1:24:36

the longer term, right? Like, maybe you

1:24:38

buy a little bit bigger house because

1:24:40

you're like, well, I know that like,

1:24:42

you know, um, housing, um, is going

1:24:44

to be, you know, more stable than,

1:24:46

you know, um, the supply of

1:24:49

houses is not going to increase at the rate

1:24:51

of growth of the money supply. Right. So I,

1:24:53

so I have a little bit more confidence that,

1:24:55

that this is going to retain its value. And

1:24:58

to the extent that, and even to the

1:25:00

extent that, that it doesn't, like I get

1:25:03

to live in it. So I'm getting some

1:25:05

value out of it, even if I'm wrong

1:25:07

about that. Right. But in general, what, what

1:25:09

tends to happen is, yeah, people. in inflationary

1:25:11

environments, they move into real assets. And that

1:25:14

does tend to lower real interest rates. And

1:25:16

so, which does encourage more borrowing. And so

1:25:18

if you move to a deflationary system, yes,

1:25:20

you would have less, I think you would

1:25:22

have less borrowing because you, because you're going

1:25:25

to see the reversal of that effect, right?

1:25:27

So if your money is now appreciating every

1:25:29

year in real terms, well, then

1:25:31

you don't need to buy a bigger house.

1:25:33

You don't need to buy an extra house.

1:25:35

You don't need to invest in those real

1:25:38

assets because you're not trying to avoid the

1:25:40

the inflation. And so in that case, you

1:25:42

know, real interest rates would would rise and

1:25:44

we'd get and we'd get less borrowing. And

1:25:47

where does fractional reserve banking fit into this?

1:25:49

Do you think we'll still have fractional reserve

1:25:51

banking under a Bitcoin standard? I

1:25:53

mean, it it depends. I

1:25:56

mean, I think I mean, my attitude on

1:25:58

this is that in the short run, like

1:26:00

Bitcoiners should really resist this as much as

1:26:02

possible. because it

1:26:04

would be a source

1:26:07

of manipulation in the

1:26:09

market given Bitcoin's market

1:26:11

cap. Any

1:26:13

kind of like fractional reserve system

1:26:15

right now would just make it very,

1:26:17

very easy to manipulate the system.

1:26:20

Over the long run, I don't know

1:26:23

if you can necessarily prevent it. And

1:26:26

the reason that I say

1:26:28

that is that like a

1:26:30

fractional reserve system would be

1:26:32

the easiest way to scale

1:26:34

if it becomes too costly

1:26:36

to transact on the base

1:26:38

layer. Now,

1:26:42

the issue though

1:26:44

is that because

1:26:46

Bitcoin is programmable

1:26:49

money, as they

1:26:51

say, even

1:26:56

a fractional reserve system would probably

1:26:58

look much different than the fractional

1:27:00

reserve systems that we have experienced,

1:27:02

right? And

1:27:04

what I mean by that

1:27:07

is that, if you had

1:27:09

banks that were sort of

1:27:11

issuing more liabilities than what

1:27:13

they had in reserve as

1:27:16

Bitcoin, there could

1:27:18

be ways where you could actually,

1:27:20

you know, Where

1:27:22

you can actually verify like what their

1:27:24

issuance is what their you know how

1:27:27

much that they have in reserve and

1:27:29

also. You know

1:27:31

if you have. You

1:27:34

know if you have on demand redeem ability

1:27:36

anytime that you know you're uncomfortable with what

1:27:38

they do you can potentially do that or

1:27:40

you could just have instances where some people

1:27:42

just actually like agree not to use their

1:27:44

bitcoin for some certain amount of time in

1:27:46

exchange for. Paying a rate

1:27:48

of return or something on that so that

1:27:50

other people can can use it but so

1:27:52

there might be ways to avoid it But

1:27:54

I think like the issue is is the

1:27:57

the question of whether or not we'll get

1:27:59

fractional reserve on Bitcoin I think we should

1:28:01

resist that now like there's no need for

1:28:03

like Bitcoin banks that are issuing You know

1:28:05

pieces of paper that are redeemable for Bitcoin.

1:28:07

There's no there's no need for that now

1:28:09

People should resist that now But

1:28:13

then the question is is it's all

1:28:16

going to boil down to like how

1:28:18

things scale right so in terms of

1:28:20

like if if the base layer becomes

1:28:22

too expensive for Transactions to be going

1:28:25

on all the time the easiest way

1:28:27

to solve that is to figure out

1:28:29

how to make transactions outside of the

1:28:32

base layer and and then the question

1:28:34

is is then you know Does that

1:28:36

require you know issuing claims to Bitcoin?

1:28:41

that are redeemable for Bitcoin or something like

1:28:43

that. Or are there just

1:28:45

technological solutions that we can use that would

1:28:47

solve that problem? And so

1:28:49

history says it's gonna be hard to

1:28:52

avoid that kind of a system because

1:28:54

that's just what we've observed over time.

1:28:57

But at the same time, again,

1:28:59

it's very, very hard to predict

1:29:01

the future because this is very,

1:29:03

very different than other traditional forms

1:29:05

of money. gold

1:29:08

where it's literally just this

1:29:10

physical thing that you hold.

1:29:13

Conceivably, there are technological solutions that

1:29:15

could exist for Bitcoin that just

1:29:17

can't possibly exist for something like

1:29:19

gold or silver. Love

1:29:21

it. Well, this has been great. Thank

1:29:24

you very much, Josh. We've been through

1:29:26

most of the big topics there. But

1:29:28

we obviously, we started this conversation where

1:29:31

I kind of jokingly made fun of

1:29:33

economists for not understanding Bitcoin. But what

1:29:35

is it that you think Bitcoiners don't

1:29:37

understand about economics? I

1:29:40

would add, well, okay, there's a

1:29:42

line. There's

1:29:46

a line that one of my favorite

1:29:48

economists, a guy named Armin Alchin, there's

1:29:51

a line that he used to say,

1:29:53

which was don't listen to economists listen

1:29:55

to don't listen to what economists have

1:29:57

to say, listen to what economics has

1:29:59

to say. Okay. And I've

1:30:02

always really liked that line because the

1:30:04

thing is, is that economists are just

1:30:06

people, right? And they have lots of

1:30:08

opinions and those opinions might be informed

1:30:10

by economics. They might not be informed

1:30:12

by economics. It depends on the

1:30:14

context, but even if they are informed

1:30:16

by economics, like sometimes, you know, it's,

1:30:18

hey, I have this knowledge and given

1:30:20

my knowledge, this is my opinion, but

1:30:22

that doesn't mean that that's what economics

1:30:24

actually says. That's how they interpret things.

1:30:27

And so, I mean, my thing is, is

1:30:29

that, I

1:30:31

get like basically one of two responses

1:30:33

when I meet Bitcoiners, right? Bitcoiners are

1:30:36

either really super excited that an economist

1:30:38

is there to talk, you know, it

1:30:40

wants to talk about Bitcoin. Or

1:30:43

I get kind of dismissed like,

1:30:45

oh, well, you like economists. I

1:30:47

don't, you know, I don't want

1:30:50

to talk to you. But

1:30:52

I think, you know, in general, I

1:30:56

think there's a lot

1:30:58

of economics that that's

1:31:01

good economics, that's valuable to

1:31:04

learn. I

1:31:07

agree with Bitcoiners that Keynesianism is bad

1:31:09

and that it's not particularly valuable and

1:31:11

I wish that we could get rid

1:31:14

of a lot of these Keynesian aspects

1:31:16

of the way things are taught. But

1:31:20

at the same time, there is a lot

1:31:22

of value there, there is a lot of

1:31:24

stuff to learn. And essentially, I mean, a

1:31:26

lot of the ways that I have

1:31:29

been able to understand Bitcoin are based on

1:31:31

things that I've learned from monetary theory and

1:31:34

monetary history and just applying that to a

1:31:36

different context. And so, and to me, one

1:31:38

of the most fascinating things about Bitcoin, the

1:31:40

reason that I got interested in it in

1:31:42

the first place is my sense was, okay,

1:31:44

we have all these theories of how things

1:31:46

work. And a lot of these theories match

1:31:48

the data, but of course they match the

1:31:50

data, right? Because theory can never be completely

1:31:53

detached from like personal experience. So the fact

1:31:55

that we've experienced all of these things is

1:31:57

informing what we're writing down with our theory.

1:31:59

And the interesting thing to me was, okay,

1:32:01

here's Bitcoin. And so in

1:32:03

some ways it confirms certain

1:32:06

things about monetary theory and

1:32:08

some ways it challenges certain

1:32:10

things in monetary theory. But

1:32:12

this is fascinating because no

1:32:14

matter what happens with Bitcoin,

1:32:16

no matter how anything plays

1:32:18

out, it's a way to

1:32:20

take something that

1:32:22

didn't exist when a lot of

1:32:25

these theories were written down and

1:32:27

sort of test those theories with

1:32:29

something that the theorists who wrote

1:32:32

these things down never could have

1:32:34

thought about or predicted. And

1:32:36

to me, that's just a fascinating thing.

1:32:38

And I think that there's actually a

1:32:40

ton of interesting monetary theory, interesting monetary

1:32:43

history. that can be learned and that

1:32:45

can be valued. And I would also

1:32:47

point out that there are many people

1:32:49

in Bitcoin who have learned a lot

1:32:51

of this stuff, whether formally or on

1:32:53

their own. They might not be economics

1:32:55

professors, but a lot of them have

1:32:57

read a lot of monetary stuff just

1:32:59

because of their interest in Bitcoin. And

1:33:01

what I would say is if you've

1:33:03

read that stuff and you enjoy that

1:33:06

stuff, you should just know that there's

1:33:08

a lot more of that stuff that

1:33:10

exists. And it's really good.

1:33:13

And also, I would just say,

1:33:16

like, probably the last point is

1:33:18

that their interactions are going to

1:33:20

be biased, especially negative

1:33:22

interactions, right? Like, so if you're

1:33:24

if you're on, if you're on

1:33:27

the internet, if you're on social

1:33:29

media and you're arguing with somebody

1:33:31

about Bitcoin, that's because, you know,

1:33:33

like people, it attracts the internet

1:33:35

attracts people who like to argue

1:33:37

with each other, right? And so

1:33:39

if you If you're arguing with

1:33:42

somebody that doesn't mean that person

1:33:44

is representative of the profession or

1:33:46

representative of the views of economics,

1:33:49

actually like they are just probably one of

1:33:51

the loudest voices in economics and whether they

1:33:53

agree with you or not is just tangential

1:33:55

to the fact that they're kind of one

1:33:58

of the loudest voices. And

1:34:00

the loudest voices by definition are

1:34:02

the people with the strongest opinions,

1:34:04

but you shouldn't assume that they

1:34:06

speak for everybody or that... they're

1:34:08

even representative of what we believe.

1:34:12

Yeah, it's like the meme of the person stuck on

1:34:14

the computer saying, I can't come now, someone's wrong on

1:34:16

the internet. But so this has

1:34:18

been really great. If there was one kind of

1:34:20

piece of, if there was one book that you

1:34:22

would recommend to someone, what would it be? Well,

1:34:26

I mean, honestly, what

1:34:28

got me into this stuff

1:34:31

was studying, you know, alternative.

1:34:34

you know, monetary systems and the work of

1:34:36

people like Larry White and George Selgin. Like

1:34:38

these were guys that, you know, the cypher

1:34:41

punks were reading like these guys were on

1:34:43

the cypher punk mailing list. And so they've

1:34:45

written a lot about free banking. They've written

1:34:47

a lot about the gold standard. They've written

1:34:49

a lot about these things. And I think

1:34:51

that those people are, you can

1:34:53

read them and you can always gain

1:34:56

something. And even if you disagree with

1:34:58

certain things or even if you, you

1:35:00

know, or even if, you know, you,

1:35:02

you likes. you know, certain aspects of

1:35:04

what they're writing about and not others.

1:35:06

Like, I mean, you can read, you

1:35:09

can read their stuff and you can

1:35:11

learn a lot. And you can also,

1:35:13

and the other thing about their work

1:35:15

that I think is valuable is their

1:35:17

work, a lot of their work on

1:35:19

things like understanding current monetary policy is

1:35:22

done through the lens of, yeah, let's

1:35:24

think about current monetary policy, but let's

1:35:26

think about what a competitive system would

1:35:28

look like and then compare that to

1:35:30

how the actual system works and is

1:35:32

there any way that we can convince

1:35:35

monetary policymakers to move in the direction

1:35:37

that where they would at least behave.

1:35:39

Similar to how a competitive system would

1:35:41

work and I think like those are

1:35:43

actually really interesting thought experiment. Especially

1:35:47

because if you think we can't get rid of

1:35:49

central banks well you should at least want to

1:35:51

change their behavior to stop doing the bad things

1:35:54

and start doing you know start doing a better

1:35:56

job. I've always found it

1:35:58

weird that George Shaljin isn't Bitcoiner. Do

1:36:00

you, is that surprised you? I

1:36:03

think that, so you

1:36:06

asked me earlier sort of, you

1:36:08

know, what's the ideal system? Like

1:36:10

George, his work on free banking

1:36:12

really emphasizes that the reason that

1:36:15

competitive free banking works really well

1:36:17

is that the amount of money

1:36:19

supplied just matches money demand. When

1:36:21

you issue too much money, people

1:36:23

redeem those notes for gold. And

1:36:26

so there's a market -based constraint

1:36:28

on your ability to create money

1:36:30

and things like that. But the

1:36:32

thing is, is that because they

1:36:35

have the incentive to issue more

1:36:37

notes, they tend to issue the

1:36:39

amount that's demanded. And so that

1:36:41

tends to minimize a lot of

1:36:43

fluctuations that central banks cause because

1:36:46

central banks are moving around the

1:36:48

money supply. People's money demand

1:36:50

is changing. But they're

1:36:52

not necessarily related in any particular

1:36:55

way, right? And so

1:36:57

I think like a key lesson from

1:36:59

George's work is that, is

1:37:01

that what you would want a central

1:37:03

bank to do or what you would

1:37:05

ideally want out of a monetary system

1:37:07

is to have a monetary system where

1:37:09

the supply, you know, moves to meet

1:37:11

demand. And so I think that So

1:37:15

I think that like his concerns about the

1:37:17

viability of Bitcoin, I think are related to

1:37:19

the fixed supply because I think like his

1:37:21

concern is like that. How

1:37:23

do we know that that volatility will

1:37:25

ever calm down to the point where

1:37:27

people would be willing to use this

1:37:29

in transactions on a regular basis, right?

1:37:32

And so I think he would want an elastic to supply to

1:37:34

some degree. Yeah. And so I

1:37:36

think like ideally he would prefer that,

1:37:38

you know, demand was met with.

1:37:40

with increased supply and that that would

1:37:43

lead to stable purchasing power. The

1:37:47

issue is that that

1:37:49

perspective is by definition

1:37:51

like an irreconcilable difference

1:37:53

with Bitcoin, because there's

1:37:55

a reason why the

1:37:57

fixed supply of Bitcoin

1:37:59

is really important. The

1:38:02

fixed supply is important because first

1:38:04

of all, we don't have any

1:38:06

kind of technological mechanism. that

1:38:10

exists that could even implement

1:38:12

like George's preferred system, right?

1:38:14

Like there's no way that

1:38:16

you could program a protocol

1:38:18

that would just adjust the

1:38:20

money supply in conjunction with

1:38:22

money demand. And

1:38:25

the other thing is is that even

1:38:27

if you did have that sort of

1:38:29

system, it would be susceptible to changes,

1:38:32

right? People would constantly be tinkering with

1:38:34

it or people would want to argue

1:38:36

about. Well, should it really match demand

1:38:38

or should it be like slightly less

1:38:40

than demand or should it be slightly

1:38:42

more than demand or highly kind of,

1:38:45

you know, and that would be a

1:38:47

subject of debate. I think like the

1:38:49

Bitcoin's fixed supply is its strength precisely

1:38:51

because Bitcoin's not redeemable for anything else,

1:38:53

right? Like the reason why people are

1:38:55

willing to accept it is because the

1:38:58

supply is fixed. They know that there

1:39:00

will never be more. And so because

1:39:02

there won't be any more, like that's

1:39:04

the thing that that drives it. But

1:39:06

also that's the only thing. You can't

1:39:09

have a decentralized money without that characteristic,

1:39:11

at least given what we know now,

1:39:13

right? You can't have

1:39:15

this decentralized system if this

1:39:17

supply has to adjust to

1:39:20

demand because it's going to

1:39:22

require some real world adjustment.

1:39:24

And then you back in the same situation we're in now

1:39:26

anyway. Right. Exactly. And so then you're

1:39:29

just back into can you, you know, Can

1:39:31

you actually do this well? Can you trust

1:39:33

it? Yeah. And so the thing is, is

1:39:36

like the fixed supply is actually one of

1:39:38

the important components of, you know, the sort

1:39:40

of decentralized nature of the system. And it's

1:39:42

one of the things that kind of anchors

1:39:44

the system because nobody has an incentive to

1:39:46

change that. I mean, even if Bitcoin just

1:39:48

kind of even if the support, I

1:39:51

would argue that if the supply wasn't fixed,

1:39:54

it would actually make it. there

1:39:58

would actually be another problem, which is that

1:40:00

like, so suppose that Bitcoin just increased by

1:40:02

like 1 % a year forever or something

1:40:04

like that. At some point, people would debate,

1:40:06

should it be 2%, should it be 0

1:40:08

.9%, right? Like, and these things would become

1:40:10

issues that people would fight over. But the

1:40:12

fact that it's fixed, nobody

1:40:14

has an incentive to increase it,

1:40:16

right? And so

1:40:18

because nobody has an incentive to increase it,

1:40:20

you know that the system is committed to

1:40:23

that fixed supply. And so that's crucial to

1:40:25

how the system actually works. But these are

1:40:27

irreconcilable differences, right? If you want a system

1:40:29

where supply is going to adjust to meet

1:40:31

demand, that's,

1:40:33

you know, Bitcoin

1:40:35

obviously doesn't do that, but Bitcoin can't

1:40:37

do that because it wouldn't be Bitcoin.

1:40:39

It would be something completely different and

1:40:41

it would be much more similar to

1:40:44

kind of what we have now. Yeah,

1:40:46

the fixed supply is something that trips Jeff Snyder

1:40:49

up as well. He would like to see something

1:40:51

that had an elastic supply, but I'm obviously completely

1:40:53

with you on that. But thank you

1:40:55

very much for this, Josh. Where do you want to send

1:40:57

anyone to follow your work or anything that you're doing? You

1:41:01

can follow me on Twitter or X, I guess

1:41:04

it's now called. You know, I'm

1:41:06

at Rebel Econ Prof. And

1:41:09

I write a newsletter with one of my friends,

1:41:11

Brian Albrecht. I mean, I guess this is, if

1:41:13

you're interested in economics, this is, you

1:41:15

know, sometimes I write about monetary stuff. Sometimes

1:41:18

I just write about, you know, ordinary stuff,

1:41:20

but we write every week. The newsletter is

1:41:22

called Economic Forces. It's a

1:41:24

substack. There's

1:41:26

an econ topic every single week.

1:41:28

And the idea is that we're

1:41:31

really trying to revive like this

1:41:33

older kind of tradition, which is

1:41:35

kind of like this UCLA tradition

1:41:37

of economics, which focuses on really

1:41:39

simple models, but really focused on

1:41:41

understanding human behavior with those really

1:41:43

simple frameworks and seeing how far

1:41:45

you can push those frameworks. And

1:41:48

UCLA is also kind of this interesting

1:41:51

place because it's kind of like this

1:41:53

mixture of sort of Chicago school, people

1:41:55

with like more like, but

1:41:57

with Austrian tendencies. And so they a

1:42:00

very, very unique

1:42:02

school that's kind of gone

1:42:04

away, but we're trying to keep

1:42:06

that tradition alive because it still

1:42:08

exists, at least in classrooms, if

1:42:10

not at UCLA. So that's a

1:42:12

good place to kind of learn

1:42:14

some economics and general

1:42:16

stuff like that. Love

1:42:19

it. Well, I'm gonna go subscribe to that. Well,

1:42:21

I appreciate the time. Thank you, Josh. Yep,

1:42:23

no problem. Enjoy being here.

Rate

Join Podchaser to...

  • Rate podcasts and episodes
  • Follow podcasts and creators
  • Create podcast and episode lists
  • & much more

Episode Tags

Do you host or manage this podcast?
Claim and edit this page to your liking.
,

Unlock more with Podchaser Pro

  • Audience Insights
  • Contact Information
  • Demographics
  • Charts
  • Sponsor History
  • and More!
Pro Features